Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2018

01.08.2018

A capture theory of committees

verfasst von: Alvaro J. Name-Correa, Huseyin Yildirim

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Why do committees exist? The extant literature emphasizes that they pool dispersed information across members. In this paper, we argue that they may also serve to discourage outside influence or capture by raising its cost. As such, committees may contain members who are uninformed or who add no new information to the collective decision. We show that the optimal committee is larger when outsiders have larger stakes in its decision or contribute lower-quality proposals, or when its members are more corruptible. We also show that keeping committee members anonymous and accountable for their votes helps deter capture.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
For excellent surveys, see Gerling et al. (2005) and Li and Suen (2009).
 
2
It is well-established in the literature that committees may fail to aggregate diverse information because of strategic (or pivotal) voting (e.g., Austen-Smith and Banks 1996; Feddersen and Pesendorfer 1998).
 
3
Stigler presented an influential theory (and empirical evidence) of regulatory capture, which was later refined and expanded by Peltzman (1976) and Becker (1983) and applied to many other settings, including the political economy of trade policy (Grossman and Helpman 1994). For edifying reviews of the regulatory capture literature, see Laffont and Tirole (1993, ch. 11) and Dal Bó (2006).
 
4
Like other researchers, we recognize that vote buying is illegal in many societies and organizations, but the inducements offered to committee members need not be explicit. Indeed, there have been many real cases in which committee decisions were doubted or even dismissed owing to the fear of capture. Elliott (2011) reports that, perceived of unduly favoring the industry, the US Atomic Energy Commission was replaced by the independent Nuclear Regulatory Commission (NRC) in 1975. In sports, the international soccer federation’s (FIFA’s) decision to award the 2018 and 2022 World Cups to Russia and Qatar, respectively, were linked to bribery and vote-rigging, resulting in the indictments of several top FIFA officials (Collett et al. 2015). Last, but not least, in the 2016 Rio Olympics, several referees and judges were removed from the boxing competitions after “suspicious results” (Belson 2016).
 
5
We later extend the analysis to imperfectly informed experts for whom information aggregation is an issue.
 
6
In our baseline model, a larger committee size raises the cost of capture for the agent both because it increases the probability of a sufficiently incorruptible (or socially motivated) member and because it increases the number of bribes to be paid. What ensures a finite committee is a small cost of participation for each member (as in Persico 2004) or a finite pool of available experts. If, unlike our model, experts were purely self-motivated, no committee size would deter capture, as will be clear in the analysis.
 
7
Consistent with this finding, a randomized scoring system is used in Olympic boxing competitions, whereby only a subset of judges’ scores are tallied (Belson 2016). See also Amegashie (2006) for a similar rule in Olympic figure skating. Similarly, the verdicts of panels of judges in civil law regimes are announced by the court as a whole; the votes of the individual judges are not disclosed.
 
8
As will be seen in the analysis, without the ability to commit to size, the principal has an incentive to scale down the committee under no disclosure. Hence, if partial disclosure is not feasible or credible, the principal may opt for full disclosure of the committee.
 
9
The uniform distribution assumption greatly simplifies the analysis, but is not essential for the results.
 
10
The fact that the participation cost of a member is small reflects the idea that the committee serves the larger society.
 
11
Whether individual votes are secret or public is of no consequence in our setting since, as we will see below, the principal optimally chooses a rule of the unanimity, i.e., \(k=n\), thereby removing the possibility of vote-buying schemes based on casting a pivotal vote, as in Dal Bó (2007).
 
12
As is standard in the literature on political influence, we assume that the agent fulfills his promise of bribes even in a one-shot interaction: perhaps because he cares strongly about his “word of honor” or building reputation across a sequence of ad hoc committees; see, e.g., Laffont and Tirole (1993, ch. 11) for a discussion.
 
13
Claim A1 in the online appendix establishes that the agent has no incentive to bribe in the original problem if and only if he has no incentive to bribe in the relaxed problem.
 
14
Of course, there are other institutional and informational reasons, not modeled here, for adopting a unanimity rule (see, e.g., Yildirim 2007; Bond and Eraslan 2010; Alonso and Câmara 2016; Breitmoser and Valasek 2017).
 
15
Since an unbribed committee member would accept only a socially desirable project under the unanimity rule, bribes that target a subset of members would be a pure waste for the agent.
 
16
As is common in committee voting problems, a trivial equilibrium exists in which all members reject the project regardless of its social value—i.e., \(\phi _{-i}=0\) for all i. Aside from being uninteresting, such an equilibrium involves weakly dominated strategies for committee members and thus is not considered herein.
 
17
Recall that experts incur a negligible but positive participation cost, leading the principal to select the smallest committee that deters bribery.
 
18
For instance, the International Olympics Committee (of 98 members), the Tony Awards nominating committee (of 51 members), and university presidential search committees (of 15–21 members) are commonly publicized.
 
19
By the same token, if experts could actively solicit bribes from the agent, all N would do so.
 
20
Specifically, Claim A2 in the online appendix shows that under nondisclosure, unless the committee size is conjectured to be one, it would be strictly optimal for the agent to bribe all N experts. Otherwise, as seen in (5), a trivial indifference exists as to the number of bribes, m, offered when the committee comprises one member.
 
21
The composition effect identified under full disclosure is internal to the committee and operates regardless of other circumstances.
 
22
If the committee prepares a joint report after the vote, then \(c=\frac{C}{n}\) may be considered to be the (decreasing) marginal cost per member. Our conclusion in Proposition 4, however, would not change.
 
23
Given that prediction, one may wonder why the principal would not set a very high c—perhaps by requiring very detailed and onerous expert reports. While not part of our model, we believe that such high costs may affect experts’ willingness to serve on committees.
 
24
Whether a member decides to become informed before or after receiving a bribe has no qualitative effects, since we focus on the no-bribing equilibrium.
 
25
Given that \(s\sim U[-\,S,S]\), the value of information is
$$\begin{aligned} \Pr \{s>0\}E[s|s>0]+\Pr \{s<0\}(0)-E[s]=\frac{S}{4}. \end{aligned}$$
 
26
In fact, no committee size would deter bribing if \(\eta _{E}>\frac{S}{4}\). The reason is that, with sufficiently high information costs, all members would remain uninformed and vote to accept the project in exchange for a negligible bribe. Anticipating such full capture, the principal would not appoint a committee.
 
27
Recall that all informed members observe the same signal, so \(E[s|s_{i},s^{*},I]\) is not conditional on the number of informed members.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Alcindor, Y. (2013, June 14). Zimmerman jurors to be sequestered up to a month. USA Today. Alcindor, Y. (2013, June 14). Zimmerman jurors to be sequestered up to a month. USA Today.
Zurück zum Zitat Alonso, R., & Câmara, O. (2016). Persuading voters. American Economic Review, 106(11), 3590–3605.CrossRef Alonso, R., & Câmara, O. (2016). Persuading voters. American Economic Review, 106(11), 3590–3605.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Amegashie, J. A. (2006). The 2002 Winter Olympics scandal. Social Choice and Welfare, 26, 183–189.CrossRef Amegashie, J. A. (2006). The 2002 Winter Olympics scandal. Social Choice and Welfare, 26, 183–189.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. S. (1996). Information aggregation, rationality, and the Condorcet jury theorem. American Political Science Review, 90(1), 34–45.CrossRef Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. S. (1996). Information aggregation, rationality, and the Condorcet jury theorem. American Political Science Review, 90(1), 34–45.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bagnoli, M., & Bergstrom, T. (2005). Log-concave probability and its applications. Economic Theory, 26(2), 445–469.CrossRef Bagnoli, M., & Bergstrom, T. (2005). Log-concave probability and its applications. Economic Theory, 26(2), 445–469.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.CrossRef Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Belson, K. (2016, August 17). Boxing judges and refs removed after suspicious results. New York Times. Belson, K. (2016, August 17). Boxing judges and refs removed after suspicious results. New York Times.
Zurück zum Zitat Besley, T., & Prat, A. (2006). Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability. The American Economic Review, 96(3), 720–736.CrossRef Besley, T., & Prat, A. (2006). Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability. The American Economic Review, 96(3), 720–736.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bond, P., & Eraslan, H. (2010). Strategic voting over strategic proposals. Review of Economic Studies, 77(2), 459–490.CrossRef Bond, P., & Eraslan, H. (2010). Strategic voting over strategic proposals. Review of Economic Studies, 77(2), 459–490.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Breitmoser, Y., & Valasek, J. (2017). A rationale for unanimity in committees. Working paper. Breitmoser, Y., & Valasek, J. (2017). A rationale for unanimity in committees. Working paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Callander, S. (2008). Majority rule when voters like to win. Games and Economic Behavior, 64(2), 393–420.CrossRef Callander, S. (2008). Majority rule when voters like to win. Games and Economic Behavior, 64(2), 393–420.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collett, M., Homewood, B., & Raymond, N. (2015, May 27). World soccer rocked by U.S. Swiss arrests of officials for graft. Reuters. Collett, M., Homewood, B., & Raymond, N. (2015, May 27). World soccer rocked by U.S. Swiss arrests of officials for graft. Reuters.
Zurück zum Zitat Condorcet, M. (1785). Essai sur l’application de l’analyse a la probabilite des decisions rendues a la pluralite des voix. Paris, France: L’Imprimerie Royale. [Translation. Iain McLean and Fiona Hewitt, Paris, 1994]. Condorcet, M. (1785). Essai sur l’application de l’analyse a la probabilite des decisions rendues a la pluralite des voix. Paris, France: L’Imprimerie Royale. [Translation. Iain McLean and Fiona Hewitt, Paris, 1994].
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (1984). Committees and rent-seeking effort. Journal of Public Economics, 25(1–2), 197–209.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (1984). Committees and rent-seeking effort. Journal of Public Economics, 25(1–2), 197–209.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dal Bó, E. (2006). Regulatory capture: A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.CrossRef Dal Bó, E. (2006). Regulatory capture: A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203–225.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dal Bó, E. (2007). Bribing voters. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 789–803.CrossRef Dal Bó, E. (2007). Bribing voters. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 789–803.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dekel, E., Jackson, M. O., & Wolinsky, A. (2008). Vote buying: General elections. Journal of Political Economy, 116(2), 351–380.CrossRef Dekel, E., Jackson, M. O., & Wolinsky, A. (2008). Vote buying: General elections. Journal of Political Economy, 116(2), 351–380.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diamond, P. A., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1974). Increases in risk and in risk aversion. Journal of Economic Theory, 8(3), 337–360.CrossRef Diamond, P. A., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1974). Increases in risk and in risk aversion. Journal of Economic Theory, 8(3), 337–360.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Elliott, J. (2011). How nuclear regulators became captive to industry. Salon.com. Elliott, J. (2011). How nuclear regulators became captive to industry. Salon.com.
Zurück zum Zitat Feddersen, T., & Pesendorfer, W. (1998). Convicting the innocent: The inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting. American Political Science Review, 92(1), 23–35.CrossRef Feddersen, T., & Pesendorfer, W. (1998). Convicting the innocent: The inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting. American Political Science Review, 92(1), 23–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gerling, K., Grüner, H. P., Kiel, A., & Schulte, E. (2005). Information acquisition and decision making in committees: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(3), 563–597.CrossRef Gerling, K., Grüner, H. P., Kiel, A., & Schulte, E. (2005). Information acquisition and decision making in committees: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(3), 563–597.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Groseclose, T., & Snyder, J. M. (1996). Buying supermajorities. American Political Science Review, 90(2), 303–315.CrossRef Groseclose, T., & Snyder, J. M. (1996). Buying supermajorities. American Political Science Review, 90(2), 303–315.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.
Zurück zum Zitat Laffont, J.-J., & Tirole, J. (1993). A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. London: MIT Press. Laffont, J.-J., & Tirole, J. (1993). A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. London: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Levy, G. (2007). Decision making in committees: Transparency, reputation, and voting rules. American Economic Review, 97(1), 150–168.CrossRef Levy, G. (2007). Decision making in committees: Transparency, reputation, and voting rules. American Economic Review, 97(1), 150–168.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Li, H., & Suen, W. (2009). Decision-making in committees. Canadian Journal of Economics, 42, 359–392.CrossRef Li, H., & Suen, W. (2009). Decision-making in committees. Canadian Journal of Economics, 42, 359–392.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Midjord, R., Barraquer, T. R., & Valasek, J. (2017). Voting in large committees with disesteem payoffs: A ‘state of the art’ model. Games and Economic Behavior, 104, 430–443.CrossRef Midjord, R., Barraquer, T. R., & Valasek, J. (2017). Voting in large committees with disesteem payoffs: A ‘state of the art’ model. Games and Economic Behavior, 104, 430–443.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morgan, J., & Várdy, F. (2012). Mixed motives and the optimal size of voting bodies. Journal of Political Economy, 120(5), 986–1026.CrossRef Morgan, J., & Várdy, F. (2012). Mixed motives and the optimal size of voting bodies. Journal of Political Economy, 120(5), 986–1026.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.CrossRef Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Persico, N. (2004). Committee design with endogenous information. Review of Economic Studies, 71(1), 165–191.CrossRef Persico, N. (2004). Committee design with endogenous information. Review of Economic Studies, 71(1), 165–191.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3–21.CrossRef Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3–21.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yildirim, H. (2007). Proposal power and majority rule in multilateral bargaining with costly recognition. Journal of Economic Theory, 136(1), 167–196.CrossRef Yildirim, H. (2007). Proposal power and majority rule in multilateral bargaining with costly recognition. Journal of Economic Theory, 136(1), 167–196.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
A capture theory of committees
verfasst von
Alvaro J. Name-Correa
Huseyin Yildirim
Publikationsdatum
01.08.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0593-6

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2018

Public Choice 1-2/2018 Zur Ausgabe