Skip to main content

2020 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

7. Conclusions and Policies

verfasst von : Arwid Lund, Mariano Zukerfeld

Erschienen in: Corporate Capitalism's Use of Openness

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this final chapter, we present a summary and a comparison of insights gained from the case studies done, followed by the presentation of four major strands of policy suggestions that challenge the for-profit perspective that has been criticized throughout this book. In so doing we are challenging liberal ideology from the point of view of socialism’s understanding of freedom as an effective power to act, an ideological position that logically and ideally is dependent on an effective openness that is not open for subsequent enclosures. Within this change of perspective we will prioritize horizontal ways of organizing production in more participatory and horizontal ways—as in the cases of cooperatives and commons-based peer production (CBPP)—that stress the importance of commoning together. This ideological position can in turn be tied to republicanism. We propose policies in four related sectors of cognitive capitalism in order to operationalize and structure this shift of perspective. The policies relate to economy, technical infrastructure, legal regulation (where we introduce the Commoners License Family) and alternative digital platforms.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
It is possible to distinguish between market-conforming regulation and market-negating regulation (Lapavitsas, 2010). Curran et al. complement this with a state-negating regulation in order to protect digital spaces from state surveillance and control (Curran et al., 2016, p. 206), but they also conclude that “the idea that one can use the power of the state to enhance public provision, as opposed to government control, is hardly new” (Curran et al., 2016, p. 207).
 
2
The principle goes back to André Malraux, French Minister of Culture for the Popular Front in the 1930s.
 
3
Additionally, naming this tax—targeted at companies such as Google—after Vinton Cerf is to some extent polemical, not because of his undisputed and amazing contributions to the development of the Internet, but because of his role as a Google employee.
 
4
It should be noted that content from produsers is exploited in many different ways. Often these ways include chains of interdependence like in the vertically integrated uses of FOSS, by for example IBM intermediated by Red Hat in chains going back to the Fedora community, and to many other previously unpaid produsers’ programming activities around the Linux kernel. The exploitation could of course also be more direct as in the case of Facebook that is directly exploiting produsers of various forms of content on their own platform. A tax in this field not only focuses on the exploitation of living labor or unpaid activities in the case of Facebook, but also on the exploitation of historically unpaid living labor in IBM and Red Hat’s case.
 
5
A minor comment on intellectual property justifications: Individual ownership of data can also be justified from the Hegelian theory of personality, but not from a Lockean theory of labor (Hughes, 1988).
 
6
Different apps for managing personal data and intending to give consent and/or sell it have been developed. See for instance Yansen’s (2019) work on Wibson.
 
7
Curran et al. contend that data mining of big data should be used for “non-profit coordination of healthcare, transport, and public services”, and therefore support Morozov’s call for socializing the data centers, and criticize the use of datasets as a commodity to attract advertising (Curran et al., 2016, p. 207).
 
8
This is of course against so-called Net Neutrality. Neutrality, in a capitalist environment, is usually an ideological concept used to conceal the interests of those allegedly neutral actors. This is no exception and the net neutrality debate disguises the confrontation between capitalist services and content providers (such as Google or Netflix) and ISPs and owners of the infrastructure. While the latter demand price discrimination in order to charge more to huge companies, the former demand that every package is treated without discrimination, to equal their activities with those of an end user. Our position here is in favor of a radical neutrality, one in which the playing field is truly leveled.
 
9
The streaming service form of digital platforms like Netflix or Spotify has today substituted the P2P-file sharing of media content from platforms like The Pirate Bay. This strengthens a new form one-directional communication, or rather a relation in which a dominant party streams content in exchange for users’ attention (to advertisements) or for a fee, but also in exchange for the users’ data.
 
10
The architect behind the GPL, Richard Stallman, understands openness as being less important than rights and freedoms to act in common and in solidarity. Users should collectively control the program and what they can do with it: “Free software is software that respects users’ freedom and community” (Stallman, 2018, pp. 77–8). Actually GPL not only grants, but also requires that the freedoms or rights to access, reproduce, adapt and distribute the software (all being activities) are present in all derivative works (Stallman, n.d.). But, although GPL pits political liberalism’s favor of freedom of speech against economic liberalism’s need for private property enclosures, Stallman still moves very much within a liberal tradition that is critical of oligopoly capitalism, but not of smaller firms and enterprises (Stallman, 2018, p. 84). Even if Stallman stresses the building of commons and the fostering of solidarity, he stops short of developing a clear critique of capitalism’s anti-social logic. Competition between capitals will, regardless of the form capitalism takes, lead to capital concentration and centralization, in which smaller capitals are out-competed and co-opted by larger ones (Bottomore & Harris, 1991; Marx, 1867).
 
11
Moreover, although we support the idea of a reciprocal clause in general, we think that the suggested elaborations on a measurement system in relation to a reciprocal clause miss the point with a commons-based gift economy, and introduce a form of instrumental reason that is alien to such a gift economy (Said Vieira & De Filippi, 2014).
 
12
A license, from whichever party, is non-exclusive as long as it does not actively state the transfer of exclusive rights (Dodd, Lichter, & Reichman, 2019). Instead, content that is licensed by the copyright owner to someone in an exclusive manner, is effectively giving away the ownership of that content to the other party. After that is done, the original copyright holder has no control over the economic rights and cannot re-license the content in any way. That is what happens when you sign a traditional contract with a traditional book publisher, but also when you sign a contract with many Open Access Journals (OAJs). In the latter case, the choice of specific libre license (with specific CC license) is important. On the other hand, if the license is used together with a non-exclusive right, the receiving party cannot control either the copyright or the use of the entity that has been licensed to them. This also means that the original copyright holder, a lone programmer or the many commons-based peer-to-peer producers (if all are consenting) of the project, could re-license the content or software as they wish. This re-licensing would constitute a dual- or multi-licensing of software or cultural works, which forms one of the major loopholes connected to the GPL license.
 
13
Dual licensing creates a substantial loophole in relation to the standard GPL license, not only in relation to software but also in relation to cultural goods. Individual, institutional (companies and co-ops) and CBPP license holders can decide to issue a new proprietary license for the same work. In relation to companies based on CBPP-developed projects, this is often achieved by a CLA (Contributor License Agreement).
 
14
We agree with Stallman’s critique that Creative Commons only offers the copyleft alternative as one of many different options (Stallman, 2018, p. 79). Instead we would like to propose that co-ops, CBPPs and state-funded platforms use the PPL as the base for a new kind of license family, where the distinction between non-profit and for-profit actors along with copyleft are core units that are complemented by various voluntary options that can be added to the core.
 
15
But, what is a substantial contribution? It is hard to tell. From the literature (Bauwens & Kostakis, 2014, 2015; Kostakis & Bauwens, 2014; P2P Foundation, 2018; Said Vieira & De Filippi, 2014) it is very unclear how large a for-profit company’s active contribution to a co-op or commons-based project will have to be in order to be valid as such, thus rendering it possible for it to exploit the co-op’s or CBPP’s work. Also, there seems to be no difference between the contributions by a for-profit company and the contribution of a co-op member, or a “true” commoner.
 
16
“But, beyond that, governments should pass laws saying that agreements of that nature are invalid—that they have no legal force in this jurisdiction, no matter where they were signed. This applies to non-negotiated contracts, where the terms are just imposed: ‘If you want this, agree to the contract’—there’s no chance to negotiate, and that’s the great abuse. It’s different when the parties actually talk about what terms they want; there may be no need to restrict those” (Stallman, 2018, p. 86).
 
17
How such alternatives could grow stronger in order to harness the value of the network effects is a crucial question. To successfully address this problem will involve cooperation and strategic alliances between co-ops, CBPPs and state agency-funded platforms. In the end there will have to be cooperation around collective or federated solutions, like in networks of both state-funded distributed institutional repositories of peer-reviewed scholarly articles (based on the OAI-PMH protocol) with a common search interface, and in networks of non-profit academic journals that Fuchs and Sandoval propose as an alternative to the Gold OA business model (Fuchs & Sandoval, 2013). But, in order to be successful, we cannot rely only on the state. The state under capitalism, characterized by citizens’ rights that potentially give the “subaltern classes control over legislative and executive powers” at the same time as the constitution backs the interests of private property (Jessop, 2018), needs support from trade unions, social movements and non-profit organizations, in order to have an increasingly progressive function. The partner state (Bauwens, Kostakis, & Pazaitis, 2019; Kostakis & Bauwens, 2014) will need to have someone to partner up with. Therefore, there is a need to incite and facilitate bottom-up, commons-based or cooperative projects that are increasingly networked and federated amongst themselves, and in relation to the state. Helping each other in federated networks could eventually lead to effective ways of harnessing network effects in non-profit forms. Very much like Wikipedia with all its language-versions is already experiencing.
 
18
The state’s support to platform projects should in turn, in our view, be characterized by the arm’s length principle that we discussed initially in this chapter. It should be directed toward prioritizing platform projects using one of the licenses in the Commoners’ License Family. Using one of the Commoners’ licenses safeguards, builds, and also has the potential to level the digital playing field in potentially expanding and flexible ways, popularizing the effective power to act that would expand social practices of doing in common, commoning, in-between and also beyond the state and the market (De Angelis, 2017). Strengthening society’s commons will in turn strengthen the state’s power to challenge (an effective right to act) neoliberalism.
 
19
Scholz enumerates three parts or principles of his proposal for Platform Cooperativism. Here we rearranged these principles to better reflect our perspective. Despite Scholz using the term “co-ops”, his examples, typologies and principles refer to a wider set of organizations than just cooperatives.
 
20
The Marxist critique of cooperatives is straightforward: either they survive by competing on the market, but then they tend to become capitalistic in character in the process, or they stick to their alternative visions, but then tend to fail in the competition on the market and dissolve sooner or later (Sandoval, 2016, pp. 98, 100–1). Sandoval (2016) points out that contemporary business discourse and older liberal discourse actually exceed this critique by advocating co-ops as a strategy to increase productivity and innovation within capitalism. And, in order to be political in the grander scheme of things they have to establish political goals on a societal level for the business (Sandoval, 2016, pp. 98, 100–1). “Radical politics are not inherent in the co-operative structure” (Sandoval, 2016, p. 102).
 
21
Scholz’s concept of platform co-ops exceeds our focus here in two respects. On the one hand, he describes co-ops as platforms which we would classify as CBPP (as “Produser-owned Platforms”) or state funded (“City-Owned Platform Cooperatives”). On the other hand, Scholz is engaged not only in finding alternatives to profit from openness business models but also and mainly to other kinds of platforms, such as Uber, Airbnb, Task Rabbit and so on (see Scholz, 2016). Certainly, we welcome this broad perspective, as we do think that it contributes to building a thriving sphere of digital commons.
 
22
It is also important to mention that even if in this study we reserve the term co-op for workers’ co-ops, consumer-driven co-ops have been around for more than 100 years. A consumer co-op is not the same thing as a user or produser cooperative as it is built around commercial activity, but the historic consumer co-ops with their more fluctuating memberships connect political ideas put forward within guild socialism’s and anarcho-syndicalism’s ideas about establishing federations of producer and consumer co-ops that synchronize their activities on a societal level (Lund, 2001; Wikipedia contributors, 2018). Future policies could discover further insights about how to scale up the produser-cooperative idea in progressive and democratic ways from these traditions.
 
23
More precisely, the former provide subtractable goods and services while the latter offer non-subtractable goods. Regarding these concepts, see the section on commons in Chap. 1.
 
24
To be sure, there are worker co-ops providing free software (such as Gcoop in Argentina), but they are not platform co-ops.
 
25
Bauwens et al. explain heterarchy as follows: “In CBPP some contributors may be paid/employed but all (in collaboration with groups and individuals that are not) produce commons. Hence, the work is not directed by corporate hierarchies, but through the mutual coordination mechanisms of the productive community. CBPP is based on open and transparent systems, in which everyone can see the signals of the work of others, and can, therefore, adapt to the needs of the system as a whole” (Bauwens et al., 2019, p. 12).
 
26
There are also other alternatives. The main one refers to institutional arrangements in which the state funds organizations placed outside it. For instance, Public Benefit Organization (PBO) or Public Good Organization is a narrower form of non-profit organization. PBOs provide specific services that often exclude partisan or political and lobbying organizations (Bolleyer, 2018). Such organizations could be publicly funded by the state, under the principle of arm’s length distance, to develop digital platforms of various sorts. Yet another kind of state-centered platform for commoning might refer to experiments with participatory budgeting. They constitute a direct-democracy approach to budgeting that could strengthen an inclusive and more horizontal governance, but could also be captured by interest groups in an unequal society (Shah, 2007, p. 1). Such projects could use digital platforms in new experimental ways through regional and neighborhood committees.
 
27
This development takes its influences from the USA, the doctrine of New Public Management, and the central banks’ independence in Europe, and the independent agencies are located in specific fields (like water, telecom and electricity) where they are thought to enhance the efficiency and quality of services to the citizens. As an example, the state in Latin America has changed its character since the 1990s because of these autonomous regulatory agencies (Bouckaert & Peters, 2004, p. 89; Levi-Faur & Jordana, 2006, pp. 335–6, 340).
 
28
Like in many examples, the borders between independent agencies, state-funded NGOs and CBPP are blurred. For instance, academic researchers acting as peers (in peer-review processes) remind us of a CBPP feature. However, in many cases these unremunerated activities are part of the duties that are measured and taken into account by the institution which pays the wages of teachers taking on the duties of peer reviewers.
 
29
Another version of the same problem regards the monitoring of how co-op members, wage laborers and produsers follow the regulations of for-profit uses, in case they are allowed.
 
30
Our policies regarding the alternative platforms’ monetary relations to the capitalist economy differ from other ways of financing alternative platforms. Spanish Goteo is here an instructive example to discuss. Goteo is a crowdfunding platform that works as a middle man, helping what they call commons-based projects to collect monetary gifts, or facilitating distributed voluntary contributions (microtasks, services or infrastructure-related) to them (Goteo, 2019c). “It is a tool for generating resources ‘drop by drop’ for a community of communities consisting of over 65,000 people, with a funding success rate over 70%” (Goteo, 2019a). This support is much needed for alternative platforms, but there are several crucial differences between the policies we propose and Goteo’s perspective.
First, Goteo fully accepts the unconditional possibility of “individual rewards” as long as the actions contribute to “generate a collective return through fomenting the commons” (Goteo, 2019c). This puts the focus on prosperous individuals rather than collectives. Second, this collective return refers to projects that are transferable and reusable not only under free licenses (like in free software), but also under open licenses (like open source software) (Goteo, 2019b). The project therefore to some extent supports the openness ideology that we critique and direct our policy suggestions against. Third, Goteo does not regulate for-profit uses of the commons’ resources by for-profit actors. Our proposed alternative co-ops, CBPPs and state agencies that use the Commoners’ License Family, could form the base for a new intermediary that gives a helping hand in building robust and collectively governed commons that prosper from the regulated collection and distribution of fees from for-profit uses of their resources that do not permit the enclosure of derivative works.
 
31
In projects that already depend on voluntary contributions of productive activities, a significant contribution from an outsider does not have to be distinguished from commoners’ contributions, if no profits are made and kept privately by the two. The outsider just becomes an insider. But, on the other hand, all commoners that are making substantial contributions, also get the commercial right to use the commons for for-profit uses.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Bauwens, M., & Kostakis, V. (2014). From the communism of capital to capital for the commons: Towards an open co-operativism. TripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society, 12(1), 356–361.CrossRef Bauwens, M., & Kostakis, V. (2014). From the communism of capital to capital for the commons: Towards an open co-operativism. TripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society, 12(1), 356–361.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bauwens, M., & Kostakis, V. (2015). Towards a new reconfiguration among the state, civil society and the market. Journal of Peer Production, 7, 1–6. Bauwens, M., & Kostakis, V. (2015). Towards a new reconfiguration among the state, civil society and the market. Journal of Peer Production, 7, 1–6.
Zurück zum Zitat Bauwens, M., Kostakis, V., & Pazaitis, A. (2019). Peer to peer: The commons manifesto. In Critical, digital and social media studies. London: University of Westminster. Bauwens, M., Kostakis, V., & Pazaitis, A. (2019). Peer to peer: The commons manifesto. In Critical, digital and social media studies. London: University of Westminster.
Zurück zum Zitat Benkler, Y. (2006). The wealth of networks: How social production transforms markets and freedom. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Benkler, Y. (2006). The wealth of networks: How social production transforms markets and freedom. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Benkler, Y. (2014). Peer production and cooperation, forthcoming. In J. M. Bauer & M. Latzer (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of the Internet. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar. Benkler, Y. (2014). Peer production and cooperation, forthcoming. In J. M. Bauer & M. Latzer (Eds.), Handbook on the economics of the Internet. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar.
Zurück zum Zitat Bolleyer, N. (2018). The state and civil society: Regulating interest groups, parties, and public benefit organizations in contemporary democracies. Oxford: Oxford Scholarship Online.CrossRef Bolleyer, N. (2018). The state and civil society: Regulating interest groups, parties, and public benefit organizations in contemporary democracies. Oxford: Oxford Scholarship Online.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bottomore, T. B., & Harris, L. (Eds.). (1991). A dictionary of Marxist thought. Oxford: Blackwell. Bottomore, T. B., & Harris, L. (Eds.). (1991). A dictionary of Marxist thought. Oxford: Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Bouckaert, G., & Peters, G. (2004). Symposium on state autonomous agencies. Public Administration & Development, 24(2), 89.CrossRef Bouckaert, G., & Peters, G. (2004). Symposium on state autonomous agencies. Public Administration & Development, 24(2), 89.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. (1960, October). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef Coase, R. (1960, October). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Curran, J., Fenton, N., & Freedman, D. (2016). Misunderstanding the Internet (2nd ed.). Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge.CrossRef Curran, J., Fenton, N., & Freedman, D. (2016). Misunderstanding the Internet (2nd ed.). Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Angelis, M. (2017). Omnia Sunt Communia: On the commons and the transformation to postcapitalism. London: Zed Books. De Angelis, M. (2017). Omnia Sunt Communia: On the commons and the transformation to postcapitalism. London: Zed Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Demsetz, H. (1970). The private production of public goods. Journal of Law and Economics, 13(2), 293–306.CrossRef Demsetz, H. (1970). The private production of public goods. Journal of Law and Economics, 13(2), 293–306.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frenander, A. (2007). No discord, or, and area without significant political stakes? International Journal of Cultural Policy, 13(4), 393–406.CrossRef Frenander, A. (2007). No discord, or, and area without significant political stakes? International Journal of Cultural Policy, 13(4), 393–406.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fuchs, C. (2015). Left-wing media politics and the advertising tax. Reflections on Astra Taylor’s book ‘The people’s platform: Taking back power and culture in the digital age’. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique, 13(1), 1–4. Fuchs, C. (2015). Left-wing media politics and the advertising tax. Reflections on Astra Taylor’s book ‘The people’s platform: Taking back power and culture in the digital age’. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique, 13(1), 1–4.
Zurück zum Zitat Fuchs, C., & Sandoval, M. (2013). The diamond model of open access publishing: Why policy makers, scholars, universities, libraries, labour unions and the publishing world need to take non-commercial, non-profit open access serious. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society, 13(2), 428–443.CrossRef Fuchs, C., & Sandoval, M. (2013). The diamond model of open access publishing: Why policy makers, scholars, universities, libraries, labour unions and the publishing world need to take non-commercial, non-profit open access serious. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society, 13(2), 428–443.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goteo. (2019b). About the projects. Retrieved March 20, 2019, from Goteo.org: Crowdfunding the commons website: The only differences between. Goteo. (2019b). About the projects. Retrieved March 20, 2019, from Goteo.​org: Crowdfunding the commons website: The only differences between.
Zurück zum Zitat Hughes, J. (1988). The philosophy of intellectual property. Georgetown Law Journal, 77, 287–366; reprinted in Intellectual property: Moral, legal, and international dilemmas (A. Moore, Ed.). Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield. Hughes, J. (1988). The philosophy of intellectual property. Georgetown Law Journal, 77, 287–366; reprinted in Intellectual property: Moral, legal, and international dilemmas (A. Moore, Ed.). Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield.
Zurück zum Zitat Jessop, B. (2018). Elective affinity or comprehensive contradiction? Reflections on capitalism and democracy in the time of finance-dominated accumulation and austerity states. Berliner Journal für Soziogie, 28(1–2), 9–37.CrossRef Jessop, B. (2018). Elective affinity or comprehensive contradiction? Reflections on capitalism and democracy in the time of finance-dominated accumulation and austerity states. Berliner Journal für Soziogie, 28(1–2), 9–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kleiner, D. (2010). The telekommunist manifesto (G. Lovink & S. Niederer, Red.). Amsterdam: Institute of Network Cultures. Kleiner, D. (2010). The telekommunist manifesto (G. Lovink & S. Niederer, Red.). Amsterdam: Institute of Network Cultures.
Zurück zum Zitat Kostakis, V., & Bauwens, M. (2014). Network society and future scenarios for a collaborative economy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRef Kostakis, V., & Bauwens, M. (2014). Network society and future scenarios for a collaborative economy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lanier, J. (2013). Who owns the future. New York: Simon & Schuster. Lanier, J. (2013). Who owns the future. New York: Simon & Schuster.
Zurück zum Zitat Lapavitsas, C. (2010). Regulate financial institutions, or financial institutions? In P. Arestis, R. Sobreira, & L. Oreiro (Eds.), The financial crisis: Origins and implications (pp. 137–159). Houndsmills: Palgrave Macmillan. Lapavitsas, C. (2010). Regulate financial institutions, or financial institutions? In P. Arestis, R. Sobreira, & L. Oreiro (Eds.), The financial crisis: Origins and implications (pp. 137–159). Houndsmills: Palgrave Macmillan.
Zurück zum Zitat Levi-Faur, D., & Jordana, J. (2006). Toward a Latin American regulatory state? The diffusion of autonomous regulatory agencies across countries and sectors. International Journal of Public Administration, 29(4–6), 335–366.CrossRef Levi-Faur, D., & Jordana, J. (2006). Toward a Latin American regulatory state? The diffusion of autonomous regulatory agencies across countries and sectors. International Journal of Public Administration, 29(4–6), 335–366.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lindsköld, L. (2015). Contradicting cultural policy: A comparative study of the cultural policy of the Scandinavian radical right. Nordisk kulturpolitisk tidskrift, 18(1), 8–26. Lindsköld, L. (2015). Contradicting cultural policy: A comparative study of the cultural policy of the Scandinavian radical right. Nordisk kulturpolitisk tidskrift, 18(1), 8–26.
Zurück zum Zitat Lund, A. (2001). Albert Jensen och revolutionen: syndikalismens revolutionära idéer 1900–1950. Stockholm: Federativ. Lund, A. (2001). Albert Jensen och revolutionen: syndikalismens revolutionära idéer 1900–1950. Stockholm: Federativ.
Zurück zum Zitat Lund, A. (2017b). The open data movement in the Age of Big Data Capitalism (Nr 7). London: Westminster Institute for Advanced Studies (WIAS). Lund, A. (2017b). The open data movement in the Age of Big Data Capitalism (Nr 7). London: Westminster Institute for Advanced Studies (WIAS).
Zurück zum Zitat Lund, A. (2017c). Wikipedia, work and capitalism: A realm of freedom? In Dynamics of virtual work. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan and Springer Nature. Lund, A. (2017c). Wikipedia, work and capitalism: A realm of freedom? In Dynamics of virtual work. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan and Springer Nature.
Zurück zum Zitat Lund, A., & Venäläinen, J. (2016). Monetary materialities of peer production: The case of Wikipedia and its controversies with paid labour. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society, 14(1), 78–98. Lund, A., & Venäläinen, J. (2016). Monetary materialities of peer production: The case of Wikipedia and its controversies with paid labour. tripleC: Communication, Capitalism & Critique. Open Access Journal for a Global Sustainable Information Society, 14(1), 78–98.
Zurück zum Zitat Marx, K. (1867). Capital: A critique of political economy (Vol. 1). London: Penguin. Marx, K. (1867). Capital: A critique of political economy (Vol. 1). London: Penguin.
Zurück zum Zitat Moullier-Boutang, Y. (2011). Cognitive capitalism. Cambridge: Polity. Moullier-Boutang, Y. (2011). Cognitive capitalism. Cambridge: Polity.
Zurück zum Zitat Oszlak, O., & O’Donnell, G. (1995). Estado y políticas estatales en América Latina: hacia una estrategia de investigación. Redes, 2(4), 99–128. Oszlak, O., & O’Donnell, G. (1995). Estado y políticas estatales en América Latina: hacia una estrategia de investigación. Redes, 2(4), 99–128.
Zurück zum Zitat Rigi, J. (2013). Peer production and Marxian communism: Contours of a new emerging mode of production. Capital & Class, 37(3), 397–416.CrossRef Rigi, J. (2013). Peer production and Marxian communism: Contours of a new emerging mode of production. Capital & Class, 37(3), 397–416.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sahlins, M. D. (2004). Stone Age economics. London: Routledge. Sahlins, M. D. (2004). Stone Age economics. London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Said Vieira, M., & De Filippi, P. (2014). Between Copyleft and Copyfarleft: Advance reciprocity for the commons. Journal of Peer Production, (4). Said Vieira, M., & De Filippi, P. (2014). Between Copyleft and Copyfarleft: Advance reciprocity for the commons. Journal of Peer Production, (4).
Zurück zum Zitat Sandoval, M. (2016). What would Rosa do? Co-operatives and radical politics. Soundings: A Journal of Politics and Culture, 63, 98–111.CrossRef Sandoval, M. (2016). What would Rosa do? Co-operatives and radical politics. Soundings: A Journal of Politics and Culture, 63, 98–111.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shah, A. (2007). Overview. In Participatory budgeting. World Bank Publications. Shah, A. (2007). Overview. In Participatory budgeting. World Bank Publications.
Zurück zum Zitat Söderberg, J. (2008). Hacking capitalism: The free and open source software movement. New York: Routledge. Söderberg, J. (2008). Hacking capitalism: The free and open source software movement. New York: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Stallman, R. (2018). Talking to the mailman. New Left Review, September–October, (113), 69–93. Stallman, R. (2018). Talking to the mailman. New Left Review, September–October, (113), 69–93.
Zurück zum Zitat Virno, P. (2004). A grammar of the multitude: For an analysis of contemporary forms of life. New York: Semiotext(e). Virno, P. (2004). A grammar of the multitude: For an analysis of contemporary forms of life. New York: Semiotext(e).
Zurück zum Zitat Yansen, G. (2019). Blockchain and data market. The case of Wibson from a critical perspective. In M. Ragnedda & G. Destefanis (Eds.), Blockchain and Web 3.0: Social, economic, and technological challenges. London: Routledge. Yansen, G. (2019). Blockchain and data market. The case of Wibson from a critical perspective. In M. Ragnedda & G. Destefanis (Eds.), Blockchain and Web 3.0: Social, economic, and technological challenges. London: Routledge.
Metadaten
Titel
Conclusions and Policies
verfasst von
Arwid Lund
Mariano Zukerfeld
Copyright-Jahr
2020
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-28219-6_7