Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Empirical Economics 6/2020

20.11.2018

Demand for emergency savings is higher for low-income households, but so is the cost of shocks

verfasst von: Scott L. Fulford

Erschienen in: Empirical Economics | Ausgabe 6/2020

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper examines how the precautionary motive varies with income. I first develop a theoretical benchmark of how we would expect precaution to vary with income starting from a basic version of the buffer-stock model. Emergency savings provide a way for households to smooth over shocks and so give insight into the precautionary motive. Using data from the Survey of Consumer Finances in the USA, I show that as income declines, the desired emergency savings relative to income increase, suggesting that low-income households are more precautionary. Observable differences, such as income uncertainty, do not explain the rise. Instead, I propose and estimate a model with a minimum subsistence level and unexpected expenses. The model implies that low-income households are increasingly exposed to shocks, explaining the increase in precaution. Supporting the approach, I show that expenses on repairs are a larger fraction of the spending of low-income households.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Precautionary behavior (Zeldes 1989; Deaton 1991) is central to many models of savings behavior and has been used to explain departures from the simplest life-cycle and permanent income hypothesis models of savings (Hubbard et al. 1995; Carroll 1997; Attanasio et al. 1999; Gourinchas and Parker 2002; Ludvigson and Michaelides 2001; Attanasio and Weber 2010). It is also frequently used as a benchmark for generating inequality in macroeconomic models (Aiyagari 1994; Krusell and Smith 1998) and to understand fluctuations in income and consumption in aggregate (Carroll et al. 1992; Parker and Preston 2005) and so precaution has been central to some of the most important questions of macroeconomics (Gourinchas and Parker 2001) and microeconomics to understanding household savings behavior. It has been used to explain why East German household saved different amounts the West German households following reunification (Fuchs-Schündeln 2008), the investment and savings decisions in Thailand (Kaboski and Townsend 2011), and the effects of banks in India (Fulford 2013).
 
2
See, for example, the campaign American Saves by the Consumer Federation of America, https://​americasaves.​org/​for-savers/​set-a-goal-what-to-save-for/​save-for-emergencies, accessed February 28, 2017. Building an emergency fund is often the first advice of financial “gurus” (see Footnote 3).
 
3
Suze Orman advocates having 6–8 months of income in liquid form (“Emergency Cash Is a Necessity, Not a Luxury” Yahoo! FinanceSuze Orman Money Matters, 2006, available at: http://​finance.​yahoo.​com/​expert/​article/​moneymatters/​7599, accessed December 21, 2010). Dave Ramsey suggests building a $1000 emergency fund as step one, paying off debt as step 2, and then building liquid savings of 3–6 months worth of expenses (“The Seven Baby Steps: Begin your journey to financial peace” Available http://​www.​daveramsey.​com/​new/​baby-steps/​, accessed December 21, 2010). David Bach recommends having savings worth at least 3 months of expenses (The Automatic Millionaire : A Powerful One-Step Plan to Live and Finish Rich, 2004, New York: Broadway Books).
 
4
Surveys that ask about the monetary rather than relative value of emergency savings include the Survey of Consumer Finances used in this paper, the Italian Survey of Household Income and Wealth used by Jappelli et al. (2008), and private surveys whose results are widely reported. For example, in reporting on a Bankrate.com survey “63% Of Americans Don’t Have Enough Savings To Cover A $500 Emergency” by Maggie McGrath (Forbes, January 6, 2016, available at:https://​www.​forbes.​com/​sites/​maggiemcgrath/​2016/​01/​06/​63-of-americans-dont-have-enough-savings-to-cover-a-500-emergency/​, accessed February 28, 2017).
 
5
Recent work that can look at expenditure volatility (measured as the percent change from month to month) within individuals suggests there are few differences across income groups (Farrell and Greig 2017). Even if the risk is the same, the utility costs of the same risks may be higher for lower income households, making them more precautionary.
 
6
See Rubin (1987) and Schafer (1997) for an explanation of multiple imputation, and Kennickell (1998) for an explanation of the multiple imputation procedure in the SCF.
 
7
The emergency savings target mean months of normal income is statistically different between the lowest two quintiles and the highest quintiles. Taking into account the multiple imputation, with 95% confidence the first quintile is significantly larger than each of the other quintiles. Similarly, the second quintile is statistically larger than the third, fourth, and fifth quintiles.
 
8
Since the semi-parametric approach does not easily admit multiple imputation or survey weights, I do not present the estimates of \(\zeta \) separately, but am instead concerned with the general shape of f. I use the same shifters in the parametric analysis later, where the coefficients are reported and the standard errors are corrected for multiple imputation.
 
9
Each of the densities are scaled to be proportional to the relative size of each group in the population, but the densities themselves are calculated from the unweighted survey to show where the nonparametric estimates are most meaningful. The densities are useful for understanding where the semi-parametric estimator has power; if the density is very low, then the slope is being estimated off of few observations and so is unreliable.
 
10
The strong negative slope for the low-income households and the zero coefficient on normal income for high-income households does not depend on the specific dividing line. The results of estimating the same regression as in the third column, but allowing the dividing line to vary are shown in Fig. A-1 in Appendix ESM. The figure shows the coefficient for the high-income, the coefficient for the low-income, and the \(R^{2}\) from the regression. The coefficient on lognormal income for high-income households is statistically indistinguishable from zero when the definition of high-income varies from around $45,000 to above $90,000, and the coefficient estimate is generally very close to zero, especially between $50,000 and $65,000, the interval of the best fit. Similarly, the negative slope with normal income for the low-income is large and significant throughout the entire range of dividing lines. The divide that provides the best fit by the average of \(R^{2}\) across the imputations is $57,526, and so I present the parametric results using this divide.
 
11
There appears to be a strong association between having zero or close to zero housing debt and high precaution, since those who pay < 5% of their income to housing also have a higher precaution. The functional form that the housing costs enter in the estimates is somewhat arbitrary, but the particulars of the form do not seem to matter. Those who owe little or nothing each month hold stronger precautionary preferences, but after zero housing cost the effect appears approximately linear since additional polynomial terms of the fraction spent on housing are neither large nor statistically significant.
 
12
The data used are the 2014 public use micro-data interview survey, available at http://​www.​bls.​gov/​cex/​pumdhome.​htm, accessed December 20, 2015.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aiyagari SR (1994) Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Q J Econ 109(3):659–84CrossRef Aiyagari SR (1994) Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving. Q J Econ 109(3):659–84CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Atkeson A, Ogaki M (1996) Wealth-varying intertemporal elasticities of substitution: evidence from panel and aggregate data. J Monetary Econ 38(3):507–534CrossRef Atkeson A, Ogaki M (1996) Wealth-varying intertemporal elasticities of substitution: evidence from panel and aggregate data. J Monetary Econ 38(3):507–534CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Attanasio OP, Banks J, Meghir C, Weber G (1999) Humps and bumps in lifetime consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 17(1):22–35 Attanasio OP, Banks J, Meghir C, Weber G (1999) Humps and bumps in lifetime consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 17(1):22–35
Zurück zum Zitat Attanasio OP, Weber G (2010) Consumption and saving: models of intertemporal allocation and their implications for public policy. J Econ Lit 48(3):693–751CrossRef Attanasio OP, Weber G (2010) Consumption and saving: models of intertemporal allocation and their implications for public policy. J Econ Lit 48(3):693–751CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bucks BK, Kennickell AB, Mach TL, Moore KB (2009) Changes in U.S. family finances from 2004 to 2007: evidence from the survey of consumer finances. Fed Reserve Bull 95:A1–A56 Bucks BK, Kennickell AB, Mach TL, Moore KB (2009) Changes in U.S. family finances from 2004 to 2007: evidence from the survey of consumer finances. Fed Reserve Bull 95:A1–A56
Zurück zum Zitat Cagetti M (2003) Wealth accumulation over the life cycle and precautionary savings. J Bus Econ Stat 21(3):339–353CrossRef Cagetti M (2003) Wealth accumulation over the life cycle and precautionary savings. J Bus Econ Stat 21(3):339–353CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD (1997) Buffer stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis. Q J Econ 112(1):1–55CrossRef Carroll CD (1997) Buffer stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis. Q J Econ 112(1):1–55CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll C (2001a) Death to the log-linearized consumption Euler equation! (And very poor health to the second-order approximation). Adv Macroecon 1:(1)CrossRef Carroll C (2001a) Death to the log-linearized consumption Euler equation! (And very poor health to the second-order approximation). Adv Macroecon 1:(1)CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD (2001b) A theory of the consumption function, with and without liquidity constraints. J Econ Perspect 15(3):23–45CrossRef Carroll CD (2001b) A theory of the consumption function, with and without liquidity constraints. J Econ Perspect 15(3):23–45CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD (2004) Theoretical foundations of buffer stock saving. NBER working paper no. 10867 Carroll CD (2004) Theoretical foundations of buffer stock saving. NBER working paper no. 10867
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD, Hall RE, Zeldes SP (1992) The buffer-stock theory of saving: some macroeconomic evidence. Brook Pap Econ Act 1992(2):61–156CrossRef Carroll CD, Hall RE, Zeldes SP (1992) The buffer-stock theory of saving: some macroeconomic evidence. Brook Pap Econ Act 1992(2):61–156CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD, Kimball MS (1996) On the concavity of the consumption function. Econometrica 64(4):981–992CrossRef Carroll CD, Kimball MS (1996) On the concavity of the consumption function. Econometrica 64(4):981–992CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD, Samwick AA (1997) The nature of precautionary wealth. J Monetary Econ 40(1):41–71CrossRef Carroll CD, Samwick AA (1997) The nature of precautionary wealth. J Monetary Econ 40(1):41–71CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carroll CD, Samwick AA (1998) How important is precautionary saving? Rev Econ Stat 80(3):410–419CrossRef Carroll CD, Samwick AA (1998) How important is precautionary saving? Rev Econ Stat 80(3):410–419CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Collins JM (ed) (2015) A fragile balance: emergency savings and liquid resources for low-income consumers. Palgrave Macmillan, New York Collins JM (ed) (2015) A fragile balance: emergency savings and liquid resources for low-income consumers. Palgrave Macmillan, New York
Zurück zum Zitat De Nardi M, French E, Jones BJ (2010) Why do the elderly save? The role of medical expenses. J Political Econ 118(1):39–75CrossRef De Nardi M, French E, Jones BJ (2010) Why do the elderly save? The role of medical expenses. J Political Econ 118(1):39–75CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Deaton A (1991) Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59(5):1221–1248CrossRef Deaton A (1991) Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59(5):1221–1248CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dynan KE (1993) How prudent are consumers? J Political Econ 101(6):1104–1113CrossRef Dynan KE (1993) How prudent are consumers? J Political Econ 101(6):1104–1113CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fagereng A, Guiso L, Pistaferri L (2018) Portfolio choices, firm shocks, and uninsurable wage risk. Rev Econ Stud 85(1):437–474 Fagereng A, Guiso L, Pistaferri L (2018) Portfolio choices, firm shocks, and uninsurable wage risk. Rev Econ Stud 85(1):437–474
Zurück zum Zitat Farrell D, Greig F (2017) Coping with costs: big data on expense volatility and medical payments. Technical report, JPMorgan Chase Institute Farrell D, Greig F (2017) Coping with costs: big data on expense volatility and medical payments. Technical report, JPMorgan Chase Institute
Zurück zum Zitat Fuchs-Schündeln N (2008) The response of household saving to the large shock of German reunification. Am Econ Rev 95(5):1798–1828CrossRef Fuchs-Schündeln N (2008) The response of household saving to the large shock of German reunification. Am Econ Rev 95(5):1798–1828CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fulford S (2013) The effects of financial development in the short and long run: theory and evidence from India. J Dev Econ 104:56–72CrossRef Fulford S (2013) The effects of financial development in the short and long run: theory and evidence from India. J Dev Econ 104:56–72CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fulford SL (2015) The surprisingly low importance of income uncertainty for precaution. Eur Econ Rev 79:151–171CrossRef Fulford SL (2015) The surprisingly low importance of income uncertainty for precaution. Eur Econ Rev 79:151–171CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gourinchas P-O, Parker JA (2001) The empirical importance of precautionary saving. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 91(2):406–412CrossRef Gourinchas P-O, Parker JA (2001) The empirical importance of precautionary saving. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 91(2):406–412CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gourinchas P-O, Parker JA (2002) Consumption over the life cycle. Econometrica 70(1):47–89CrossRef Gourinchas P-O, Parker JA (2002) Consumption over the life cycle. Econometrica 70(1):47–89CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guiso L, Jappelli T, Terlizzese D (1992) Earnings uncertainty and precautionary saving. J Monetary Econ 30(2):307–337CrossRef Guiso L, Jappelli T, Terlizzese D (1992) Earnings uncertainty and precautionary saving. J Monetary Econ 30(2):307–337CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hubbard RG, Skinner J, Zeldes SP (1995) Precautionary saving and social insurance. J Political Econ 103(2):360–399CrossRef Hubbard RG, Skinner J, Zeldes SP (1995) Precautionary saving and social insurance. J Political Econ 103(2):360–399CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huggett M (2004) Precautionary wealth accumulation. Rev Econ Stud 71(3):769–781CrossRef Huggett M (2004) Precautionary wealth accumulation. Rev Econ Stud 71(3):769–781CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hurst E, Lusardi A, Kennickell A, Torralba F (2010) The importance of business owners in assessing the size of precautionary savings. Rev Econ Stat 92(1):61–69CrossRef Hurst E, Lusardi A, Kennickell A, Torralba F (2010) The importance of business owners in assessing the size of precautionary savings. Rev Econ Stat 92(1):61–69CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jappelli T, Padula M, Pistaferri L (2008) A direct test of the buffer-stock model of saving. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(6):1186–1210CrossRef Jappelli T, Padula M, Pistaferri L (2008) A direct test of the buffer-stock model of saving. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(6):1186–1210CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kaboski JP, Townsend RM (2011) A structural evaluation of a large-scale quasi-experimental microfinance initiative. Econometrica 79:1357–1406CrossRef Kaboski JP, Townsend RM (2011) A structural evaluation of a large-scale quasi-experimental microfinance initiative. Econometrica 79:1357–1406CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kazarosian M (1997) Precautionary savings—a panel study. Rev Econ Stat 79(2):241–247CrossRef Kazarosian M (1997) Precautionary savings—a panel study. Rev Econ Stat 79(2):241–247CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kennickell A, Annamaria L (2004) Disentangling the importance of the precautionary saving motive. Working paper 10888, NBER Kennickell A, Annamaria L (2004) Disentangling the importance of the precautionary saving motive. Working paper 10888, NBER
Zurück zum Zitat Krusell P, Smith AA Jr (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. J Political Econ 106(5):867–896CrossRef Krusell P, Smith AA Jr (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. J Political Econ 106(5):867–896CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lokshin M (2006) Difference-based semiparametric estimation of partial linear regression models. Stata J 6(3):377–383CrossRef Lokshin M (2006) Difference-based semiparametric estimation of partial linear regression models. Stata J 6(3):377–383CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ludvigson SC, Michaelides A (2001) Does buffer-stock saving explain the smoothness and excess sensitivity of consumption? Am Econ Rev 91(3):631–647CrossRef Ludvigson SC, Michaelides A (2001) Does buffer-stock saving explain the smoothness and excess sensitivity of consumption? Am Econ Rev 91(3):631–647CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ludvigson S, Paxson CH (2001) Approximation bias in linearized Euler equations. Rev Econ Stat 83(2):242–256CrossRef Ludvigson S, Paxson CH (2001) Approximation bias in linearized Euler equations. Rev Econ Stat 83(2):242–256CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lusardi A (1998) On the importance of the precautionary saving motive. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 88(2):449–453 Lusardi A (1998) On the importance of the precautionary saving motive. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 88(2):449–453
Zurück zum Zitat Mabli J, Cohen R, Potter F, Zhao Z (2010) Hunger in America 2010 national report prepared for feeding America. Technical report, Mathematica Policy Research Mabli J, Cohen R, Potter F, Zhao Z (2010) Hunger in America 2010 national report prepared for feeding America. Technical report, Mathematica Policy Research
Zurück zum Zitat Parker JA, Preston B (2005) Precautionary saving and consumption fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 95(4):1119–1143CrossRef Parker JA, Preston B (2005) Precautionary saving and consumption fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 95(4):1119–1143CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rabault G (2002) When do borrowing constraints bind? Some new results on the income fluctuation problem. J Econ Dyn Control 26:217–245CrossRef Rabault G (2002) When do borrowing constraints bind? Some new results on the income fluctuation problem. J Econ Dyn Control 26:217–245CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rubin DB (1987) Multiple imputation for nonresponse in surveys. Wiley, New York Rubin DB (1987) Multiple imputation for nonresponse in surveys. Wiley, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Schafer JL (1997) Analysis of incomplete multivariate data. Chapman & Hall, Boca Raton, FLCrossRef Schafer JL (1997) Analysis of incomplete multivariate data. Chapman & Hall, Boca Raton, FLCrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schechtman J, Escudero VLS (1977) Some results on an ‘income fluctuation problem’. J Econ Theory 16:151–166CrossRef Schechtman J, Escudero VLS (1977) Some results on an ‘income fluctuation problem’. J Econ Theory 16:151–166CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yatchew A (1998) Nonparametric regression techniques in economics. J Econ Lit 36(2):669–721 Yatchew A (1998) Nonparametric regression techniques in economics. J Econ Lit 36(2):669–721
Zurück zum Zitat Zeldes SP (1989) Optimal consumption with stochastic income: deviations from certainty equivalence. Q J Econ 104(2):275–298CrossRef Zeldes SP (1989) Optimal consumption with stochastic income: deviations from certainty equivalence. Q J Econ 104(2):275–298CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Demand for emergency savings is higher for low-income households, but so is the cost of shocks
verfasst von
Scott L. Fulford
Publikationsdatum
20.11.2018
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Empirical Economics / Ausgabe 6/2020
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Elektronische ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1590-9

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 6/2020

Empirical Economics 6/2020 Zur Ausgabe