Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2015

07.01.2016

Does electoral competition affect politicians’ trade policy preferences? Evidence from Japan

verfasst von: Banri Ito

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This study examines the effect of electoral competition on politicians’ trade policy preferences using candidate observations from the House of Representatives in Japan’s 2012 general election. The study clarifies the effects of constituency size and the electoral strength of constituencies on candidates’ political stances. The empirical results provide evidence that politicians’ preferences for trade policy are sensitive to electoral pressure, but their reactions differ depending on the characteristics of each constituency. The results reveal that for a broad constituency with a large concentration of agricultural workers, election candidates are more likely to support protectionism than their counterparts running in a narrow constituency. For city district election candidates, electoral strength measured by the vote margin significantly affects their trade policy preferences. Candidates in close elections are more likely to be protectionist than candidates elected by a substantial majority, suggesting that electoral pressures deter politicians from supporting trade liberalization.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
For example, Magee (1980) and Irwin (1994) examine the correlation between votes for trade bills by congressional representatives and industry characteristics of their constituencies but do not consider skill endowment factors. Similarly, Kaempfer and Marks (1993), Baldwin and Magee (2000) and Beaulieu (2002) examine the determinants of votes for trade liberalization bills by members of the US Congress introducing both skill endowment and industry variables in their representative districts. Mostly, these studies report that both skill endowment and industry characteristics of legislators’ constituencies are correlated with votes on trade policy bills.
 
2
Grossman and Helpman (1994) theoretically explain that the introduction of a trade restriction policy is determined by the contributions of lobbying groups. Baldwin and Magee (2000) and Devault (2010) report that campaign contributions affected legislators’ votes on free trade agreements in the US House of Representatives.
 
3
In the US Congress, one-third of senators are elected every 2 years together with the entire membership of the House of Representatives.
 
4
UTAS is conducted by Masaki Taniguchi of the Graduate Schools for Law and Politics, University of Tokyo and the Asahi Shimbun.
 
5
The survey was conducted with 1504 candidates from 16 November to 16 December 2012 just before the election date, and there were 1404 valid respondents. Of these, 1294 candidates ran in single-seat constituencies. In the election, 480 seats were filled of which 300 were for single-seat districts, and 180 were elected by the proportional representation system. A candidate who belongs to a political party is allowed to run for the election in both a single-seat constituency and a proportional representation district. The seat allocation for the proportional representation system by fixed list uses the D’Hondt formula, and in cases where the same order in the list is allowed in the system, the candidate with a high loss margin in the single-seat constituency is elected.
 
6
Significant cases in which dissension resulted in the dissolution of parliament are the postal bills in 2005, the budget bill in 2011 and the bill to raise the consumption tax in 2012.
 
7
The survey was conducted with 10,816 randomly selected individuals located throughout Japan in 2011, who were asked the following question. “Do you agree with the following statement? We should further liberalize imports to make wider varieties of goods available at lower prices.” The responses were as follows: “strongly agree” (8.9 %), “somewhat agree” (42.5 %), “somewhat disagree” (26.9 %), “strongly disagree” (4.6 %), and “cannot choose or unsure” (17.1 %) (Tomiura et al. 2013). Additionally, this result differs from the US where most people oppose trade liberalization (Scheve and Slaughter 2001; Mayda and Rodrik 2005).
 
8
The World Tariff Profiles 2014 report that Japan’s average most favored nation applied tariff rate on agricultural products is 19 %, which is significantly higher than that of the EU (13.2 %) or the US (5.3 %). In particular, the tariff rate on some commodities is extremely high. For example, the tariff on rice is equivalent to 778 %, and the tariff on butter is 360 %. However, the average tariff rate on non-agricultural products in Japan is 2.6 %, which is lower than that of the EU (4.2 %) and the US (3.1 %).
 
9
Sympathy for farmers may be one of the reasons, as suggested by Naoi and Kume (2011), who examine the determinants of support for agricultural protectionism based on an experimental survery. They show that producer-priming respondents rather than consumer-priming respondents increase opposition to food import among 1200 respondents in Japan.
 
10
The authors use the Americans for Democratic Action score as a measurement of representatives’ policy positions.
 
11
There are no official statistics at the constituency level. Therefore, this study constructs data by aggregating data from the 2010 national census disaggregated into the “cyocyo” level, which is the smallest unit of address in a municipality, similar to a “street” level.
 
12
Politicians can receive donations from corporations because the law allows free movement of money between a political party and politicians. To some extent, party dummy variables are expected to control for the possible effects of political contributions through this legal loophole.
 
13
According to trade volume statistics in 2013, the US was Japan’s largest export destination and the second largest origin of imports. Japan’s share of trade with the US is 26.9 % of its total trade volume.
 
14
Although multicollinearity may be of concern, a correlation matrix among the explanatory variables does not show significantly high correlation coefficients.
 
15
See Scheve and Slaughter (2001), Mayda and Rodrik (2005), Blonigen (2011) and Ito et al. (2015).
 
16
The estimation results from the bivariate probit model are similar to those from the probit model shown in Tables 3 and 6. These results are available upon request.
 
17
For causality, using the number of votes of the last election may be appropriate, but that would sacrifice the sample of newcomers who comprise 61 % of the total sample.
 
18
A hereditary candidate is defined as one who has a relative within the third degree of relation who was a Diet member and an individual who aims to succeed that member in the entire electoral district or some part of the district. Alternatively, a hereditary candidate is an individual with a parent who was a Diet member, even if the candidate does not succeed the parent in the district. According to the definition, 11 % (140 people) of the total number of candidates (1294 people) were hereditary candidates who ran from single-seat constituencies, and 80 % (112 people) of those were elected.
 
19
For the full specification without interaction terms, the Smith-Blundell test statistic is 0.481, and the P-value is 0.786. Even in the case where margin or broad is treated as an endogenous variable, the exogeneity is not rejected. The estimation results from the probit model with endogenous variables are available upon request.
 
20
It is not compulsory to vote in public elections in Japan. Japan’s participation ratios are significantly lower than are those of the US (67.95 %) and UK (65.77 %) and are closer to those of France (55.4 %).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Albouy, D. (2011). Do voters affect or elect policies? A new perspective, with evidence from the US Senate. Electoral Studies, 30, 162–173.CrossRef Albouy, D. (2011). Do voters affect or elect policies? A new perspective, with evidence from the US Senate. Electoral Studies, 30, 162–173.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. American Economic Review, 78, 796–805. Alesina, A. (1988). Credibility and policy convergence in a two-party system with rational voters. American Economic Review, 78, 796–805.
Zurück zum Zitat Baldwin, R. E. (1985). The political economy of US import policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Baldwin, R. E. (1985). The political economy of US import policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Baldwin, R. E., & Magee, C. S. (2000). Is trade policy for sale? Congressional voting on recent trade bills. Public Choice, 105, 79–101.CrossRef Baldwin, R. E., & Magee, C. S. (2000). Is trade policy for sale? Congressional voting on recent trade bills. Public Choice, 105, 79–101.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beaulieu, E. (2002). The Stolper-Samuelson theorem faces congress. Review of International Economics, 10, 343–360.CrossRef Beaulieu, E. (2002). The Stolper-Samuelson theorem faces congress. Review of International Economics, 10, 343–360.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blonigen, B. (2011). Revisiting the evidence on trade policy preferences. Journal of International Economics., 85, 129–135.CrossRef Blonigen, B. (2011). Revisiting the evidence on trade policy preferences. Journal of International Economics., 85, 129–135.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Conconi, P., Facchini, G., & Zanardi, M. (2014). Policymakers’ horizon and trade reforms: The protectionist effect of elections. Journal of International Economics, 94, 102–188.CrossRef Conconi, P., Facchini, G., & Zanardi, M. (2014). Policymakers’ horizon and trade reforms: The protectionist effect of elections. Journal of International Economics, 94, 102–188.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, G. (1987). Electoral equilibrium under alternative voting institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 82–108.CrossRef Cox, G. (1987). Electoral equilibrium under alternative voting institutions. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 82–108.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cox, G. (1990). Centripetal and centrifugal incentives in electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 34, 903–935.CrossRef Cox, G. (1990). Centripetal and centrifugal incentives in electoral systems. American Journal of Political Science, 34, 903–935.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Devault, J. (2010). CAFTA, campaign contributions, and the role of special interests. Economics and Politics, 22, 282–297.CrossRef Devault, J. (2010). CAFTA, campaign contributions, and the role of special interests. Economics and Politics, 22, 282–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ehrlich, S. D. (2009). Constituency size and support for trade liberalization: An analysis of foreign economic policy preferences in congress. Foreign Policy Analysis, 5, 215–232.CrossRef Ehrlich, S. D. (2009). Constituency size and support for trade liberalization: An analysis of foreign economic policy preferences in congress. Foreign Policy Analysis, 5, 215–232.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review, 81, 1146–1155. Fernandez, R., & Rodrik, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty. American Economic Review, 81, 1146–1155.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850. Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84, 833–850.
Zurück zum Zitat Irwin, D. (1994). The political economy of free trade. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 75–108.CrossRef Irwin, D. (1994). The political economy of free trade. Journal of Law and Economics, 37, 75–108.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Irwin, D., & Kroszner, R. (1999). Interests, institutions and ideology in securing policy change: The republican conversion to trade liberalization after Smoot–Hawley. Journal of Law and Economics, 17, 643–673.CrossRef Irwin, D., & Kroszner, R. (1999). Interests, institutions and ideology in securing policy change: The republican conversion to trade liberalization after Smoot–Hawley. Journal of Law and Economics, 17, 643–673.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ito, B., Mukunoki, H., Tomiura, E., & Wakasugi, R. (2015). Trade policy preferences and cross-regional differences: Evidence from individual-level data of Japan. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-003. Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. Ito, B., Mukunoki, H., Tomiura, E., & Wakasugi, R. (2015). Trade policy preferences and cross-regional differences: Evidence from individual-level data of Japan. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 15-E-003. Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry.
Zurück zum Zitat Kaempfer, W. H., & Marks, S. V. (1993). The expected effects of trade liberalization: Evidence from US congressional action on fast-track authority. World Economy, 16, 725–740.CrossRef Kaempfer, W. H., & Marks, S. V. (1993). The expected effects of trade liberalization: Evidence from US congressional action on fast-track authority. World Economy, 16, 725–740.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Karol, D. (2007). Does constituency size affect elected officials’ trade policy preferences? Journal of Politics, 69, 470–482. Karol, D. (2007). Does constituency size affect elected officials’ trade policy preferences? Journal of Politics, 69, 470–482.
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, D. S., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. J. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? Evidence from the US. house. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 807–859.CrossRef Lee, D. S., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. J. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? Evidence from the US. house. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 807–859.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Magee, S. P. (1980). Three simple tests of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. In G. M. Grossman & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Issues in international economics (pp. 185–199). Stockfield: Oriel Press. Magee, S. P. (1980). Three simple tests of the Stolper-Samuelson theorem. In G. M. Grossman & K. Rogoff (Eds.), Issues in international economics (pp. 185–199). Stockfield: Oriel Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E. D., & Busch, M. L. (1995). The political economy of nontariff barriers: A cross-national analysis. International Organization, 49, 723–749.CrossRef Mansfield, E. D., & Busch, M. L. (1995). The political economy of nontariff barriers: A cross-national analysis. International Organization, 49, 723–749.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mayda, A., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Why are some people (and countries) more protectionist than others? European Economic Review, 49, 1393–1430.CrossRef Mayda, A., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Why are some people (and countries) more protectionist than others? European Economic Review, 49, 1393–1430.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging industry: The comparative politics of trade and industrial policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging industry: The comparative politics of trade and industrial policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Naoi, M., & Kume, I. (2011). Explaining mass support for agricultural protectionism: Evidence from a survey experiment during the global recession. International Organization, 65, 771–795.CrossRef Naoi, M., & Kume, I. (2011). Explaining mass support for agricultural protectionism: Evidence from a survey experiment during the global recession. International Organization, 65, 771–795.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nielson, D. L. (2003). Supplying trade reform: Political institutions and liberalization in middle-income presidential democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 470–491.CrossRef Nielson, D. L. (2003). Supplying trade reform: Political institutions and liberalization in middle-income presidential democracies. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 470–491.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Park, H. L., & Jensen, N. (2007). Electoral competition and agricultural support in OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 51(2), 314–329.CrossRef Park, H. L., & Jensen, N. (2007). Electoral competition and agricultural support in OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 51(2), 314–329.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Pew Research Center. (2014). Faith and skepticism about trade, foreign investment. Pew Research Center. (2014). Faith and skepticism about trade, foreign investment.
Zurück zum Zitat Rogowski, R. (1987). Trade and the variety of democratic institutions. International Organization, 41, 203–223.CrossRef Rogowski, R. (1987). Trade and the variety of democratic institutions. International Organization, 41, 203–223.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rogowski, R., & Kayser, M. A. (2002). Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: Price-level evidence from the OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 526–540.CrossRef Rogowski, R., & Kayser, M. A. (2002). Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: Price-level evidence from the OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 526–540.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Scheve, K., & Slaughter, M. (2001). What determines individual trade-policy preferences? Journal of International Economics, 54, 267–292.CrossRef Scheve, K., & Slaughter, M. (2001). What determines individual trade-policy preferences? Journal of International Economics, 54, 267–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, R., & Blindell, R. (1986). An exogeneity test for a simultaneous equation tobit model with an application to labor supply. Econometrica, 54(3), 679–685.CrossRef Smith, R., & Blindell, R. (1986). An exogeneity test for a simultaneous equation tobit model with an application to labor supply. Econometrica, 54(3), 679–685.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tomiura, E., Ito, B., Mukunoki, H., & Wakasugi, R. (2013). Endowment effect and trade policy preferences: Evidence from a survey on individuals. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 13-E-009. Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry. Tomiura, E., Ito, B., Mukunoki, H., & Wakasugi, R. (2013). Endowment effect and trade policy preferences: Evidence from a survey on individuals. RIETI Discussion Paper Series 13-E-009. Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry.
Zurück zum Zitat Tomz, M. (2007). Domestic audience costs in international relations: An experimental approach. International Organization, 61(4), 821–840.CrossRef Tomz, M. (2007). Domestic audience costs in international relations: An experimental approach. International Organization, 61(4), 821–840.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Does electoral competition affect politicians’ trade policy preferences? Evidence from Japan
verfasst von
Banri Ito
Publikationsdatum
07.01.2016
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2015
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0306-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Public Choice 3-4/2015 Zur Ausgabe