Skip to main content
Log in

Why Schumpeter has had so little influence on today’s main line economics, and why this may be changing

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While Schumpeter’s broad theory of how capitalist economies worked articulated in his Theory of Economic Development received strong attention in his lifetime, it was neoclassical economic theory that took hold of the profession in the last half of the twentieth century, and today few economists even read Schumpeter. The first part of this essay considers the reasons why Schumpeter largely has been ignored. However, recent developments have increased the interests of economists in innovation and in innovation driven economic activity, and the time now may be ripe for a renaissance of Schumpeterian economics. The second part of this essay provides a sketch of what an economics text-book, written from a Schumpeterian perspective, might look like.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. He provides the basis for one much later, in Chapter 7 of his Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy.

  2. The most influential such study of is Solow’s (1957). However. Solow’s work was preceeded by several other studies that came to a similar conclusion on the basis of methodologies that, while not the same as his, were similar.

  3. For a discussion of the intellectual history here see Nelson (2012a). Dosi and Nelson (2010) provide a broad review of the modern literature.

  4. Salter (1966) was one of the first economists documenting the tightness of the relationship at an industry level between increases in productivity (and implicitly decreases in unit costs) and declines in prices.

  5. For a review and discussion see Nelson (1998).

  6. I note that evolutionary economics has drawn extensively on the theory of behavior articulated in Simon (1957), March and Simon (1958), and Cyert and March (1963).

  7. Such an analysis could draw heavily on Winter (2006), Teece (2009), and Dosi et al. (2000).

  8. See Malerba et al. (2012), Innovation and the evolution of industries: history friendly models, unpublished, for a broad review.

  9. For a start on such an analysis see Nelson and Consoli (2010).

  10. McCraw (2007) provides an excellent discussion of the evolution of Schumpeter’s thinking about the appropriate nature and role of economic theory. See also Andersen (2011).

  11. For example, see Kitcher (2003) for a discussion of the contribution to understanding made by Darwin. Giere (1988) provides a good general discussion of the changes that have been occurring in the thinking among philosophers regarding the nature of science.

References

  • Andersen ES (2011) Joseph A. Schumpeter. Palgrave-Macmillan, Chippenham

  • Chandler A (1962) Strategy and structure. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler A (1990) Scale and scope. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Cyert R, March J (1963) A behavioral theory of the firm. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs

    Google Scholar 

  • Dopfer K (ed) (2005) The evolutionary foundations of economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Nelson R (2010) Technical change and industrial dynamics as evolutionary processes. In: Hall B, Rosenberg N (eds) Economics of innovation. North Holland Handbooks in Economics, Amsterdam

  • Dosi G, Nelson RR, Winter S (eds) (2000) The nature and dynamics of organizational capabilities. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1953) The methodology of positive economics. In: Essays in positive economics. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Giere R (1988) Explaining science. University Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Kitcher P (2003) Darwin’s achievement. In: In Mendel’s mirror. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • March J, Simon H (1958) Organizations. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • McCraw T (2007) Prophet of innovation: Joseph Schumpeter and creative destruction. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky H (1976) John Maynard Keynes. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R R (1998) The agenda for growth theory: a different point of view. Cambr J Econ 22(4):497–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (2003) On the uneven evolution of human know-how. Res Policy 32:900–922

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (2012a) Some features of research by economists on technological change foreshadowed by the rate and direction of inventive activity. In: Lerner J, Stern S (eds) The rate and direction of inventive activity revisited. University of Chicago Press for the NBER, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (2012b) Demand and supply and their interaction on markets as seen from the perspective of evolutionary economic theory. J Evol Econ 22. doi:10.1007/s00191-012-0274-4

  • Nelson RR, Consoli D (2010) An evolutionary theory of household consumption behavior. J Evol Econ 20:665–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Sampat B (2001) Making sense of institutions as a factor shaping economic performance. J Econ Behav Organ 44:31–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR, Winter S (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Salter WEG (1966) Productivity and technical change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson P (1981) Schumpeter as an economic theorist. In: Frisch H (ed) Schumpeterian economics. Praeger, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1939) Business cycles: a theoretical historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. McGraw Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1950) Capitalism, socialism, and democracy. Harper, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon H (1957) Models of Man. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow R (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39:312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Swedberg R (1991) Joseph A. Schumpeter: his life and works. Polity Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Teece D (2009) Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Winter S (2006) Towards a Schumpeterian theory of the firm. Ind Corp Change 15:125–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Richard R. Nelson.

Additional information

The basic themes in this paper were first presented at the conference in Vienna in October 2011 commemorating the 100th anniversary of the first publication of Schumpeter’s great book The Theory of Economic Development.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Nelson, R.R. Why Schumpeter has had so little influence on today’s main line economics, and why this may be changing. J Evol Econ 22, 901–916 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-012-0296-y

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-012-0296-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation