Skip to main content

Tipp

Weitere Artikel dieser Ausgabe durch Wischen aufrufen

Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare 3/2021

27.03.2021 | Original Paper

Does public debt secure social peace? A diversionary theory of public debt management

verfasst von: Maxime Menuet, Patrick Villieu, Marcel Voia

Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare | Ausgabe 3/2021

Einloggen, um Zugang zu erhalten
share
TEILEN

Abstract

This study analyzes the strategic use of public debt. Contrary to the classical view that politicians can use public debt to tie the hands of their successors, we show that an incumbent government can take advantage of having tied its own hands before the election with the help of public debt. By doing this, it reduces the basis for future social conflicts and benefits from social peace during its term, which may enhance its chances of being re-elected. In addition, in the case of foreign or external public debt, the incumbent can strategically divert future social conflicts toward a common enemy (foreign creditors). Thus, by increasing public debt before the election, the incumbent can strengthen social cohesion during his/her mandate, both by reducing the basis of internal conflicts and by diverting citizens from internal toward external rent-seeking activities.

Sie möchten Zugang zu diesem Inhalt erhalten? Dann informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 69.000 Bücher
  • über 500 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt 90 Tage mit der neuen Mini-Lizenz testen!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 58.000 Bücher
  • über 300 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko





Jetzt 90 Tage mit der neuen Mini-Lizenz testen!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
In the United States, for example, Peltzman (1992) shows that electors punish politicians who let public spending increase. The explanation is related to progressive fiscal systems: on average, voters are wealthier than non-voters and penalize spender incumbents because they will pay the price of future fiscal adjustments. Such fiscal “conservatism” of electors is also found by Bertola and Drazen (1993) and Brender and Drazen (2008), who show, using a sample of 74 countries from 1960 to 2003, that pre-election deficits reduce the chances of the incumbent being re-elected. Garmann (2017) shows that if voters are highly fiscally conservative, incumbents can even decrease spending before elections.
 
2
The intuition that debt can be used to manage social conflicts is not new. Capital structure theories (see, e.g., Grossman and Hart 1982; Jensen 1986; Stulz 1990, among others) emphasize the role played by corporate debt in reducing agency conflicts among workers, managers, and shareholders. Specifically, by increasing the probability of failure, private debt exerts a threat that can discipline workers by forcing them to accept low wages and poor working conditions. In this study, we show that the same type of argument can apply to public debt, which can be used as a disciplining device to limit rent-seeking behavior during the term.
 
3
This cohesion effect has been raised by a large number of social psychology and anthropology studies. For example, Sumner (1906) first introduced the term ethnocentrism and developed the idea that “the exigencies of war with outsiders are what make peace inside. (...) These exigencies also make government and law in the in-group, in order to prevent quarrels and enforce discipline.” Such a concept is introduced in a formal model of rent-seeking by Münster and Staal (2011). Their study provides one of the first economic models with simultaneous conflicts at different levels (see also Katz et al. 1990). However, Münster and Staal (2011) use a static setup and do not study electoral competition, while our model is dynamic and mixes the rent-seeking and probabilistic voting approaches. Moreover, in their model, there is conflict either between or within groups, but not both at the same time (in the basic case in which all players decide simultaneously and independently how to allocate their resources), while both conflicts can appear simultaneously in our setup. This is an important point because by using public debt, an incumbent can move the weight of internal and external conflicts according to his/her preferences.
 
4
See, for example, Pettersson-Lidbom (2001), Hodler (2011) and Kirchgässner (2014).
 
5
In the same vein, Aghion and Bolton (1990) present an interesting model in which the incumbent has an incentive to accumulate excessive public debt because he/she can more credibly commit not to default than his/her opponent.
 
6
In Alesina and Tabellini (1990), the incumbent has a chance of being re-elected, albeit his/her exact chances are uncertain; in Persson and Svensson (1989), the current government is certain to be removed.
 
7
For example, Hodler (2011) finds that the incumbent never manipulates his/her opponent’s public spending if he/she can ensure his/her own re-election.
 
8
We restrict our analysis to internal conflicts since external conflicts are not publicly available in Canada. The data on provincial internal conflicts come from the following sources (listed in Appendix A in Supplementary Material): “A Brief History of Canada”, “Riots and civil disorder in Canada”, “List of conflicts in Canada” and “History Since Confederation”. The data on provincial debt and economic measures come from Statistics Canada and the data on elections come from the Elections Canada website.
 
9
To appropriately account for the relationship between a discrete and a continuous variable, we investigate the polychoric correlation of Drasgow (1986). The polychoric correlation measures the association between ordered or categorical variables and one or multiple continuous variables.
 
10
Arguably, the events in Quebec are often related to issues of independence. This exclusion could also serve as a robustness check.
 
11
The CF approach’s advantage is that it allows for a simple endogeneity test via a Wald test (Wooldridge 2015). Given that the annual provincial debt per federal GNP was found to be endogenous, we implement the CF bias correction approach. The CF is a correction term needed as an additional regressor in the main equation of interest, as the outcome of interest is binary. A standard instrumental variables procedure cannot be applied to discrete outcomes.
 
12
As one may think that specific economic conditions might relate the mortgage rate to social unrest, through firm closures that induce industry instability and potentially lead to individual bankruptcy and foreclosures (see Huynh et al. 2010, 2017, for Canada), we checked if this potential argument is valid for Canada. Our findings suggest that for Canada, the bankruptcies are not positively correlated with the mortgage rates (we found a correlation of − 0.105 between bankruptcy and mortgage rates). Furthermore, the correlation between mortgage rates and social unrest is insignificant, the correlation below 0.005. Additionally, to the mortgage rate we consider the lag of the mortgage rate as an exclusion restriction, and the quality of the results did not change. Therefore, for Canada’s case, the proposed exclusion restrictions (mortgage rate and its square) also satisfy the conditional independence assumption as in Abadie et al. (2002).
 
13
We also test a penalized version of the logistic model that relates to rare events and the results remain unchanged.
 
14
After the election, the debt burden can be renegotiated inside the federation. Some districts can obtain debt alleviations, bailouts, or specific assistance from the federal budget depending on their bargaining power. Since the federal budget must be balanced, other districts will have to pay for these measures, which produces inter-district conflicts about the repayment of public debt.
 
15
We could also assume that there is a private good and that citizens’ utility (6) is consumption-augmented. In this case, citizens consume their net income (\((1-\tau )Y_{t}/M\) in a symmetric configuration), and our results are qualitatively unchanged.
 
16
Strictly speaking, this public good is an impure public good (i.e., a common good).
 
17
An axiomatic foundation is provided by Skaperdas (1996).
 
18
Thus, in the second period, the mere fact of having been the incumbent or challenger in the election may roughly characterize the “type” of office-holder.
 
19
This finding echoes the traditional diversionary hypothesis (see Wright 1965; Mansfield and Snyder 2004), which suggests that leaders might trigger conflict with other groups to deflect attention from problems at home. Wright states that “foreign war as a remedy for internal tension, revolution, or insurrection has been an accepted principle of government” (Wright 1965, p. 140).
 
20
To simplify our analysis, the decisiveness parameter of external conflicts (b) does not depend on the type of office-holder, contrary to that of internal conflicts (\(a^j\)). However, we could easily introduce different parameters such that \(b^I \ne b^O\). This assumption would unnecessarily complicate the model without affecting our results.
 
21
Each citizen is endowed with one unit of time. For simplicity, citizens simultaneously and independently decide how to allocate their resources to productive and unproductive activities.
 
22
A positive (resp. negative) value of \(\theta _{n}\) implies that citizen n has a bias in favor of the incumbent (resp. the challenger), whereas citizens with \(\theta _{n}=0\) are ideologically neutral. Further, w measures citizens’ responsiveness to rent-seeking activities. As w increases, citizens care more about rent captation than ideology (see Eq. 15).
 
23
Many empirical works support this specification. For example, the well-known “rally ’round the flag syndrome” suggests that external conflicts often boost the popularity of leaders (Grieco et al. 2014, p. 199). For example, some US presidents have enjoyed extra short-run popular support during the outbreak of international crises or wars (as, e.g., Lian and Oneal 1993; Hetherington and Nelson 2003, among others).
 
24
Power rents are assumed to be purely psychological. This avoids introducing an unnecessary additional conflict between the government and district i citizens.
 
25
Indeed, in the symmetric equilibrium, we have \(\partial \psi ({{\hat{{\mathbf {y}}}}}_{2})/\partial e=-b{\tilde{N}}/e\). The second-order condition is verified since \(e\mapsto \psi ({{\hat{{\mathbf {y}}}}}_2)\) is a convex mapping.
 
26
Hence, following Munster’s (2007) definition, our model exhibits only a “reversed group cohesion” effect.
 
27
The second-order condition is satisfied since \((\alpha ^I)''(\cdot )<0\) (see Appendix B in Supplementary Material).
 
28
There is an interior solution, provided that h is sufficiently small.
 
29
In the same year, the United States also benefited from such a windfall fiscal gain, with the same effect on citizens’ claims, due to strong April tax revenues (the so-called April Surprise), allowing a reevaluation of the primary budget surplus close to 50%.
 
30
For example, Prime Minister A. Tsipras was claimed in 2016 that creditors have worsened the Greek crisis. See, e.g., https://​www.​theguardian.​com/​world/​2016/​sep/​11/​alexis-tsipras-greece-criticises-creditors-thessaloniki.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Abadie A, Angrist J, Imbens G (2002) Instrumental variables estimates of the effect of subsidized training on the quantiles of trainee earnings. Econometrica 70:91–117 CrossRef Abadie A, Angrist J, Imbens G (2002) Instrumental variables estimates of the effect of subsidized training on the quantiles of trainee earnings. Econometrica 70:91–117 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion P, Bolton PP (1990) Government domestic debt and the risk of default: a political-economic model of the strategic role of government Debt. In: Dornbusch R, Draghi M (eds) Public debt management: theory, history. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 315–344 CrossRef Aghion P, Bolton PP (1990) Government domestic debt and the risk of default: a political-economic model of the strategic role of government Debt. In: Dornbusch R, Draghi M (eds) Public debt management: theory, history. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 315–344 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina A, Tabellini G (1990) A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Rev Econ Stud 57:403–414 CrossRef Alesina A, Tabellini G (1990) A positive theory of fiscal deficits and government debt. Rev Econ Stud 57:403–414 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ardagna S, Caselli F (2014) The political economy of the Greek debt crisis: a tale of two bailouts. Am Econ J Macroecon 6:291–323 CrossRef Ardagna S, Caselli F (2014) The political economy of the Greek debt crisis: a tale of two bailouts. Am Econ J Macroecon 6:291–323 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertola G, Drazen A (1993) Trigger points and budget cuts: explaining the effects of fiscal austerity. Am Econ Rev 83:11–26 Bertola G, Drazen A (1993) Trigger points and budget cuts: explaining the effects of fiscal austerity. Am Econ Rev 83:11–26
Zurück zum Zitat Brender A, Drazen A (2008) How do budget deficits and economic growth affect reelection prospects? Evidence from a large panel of countries. Am Econ Rev 98:2203–2220 CrossRef Brender A, Drazen A (2008) How do budget deficits and economic growth affect reelection prospects? Evidence from a large panel of countries. Am Econ Rev 98:2203–2220 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Drasgow F (1986) Polychoric and polyserial correlations. In: Kotz S, Johnson N (eds) The encyclopedia of statistics, vol 7. Wiley, pp 68–74 Drasgow F (1986) Polychoric and polyserial correlations. In: Kotz S, Johnson N (eds) The encyclopedia of statistics, vol 7. Wiley, pp 68–74
Zurück zum Zitat Garmann S (2017) Political budget cycles and fiscally conservative voters. Econ Lett 155:72–75 CrossRef Garmann S (2017) Political budget cycles and fiscally conservative voters. Econ Lett 155:72–75 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grieco J, Ikenberry GJ, Mastanduno M (2014) Introduction to international relations. Palgrave Grieco J, Ikenberry GJ, Mastanduno M (2014) Introduction to international relations. Palgrave
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman SJ, Hart OD (1982) Corporate financial structure and managerial incentives. The economics of information and uncertainty. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 107–140 Grossman SJ, Hart OD (1982) Corporate financial structure and managerial incentives. The economics of information and uncertainty. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 107–140
Zurück zum Zitat Heckman J, Robb R (1985) Alternative methods for evaluating the impact of interventions. J Econom 30:239–267 CrossRef Heckman J, Robb R (1985) Alternative methods for evaluating the impact of interventions. J Econom 30:239–267 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hetherington MJ, Nelson M (2003) Anatomy of a rally effect: George W. Bush and the war on terrorism. Polit Sci Polit 36:37–42 CrossRef Hetherington MJ, Nelson M (2003) Anatomy of a rally effect: George W. Bush and the war on terrorism. Polit Sci Polit 36:37–42 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirshleifer J (1989) Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice 63:101–112 CrossRef Hirshleifer J (1989) Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice 63:101–112 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hirshleifer J (2008) Anarchy and its breakdown. In: Garfinkel MR, Skaperdas IS (eds) The political economy of conflict and appropriation, chapter 2. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Hirshleifer J (2008) Anarchy and its breakdown. In: Garfinkel MR, Skaperdas IS (eds) The political economy of conflict and appropriation, chapter 2. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Hodler R (2011) Elections and the strategic use of budget deficits. Public Choice 148:149–161 CrossRef Hodler R (2011) Elections and the strategic use of budget deficits. Public Choice 148:149–161 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huynh K, Petrunia R, Voia M (2010) The impact of initial financial state on firm duration across entry cohorts. J Ind Econ 58:661–689 CrossRef Huynh K, Petrunia R, Voia M (2010) The impact of initial financial state on firm duration across entry cohorts. J Ind Econ 58:661–689 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huynh K, Ostrovsky Y, Petrunia R, Voia M (2017) Industry shutdown rates and permanent layoffs: evidence from firm-worker matched data. IZA J Labor Econ 6:7 CrossRef Huynh K, Ostrovsky Y, Petrunia R, Voia M (2017) Industry shutdown rates and permanent layoffs: evidence from firm-worker matched data. IZA J Labor Econ 6:7 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen MC (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. Am Econ Rev 76:323–329 Jensen MC (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. Am Econ Rev 76:323–329
Zurück zum Zitat Katsikas D (2012) The Greek crisis and the search for political leadership. Int Spect Ital J Int Affairs 47:49–56 Katsikas D (2012) The Greek crisis and the search for political leadership. Int Spect Ital J Int Affairs 47:49–56
Zurück zum Zitat Katz E, Nitzan S, Rosenberg J (1990) Rent seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice 65:49–60 CrossRef Katz E, Nitzan S, Rosenberg J (1990) Rent seeking for pure public goods. Public Choice 65:49–60 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kernell S (1978) Explaining presidential popularity: how ad hoc theorizing, misplaced emphasis, and insufficient care in measuring one’s variables refuted common sense and led conventional wisdom down the path of anomalies. Am Polit Sci Rev 72:506–522 CrossRef Kernell S (1978) Explaining presidential popularity: how ad hoc theorizing, misplaced emphasis, and insufficient care in measuring one’s variables refuted common sense and led conventional wisdom down the path of anomalies. Am Polit Sci Rev 72:506–522 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kirchgässner G (2014) On the political economy of public deficits and debt. German Econ Rev 15:116–130 CrossRef Kirchgässner G (2014) On the political economy of public deficits and debt. German Econ Rev 15:116–130 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Levine RA, Campbell DT (1972) Ethnocentrism: theories of conflict, ethnic attitudes and group conflict. Wiley, New York Levine RA, Campbell DT (1972) Ethnocentrism: theories of conflict, ethnic attitudes and group conflict. Wiley, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Levy J (1989) Conflict resolution in elementary and secondary education. Confl Resolut Q 7:73–87 Levy J (1989) Conflict resolution in elementary and secondary education. Confl Resolut Q 7:73–87
Zurück zum Zitat Lian B, Oneal JR (1993) Presidents, the use of military force, and public opinion. J Confl Resolut 37:277–300 CrossRef Lian B, Oneal JR (1993) Presidents, the use of military force, and public opinion. J Confl Resolut 37:277–300 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lindbeck A, Weibull J (1987) Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice 52:273–297 CrossRef Lindbeck A, Weibull J (1987) Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice 52:273–297 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield ED, Snyder J (2004) Electing to fight. MIT Press, Cambridge Mansfield ED, Snyder J (2004) Electing to fight. MIT Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Mueller JE (1973) War, presidents, and public opinion. Wiley, New York Mueller JE (1973) War, presidents, and public opinion. Wiley, New York
Zurück zum Zitat Münster J (2007) Simultaneous inter- and intra-groups conflicts. Econ Theory 32(2):333–352 CrossRef Münster J (2007) Simultaneous inter- and intra-groups conflicts. Econ Theory 32(2):333–352 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Münster J, Staal K (2011) War with outsiders makes peace inside. Confl Manag Peace Sci 28:91–110 CrossRef Münster J, Staal K (2011) War with outsiders makes peace inside. Confl Manag Peace Sci 28:91–110 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nordhaus WD (1975) The political business cycle. Rev Econ Stud 42:169–190 CrossRef Nordhaus WD (1975) The political business cycle. Rev Econ Stud 42:169–190 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Peltzman S (1992) Voters as fiscal conservatives. Q J Econ 107:327–361 CrossRef Peltzman S (1992) Voters as fiscal conservatives. Q J Econ 107:327–361 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Persson T, Svensson L (1989) Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: policy with time-inconsistent preferences. Q J Econ 104:325–346 CrossRef Persson T, Svensson L (1989) Why a stubborn conservative would run a deficit: policy with time-inconsistent preferences. Q J Econ 104:325–346 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Persson T, Tabellini G (2000) Political economics: explaining economic policy. MIT Press, Cambridge Persson T, Tabellini G (2000) Political economics: explaining economic policy. MIT Press, Cambridge
Zurück zum Zitat Pettersson-Lidbom P (2001) An empirical investigation of the strategic use of debt. J Polit Econ 109:570–583 CrossRef Pettersson-Lidbom P (2001) An empirical investigation of the strategic use of debt. J Polit Econ 109:570–583 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rogoff K, Sibert A (1988) Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Rev Econ Stud 55:1–16 CrossRef Rogoff K, Sibert A (1988) Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles. Rev Econ Stud 55:1–16 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Skaperdas S (1996) Contest success functions. Econ Theory 7:283–290 CrossRef Skaperdas S (1996) Contest success functions. Econ Theory 7:283–290 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stein AA (1976) Conflict and cohesion: a review of the literature. J Confl Resolut 20:143–172 CrossRef Stein AA (1976) Conflict and cohesion: a review of the literature. J Confl Resolut 20:143–172 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stulz R (1990) Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. J Financ Econ 26:3–27 CrossRef Stulz R (1990) Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. J Financ Econ 26:3–27 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sumner WG (1906) Folkways, a study of the sociological importance of usages, manners, customs, mores, and morals. Ginn Sumner WG (1906) Folkways, a study of the sociological importance of usages, manners, customs, mores, and morals. Ginn
Zurück zum Zitat Tajfel H (1982) Social psychology of intergroup relations. Annu Rev Psychol 33:1–39 CrossRef Tajfel H (1982) Social psychology of intergroup relations. Annu Rev Psychol 33:1–39 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wooldridge JM (2015) Control function methods in applied econometrics. J Hum Resour 50:420–445 CrossRef Wooldridge JM (2015) Control function methods in applied econometrics. J Hum Resour 50:420–445 CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wright Q (1965) A study of war. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Wright Q (1965) A study of war. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Metadaten
Titel
Does public debt secure social peace? A diversionary theory of public debt management
verfasst von
Maxime Menuet
Patrick Villieu
Marcel Voia
Publikationsdatum
27.03.2021
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Social Choice and Welfare / Ausgabe 3/2021
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Elektronische ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-021-01332-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3/2021

Social Choice and Welfare 3/2021 Zur Ausgabe

Premium Partner