Skip to main content

Litigation and the Social Order: Debt and Downward Mobility

  • Chapter
The Economy of Obligation

Part of the book series: Early Modern History: Society and Culture ((EMH))

Abstract

Because the day-to-day experience of wealth was based on the maintenance of credit, it was in a real way ‘fortune’ in the sense of being fortunate, because unpaid debts could easily become liabilities, dragging a household into the courts where its credit and wealth could be lost. Even for competent bookkeepers it was impossible to predict whether their own credit would suffer as a result of the unpaid debts of others, because profit was so dependent on the rapidly changing conditions of supply and demand. When it is considered that such insecurity existed in the competitive conditions of an economy with an oversupply of labour, it is not surprising that men had little confidence in the potential longevity of their wealth — because the institutional security provided by banks and other organizations of scale was just not present.

Debt is a consumer of credit and state, of goods and good name.

(Henry Wilkinson, The Debt Book, 1624)1

Men tumble up and downe in the world.

(Ralph Josselin, Diary, 1653.)2

By extreme sale of their wares [many tradesmen] become rich for a time but afterward fall again into poverty.

(William Harrison, Description of England, 1587.)3

I have liv’d to see, such is the uncertainty of human affairs, and especially in trade, the furious and outrageous creditor become bankrupt himself in a few years, or perhaps months after, and begging the same mercy of others.

(Daniel Defoe, Complete English Tradesman, 1726)4

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes

  1. Michael Mascuch, ‘Social mobility and middling self-identity: the ethos of British autobiographers, 1600–1750’, Social History, 20 (1995), pp. 56–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  2. C. Jackson (ed.) The Autobiography of Mrs. Alice Thornton, Surtees Society, LXII (1875), pp. 135–8.

    Google Scholar 

  3. The first Act of this kind was originally passed in December 1649, and allowed imprisoned debtors to apply for their discharge if they swore they were worth no more than five pounds in total assets. After this, the creditor had 30 days to deny that the debtor was actually this poor if he had evidence to the contrary. If the debtor was released, he was still held to be responsible for the debt. The Act under which the poor prisoners in Lynn applied for release was passed on 5 April, 1652, and simply allowed new debtors incarcerated in the time since the first Act to apply for a discharge. C.H. Firth and R.S. Rait (eds.) Acts and Ordinances of the Interregnum (London, 1911), II, pp. 321–5

    Google Scholar 

  4. In addition to the work of Joanna Innes on the King’s Bench Prison, and that of Paul Haagen see also, Beattie, Crime and the Courts, pp. 288–309; Earle, Making, pp. 124–5; R.B. Pugh, ‘Newgate between two fires’, Guildhall Studies in London History, III (1978), pp. 137–63

    Google Scholar 

  5. Ibid., p. 125. Also see Pepys, Diary, III, p. 13, VI, pp. 149–50; D.M. Woodward, The Trade of Elizabethan Chester, Occasional Papers in Economic and Social History #4 (University of Hull, 1970), p. 112.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Pepys, Dairy, III, p. 53; VI, pp. 144, 149. There was also a case in the letters of the estate steward Daniel Eaton where he reported that it took ten years before one labourer was paid his wages. Wake and Webster (eds.), Letters of Daniel Eaton, p. xlii. Many workmen’s wages also remained unpaid after a seven-year period of accounting for the rebuilding of Crome Abbey. Howard Calvin (ed.), Letters and Papers Relating to the Rebuilding of Crombe Abbey, Warwickshire, 1681–1688, The Walpole Society, 15 (1984), p. 296.

    Google Scholar 

  7. J.M. Fewster, ‘The keelmen of Tyneside in the eighteenth century, Part I’, Durham University Journal, New Series, 19 (1957), p. 27.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Copyright information

© 1998 Craig Muldrew

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Muldrew, C. (1998). Litigation and the Social Order: Debt and Downward Mobility. In: The Economy of Obligation. Early Modern History: Society and Culture. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-26879-5_10

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-26879-5_10

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, London

  • Print ISBN: 978-1-349-26881-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-1-349-26879-5

  • eBook Packages: Palgrave History CollectionHistory (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics