Skip to main content

2018 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Creating Social Norms Through Media, Cascades and Cognitive Anchors: Judicial Activism and the Quality of Energy Law from the Perspective of Behavioural Law and Economics

verfasst von : Mariusz J. Golecki, Jarosław Bełdowski

Erschienen in: Energy Law and Economics

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter is devoted to the topic of judicial activism (or lack thereof) and the quality of energy law from a behavioural law and economics point of view. It complements our previous research by showing that a third branch of government (judiciary) is not immune to impact from social norms, cascades and cognitive anchors created by media (Golecki and Bełdowski, Environmental law and economics, 471–486, 2017). We start with three basic assumptions of the quality of judicial decisions and the latter’s overview from the perspective of law and economics. We then move to the impact of heuristics and biases on adjudication, as well as listing some cascades in energy law. The German nuclear energy policy is discussed in order to note its sudden shift after the Fukushima catastrophe. Subsequently, the legislative reaction is further described to grasp the fallacy of German constitutional ruling on the matter. We suggest that the case of the German nuclear phase-out strengthens our previous findings concerning the sensitivity of judges towards availability of cascades. The conclusions are drawn at the end of the paper.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Cf. Posner (2008), pp. 19–56.
 
2
This approach assumes that judicial decisions should be based on reason, however, practical reasonability is limited and decisions can in fact be based on irrational motives or emotions. This position has been explained by MacCormick, who suggested that: “any mode of evaluative argument must involve, depend on, or presuppose, some ultimate premises which are not themselves provable, demonstrable or confirmable in terms of further or ulterior reasons, yet on the other hand, that our adherence to ultimate principles in the evaluative and normative spheres is not derived by reasoning … does not show that our adherence to such principles is other than a manifestation of our rational nature”, MacCormick (1978), p. 265.
 
3
Posner (2008).
 
4
Vermeule (2006), pp. 3–4. In particular, he identifies two concurring institutional aspects: institutional capacities and systemic effects.
 
5
Cf. Fix-Fierro (2003), Hadfield (2008).
 
6
This moderate approach has been suggested by Simon in 1991 and applied to the model of adjudication by Vermeule (2006).
 
7
Cf. Guthrie et al. (2000), Vermeule (2006) and Gigerenzer (2007).
 
8
Posner (1980, 2008), Calabresi (1982) and Tullock (1997).
 
9
Coase (1988), pp. 10–16.
 
10
Later Coase repeatedly distanced himself from this thesis, according to which the object of his study was the theory of law, emphasising rather the only economic aspects of his studies (Kitch 1983, p. 192).
 
11
Coase (1988), pp. 8–30.
 
12
Mercuro and Medema (1997), p. 61.
 
13
This follows from the previously adopted assumptions, according to which the degree of precision is proportional to the incurred cost of adoption of a given legal rule.
 
14
Ehrlich and Posner (1974), pp. 257–260.
 
15
Posner (1980), pp. 487–490.
 
16
Posner (1993).
 
17
Gennaioli and Schleifer (2007), pp. 43–68; Ponzetto and Fernandez (2008), pp. 382–384.
 
18
Hirsch (2005).
 
19
Ponzetto and Fernandez (2008), pp. 405–406; Hadfield (2010).
 
20
In this context the opposite solution, namely the application of judge made law in case of rapid social change is at least partly applicable, as proposed by Calabresi, who states that: “There is an alternate way of dealing with the problem of legal obsolescence: granting to courts the authority to determine whether a statute is obsolete, whether in one way or another it should be consciously reviewed. At times this doctrine would approach granting to courts authority to treat statutes as if they were no more and no less than part of the common law. At other times it would be used to enable courts to encourage, or even to induce, legislative reconsideration of the statute”, Calabresi (1982), p. 2. It is obvious that this kind of radical change depending on technological changes, natural disasters or other rapid and unexpected events may become especially frequent within the field of energy law.
 
21
MacCormick (1978) and Alexy (1989).
 
22
Simon (1991), Vermeule (2006) and Rachlinski (2007–2008).
 
23
Kahneman and Tversky (1979), Guthrie et al. (2000) and Sunstein and Vermeule (2003).
 
24
Jolls et al. (1998).
 
25
Kahneman et al. (1982).
 
26
Jolls et al. (1998).
 
27
Kahneman (2003).
 
28
Kahneman and Tversky (1979).
 
29
Bennett and Broe (2010).
 
30
Damasio (1994).
 
31
Cf. Peer and Gamliel (2014).
 
32
Kahneman (2003).
 
33
Kahneman and Tversky (1979).
 
34
Kahneman (2011) and Golecki et al. (2016).
 
35
Slovic et al. (2002), p. 420.
 
36
Rachlinski (2007–2008).
 
37
Wistrich et al. (2015).
 
38
Guthrie et al. (2000).
 
39
Wistrich et al. (2015).
 
40
Kahneman et al. (1982) and Kunda (1990).
 
41
Kahneman (2011), p. 139.
 
42
Kunda (1990), p. 493.
 
43
Wistrich et al. (2015), p. 863.
 
44
Maroney (2011).
 
45
Maroney claims that even judicial anger could effectively be channelled through the virtue of righteousness. Maroney (2012).
 
46
Kahneman (2011), p. 142. It seems that this mechanism could also be applied to some controversial judgments and the problem of populist adjudication or judicial populism.
 
47
Pollak and Russell (1976).
 
48
New York State Department of Health. “Love Canal: Public Health Time Bomb; A Special Report to the Governor and Legislature.” Albany, N.Y. 1978.
 
49
Cf. Golecki and Bełdowski (2017).
 
50
It has been observed that “(a)vailability provides a convincing explanation of Superfund’s existence and its endurance. The behavioural account of Superfund is that the availability of “Love Canal” as a symbol for the problem of abandoned hazardous waste dumps greatly intensified public concern, to the point where a legislative response became nearly inevitable, no matter what the actual facts might be.” Jolls et al. (1998), pp. 1520–1521.
 
51
Jolls et al. (1998) and Golecki (2015).
 
52
The obvious candidate here would be e.g. the U.S. Supreme Court’s decision in Board of Trade of Chicago v. Christie Grain & Stock Co., 198 U.S. 236 (1905), where the case has provided the Supreme Court with an excellent opportunity to clear and restate the judge-made legal regulation, to review and possibly overrule the state-based statutory limitations of speculation. Moreover, the Supreme Court could have possibly aim at altering the whole regulatory framework to set out a new legal distinction between legal and illegal forms of speculation. The court opted for a third solution, drawing a new distinction between gambling and financial insurance, understood as an uncertainty based economic activity. The solution was found strange and built upon the particular case against speculation as dangerous moral problem. The whole line of anti-speculative judgments in the U.S. could be explained by the availability cascade and lobbying of the financial brokers. Cf. Golecki (2012).
 
53
Jahn and Karolczuk (2012).
 
54
It is noteworthy that some judgments of the BvR have already been criticised on the bases of lack of empirical knowledge and misinterpretation of statistical data. Cf. Petersen (2013).
 
55
The Thirteenth Amendment to the Atomic Energy Act Is for the Most Part Compatible with the Basic Law, Press Release No. 88/2016 of 6 December 2016, https://​www.​bundesverfassung​sgericht.​de/​SharedDocs/​Pressemitteilung​en/​EN/​2016/​bvg16-088.​html [accessed 29 August 2017].
 
56
Wittneben (2012).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Alexy R (1989) A theory of legal argumentation. The theory of rational discourse as theory of legal justification. Oxford University Press, Oxford Alexy R (1989) A theory of legal argumentation. The theory of rational discourse as theory of legal justification. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Bennett H, Broe GA (2010) Judicial decision-making and neurobiology: the role of emotion and the ventromedial cortex in deliberation and reasoning. Am J Forensic Sci 42:11–18CrossRef Bennett H, Broe GA (2010) Judicial decision-making and neurobiology: the role of emotion and the ventromedial cortex in deliberation and reasoning. Am J Forensic Sci 42:11–18CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Calabresi G (1982) A common law for the age of statutes. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Calabresi G (1982) A common law for the age of statutes. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Coase RH (1988) The firm, the market, and the law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Coase RH (1988) The firm, the market, and the law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Zurück zum Zitat Damasio A (1994) Decartes’ error: emotion, reason, and the human brain. Avon, New York Damasio A (1994) Decartes’ error: emotion, reason, and the human brain. Avon, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich I, Posner RA (1974) An economic analysis of legal rulemaking. J Leg Stud 3:257–286CrossRef Ehrlich I, Posner RA (1974) An economic analysis of legal rulemaking. J Leg Stud 3:257–286CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fix-Fierro H (2003) Courts, justice and efficiency. A socio-legal study of economic rationality in adjudication. Hart Publishing, Oxford Fix-Fierro H (2003) Courts, justice and efficiency. A socio-legal study of economic rationality in adjudication. Hart Publishing, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Gennaioli N, Schleifer A (2007) The evolution of common law. J Polit Econ 115:43–68CrossRef Gennaioli N, Schleifer A (2007) The evolution of common law. J Polit Econ 115:43–68CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gigerenzer G (2007) Gut feelings: the intelligence of the unconscious. New York Gigerenzer G (2007) Gut feelings: the intelligence of the unconscious. New York
Zurück zum Zitat Golecki MJ (2012) Evolutionary theories of derivatives regulation. Aestimatio IEB Int J Financ 4:152–167 Golecki MJ (2012) Evolutionary theories of derivatives regulation. Aestimatio IEB Int J Financ 4:152–167
Zurück zum Zitat Golecki MJ (2015) New York Times v. Sullivan in European context. The optimal liability for libel from the perspective of behavioural law and economics. In: Mathis K (ed) European perspectives on behavioural law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 243–267 Golecki MJ (2015) New York Times v. Sullivan in European context. The optimal liability for libel from the perspective of behavioural law and economics. In: Mathis K (ed) European perspectives on behavioural law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 243–267
Zurück zum Zitat Golecki MJ, Bełdowski J (2017) Between Love Canal and Rada di Augusta: the optimal liability for environmental damages in American and European law from the perspective of behavioural law and economics. In: Mathis K, Huber BR (eds) Environmental law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 471–486CrossRef Golecki MJ, Bełdowski J (2017) Between Love Canal and Rada di Augusta: the optimal liability for environmental damages in American and European law from the perspective of behavioural law and economics. In: Mathis K, Huber BR (eds) Environmental law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 471–486CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Golecki MJ, Romanowicz M, Wojciechowski J (2016) Nudging in tax law? Eyetracking research on limits of efficacy of legal definitions. In: Mathis K, Tor A (eds) Nudging-possibilities, limitations and applications in European law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 289–313CrossRef Golecki MJ, Romanowicz M, Wojciechowski J (2016) Nudging in tax law? Eyetracking research on limits of efficacy of legal definitions. In: Mathis K, Tor A (eds) Nudging-possibilities, limitations and applications in European law and economics. Springer, Cham, pp 289–313CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guthrie C, Rachlinski JJ, Wistrich AJ (2000) Inside the judicial mind. Cornell Law Rev 86:777–892 Guthrie C, Rachlinski JJ, Wistrich AJ (2000) Inside the judicial mind. Cornell Law Rev 86:777–892
Zurück zum Zitat Guthrie C, Rachlinski JJ, Wistrich AJ (2007) Blinking on the bench: how judges decide cases. Cornell Law Rev 93:1–43 Guthrie C, Rachlinski JJ, Wistrich AJ (2007) Blinking on the bench: how judges decide cases. Cornell Law Rev 93:1–43
Zurück zum Zitat Hadfield G (2008) The levers of legal design: institutional determinants of the quality of law. J Comp Econ 36:43–73CrossRef Hadfield G (2008) The levers of legal design: institutional determinants of the quality of law. J Comp Econ 36:43–73CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hadfield G (2010) The dynamic quality of law: judicial incentives, legal human capital and the adaptation of law. J Econ Behav Organ 79:80–94CrossRef Hadfield G (2010) The dynamic quality of law: judicial incentives, legal human capital and the adaptation of law. J Econ Behav Organ 79:80–94CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirsch AJ (2005) Evolutionary theories of common law efficiency: reasons for (cognitive) skepticism. Fla State Univ Law Rev 32:425–441 Hirsch AJ (2005) Evolutionary theories of common law efficiency: reasons for (cognitive) skepticism. Fla State Univ Law Rev 32:425–441
Zurück zum Zitat Jahn D, Karolczuk S (2012) German exceptionalism: the end of nuclear energy in Germany! Environ Polit 21:159–164CrossRef Jahn D, Karolczuk S (2012) German exceptionalism: the end of nuclear energy in Germany! Environ Polit 21:159–164CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jolls C, Sunstein CR, Thaler R (1998) A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Rev 50:1471–1550CrossRef Jolls C, Sunstein CR, Thaler R (1998) A behavioral approach to law and economics. Stanford Law Rev 50:1471–1550CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D (2003) A perspective on judgment and choice. Mapping bounded rationality. Am Psychol 58:697–720CrossRef Kahneman D (2003) A perspective on judgment and choice. Mapping bounded rationality. Am Psychol 58:697–720CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D (2011) Thinking, fast and slow. Macmillan, London Kahneman D (2011) Thinking, fast and slow. Macmillan, London
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–293CrossRef Kahneman D, Tversky A (1979) Prospect theory: an analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47:263–293CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kahneman D, Slovic P, Tversky A (1982) Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. New York Kahneman D, Slovic P, Tversky A (1982) Judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. New York
Zurück zum Zitat Kitch EW (1983) The fire of truth: a remembrance of law and economics at Chicago, 1932–1970. J Law Econ 26:163–234CrossRef Kitch EW (1983) The fire of truth: a remembrance of law and economics at Chicago, 1932–1970. J Law Econ 26:163–234CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kunda Z (1990) The case for motivated reasoning. Psychol Bull 108:480–498CrossRef Kunda Z (1990) The case for motivated reasoning. Psychol Bull 108:480–498CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kuran T, Sunstein CR (1999) Availability cascades and risk regulation. Stanford Law Rev 51:683–768CrossRef Kuran T, Sunstein CR (1999) Availability cascades and risk regulation. Stanford Law Rev 51:683–768CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat MacCormick N (1978) Legal reasoning and legal theory. Oxford University Press, Oxford MacCormick N (1978) Legal reasoning and legal theory. Oxford University Press, Oxford
Zurück zum Zitat Maroney TA (2011) Emotional regulation and judicial behavior. Calif Law Rev 99:1485–1555 Maroney TA (2011) Emotional regulation and judicial behavior. Calif Law Rev 99:1485–1555
Zurück zum Zitat Maroney TA (2012) Angry judges. Vanderbilt Law Rev 65:1207–1286 Maroney TA (2012) Angry judges. Vanderbilt Law Rev 65:1207–1286
Zurück zum Zitat Mercuro N, Medema SG (1997) Economics and the law. From Posner to post-modernism. Princeton University Press, Princeton Mercuro N, Medema SG (1997) Economics and the law. From Posner to post-modernism. Princeton University Press, Princeton
Zurück zum Zitat Peer E, Gamliel E (2014) Heuristics and biases in judicial decisions. Court Rev 4:114–118 Peer E, Gamliel E (2014) Heuristics and biases in judicial decisions. Court Rev 4:114–118
Zurück zum Zitat Petersen N (2013) Avoiding the common-wisdom fallacy: the role of social sciences in constitutional adjudication. Int J Const Law 11:293–318 Petersen N (2013) Avoiding the common-wisdom fallacy: the role of social sciences in constitutional adjudication. Int J Const Law 11:293–318
Zurück zum Zitat Pollak D, Russell D (1976) Dangerous chemicals found leaking from Hooker Dump. Niagara Gazette, 2 November 1976 Pollak D, Russell D (1976) Dangerous chemicals found leaking from Hooker Dump. Niagara Gazette, 2 November 1976
Zurück zum Zitat Ponzetto G, Fernandez P (2008) Case law versus statute law: an evolutionary perspective. J Leg Stud 37:379–430CrossRef Ponzetto G, Fernandez P (2008) Case law versus statute law: an evolutionary perspective. J Leg Stud 37:379–430CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Posner RA (1980) The ethical and political basis of the efficiency norm in common law adjudication. Hofstra Law Rev 8:487–490 Posner RA (1980) The ethical and political basis of the efficiency norm in common law adjudication. Hofstra Law Rev 8:487–490
Zurück zum Zitat Posner RA (1993) What do judges maximize? (The same thing everybody else does). Supreme Court Econ Rev 3:1–41CrossRef Posner RA (1993) What do judges maximize? (The same thing everybody else does). Supreme Court Econ Rev 3:1–41CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Posner RA (2008) How judges think. The University of Chicago Press, Cambridge Posner RA (2008) How judges think. The University of Chicago Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Rachlinski J (2007–2008) Heuristics, biases and philosophy. Tulsa Law Rev 43:865–883 Rachlinski J (2007–2008) Heuristics, biases and philosophy. Tulsa Law Rev 43:865–883
Zurück zum Zitat Simon HA (1991) Bounded rationality and organizational learning. Organ Sci 2:125–134CrossRef Simon HA (1991) Bounded rationality and organizational learning. Organ Sci 2:125–134CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Slovic P, Finucane M, Peters E, MacGregor DG (2002) The affect heuristic. In: Gilovich T, Griffin D, Kahneman D (eds) The psychology of intuitive judgment: heuristics and biases. New York, Cambridge University Press, pp 217–229CrossRef Slovic P, Finucane M, Peters E, MacGregor DG (2002) The affect heuristic. In: Gilovich T, Griffin D, Kahneman D (eds) The psychology of intuitive judgment: heuristics and biases. New York, Cambridge University Press, pp 217–229CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sunstein CR, Vermeule A (2003) Interpretation and institutions. Mich Law Rev 2:885–951CrossRef Sunstein CR, Vermeule A (2003) Interpretation and institutions. Mich Law Rev 2:885–951CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tullock G (1997) The case against the common law. Durham Tullock G (1997) The case against the common law. Durham
Zurück zum Zitat Vermeule A (2006) Judging under uncertainty. An institutional theory of legal interpretation. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Vermeule A (2006) Judging under uncertainty. An institutional theory of legal interpretation. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Wistrich AJ, Rachlinski JJ, Guthrie C (2015) Heart versus head: do judges follow the law or follow their feelings? Texas Law Rev 93:855–923 Wistrich AJ, Rachlinski JJ, Guthrie C (2015) Heart versus head: do judges follow the law or follow their feelings? Texas Law Rev 93:855–923
Zurück zum Zitat Wittneben BBF (2012) The impact of the Fukushima nuclear accident on European energy policy. Environ Sci Pol 15:1–3CrossRef Wittneben BBF (2012) The impact of the Fukushima nuclear accident on European energy policy. Environ Sci Pol 15:1–3CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Creating Social Norms Through Media, Cascades and Cognitive Anchors: Judicial Activism and the Quality of Energy Law from the Perspective of Behavioural Law and Economics
verfasst von
Mariusz J. Golecki
Jarosław Bełdowski
Copyright-Jahr
2018
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-74636-4_10