Skip to main content

2016 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Economic Evidence in Competition Law Enforcement in India

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter seeks to understand the apprehension and reluctance in the use of economic evidence observed in the enforcement of the competition law in India. Incorporation of economic theory and sophistication of data interpretation are now considered critical for defining the market and of consumer harm in mature competition jurisdiction. Reluctance for economic evidence is an apprehension emanating from the belief that economic analysis is oriented to efficiency criteria rather than of equity consequently fails to capture the idiosyncrasies of an emerging market. Taken from a total welfare viewpoint or a rigorous consumer welfare angle decisions based on economic evidence may have been different. A precipitous analysis of competition in some of the illustrations runs the risk of distorting competition and market functioning.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
Kuhn, Kai-Uwe (2013) ‘Good Economics in Administrative proceedings: Three Challenge’s’ Concurrences, Competition Law Journal, No. 3. Daniel Sokol notes a similar trend in the early years of the European Commission and observes a change towards economic evidence in recent years comparing the difference in approach between the U.S. Department of Justice and the European Commission, Daniel Sokol & Roger D. Blair, ‘Welfare Standards in U.S. and E.U. Anti-Trust Enforcement’, Fordham Law Review, vol. 81, pp. 2497–2541.
 
2
Tata Engineering & Locomotive Co. Ltd., Bombay v. Registrar of the Restrictive Trade Agreement, New Delhi ((1977)2 SCC 55), the Supreme Court held that the “rule of reason” is to be applied in evaluating certain types of agreements relating to restrictive trade practices and in the subsequent Mahindra & Mahindra v. Union of India ((1979)2SCC529) decision referred to various US antitrust judgments. These judgments were taken as landmark decisions to the run up to the Competition Act. The Competition Act 2002 was enacted over a decade after economic liberalization policies were initiated. The emphasis of these policies was on market orientation and an open economy.
 
3
Decision of the Competition Appellate Tribunal (COMPAT) Schott Glass India Pvt. Ltd., v Competition Commission of India (Appeal No. 91 of 2012, 2 April 2014). The Appellant Tribunal is the first tier of reference after the Commission. The COMPAT Order has been challenged before the Supreme Court.
 
4
National Stock Exchange of India Limited v Competition Commission of India and Another (Appeal No. 15 of 2011, August 2014).
 
5
Sec. 3(3) deals with Horizontal Agreements; Sec. 3(4) with vertical agreements; Sec.4 is on Abuse of Dominance; Sec. 5 & 6 are for Mergers and Acquisitions (Combinations) under the Competition Act, 2002.
 
6
Horizontal Merger Guidelines of U.S. Department of Justice is the reference manual.
 
7
Competition Act, 2002, See Section 19(3) and 20(4). Sec. 19(4) relating to abuse of dominance lists out factors that determine dominance. Sub-clause (g); (h) is open to different interpretations. Section 19(3) outlines the factors when an ‘agreement’ under Section 3 has an appreciable adverse effect on competition (AAEC) and Section 20(4) on factors to be considered for merger clearances.
 
8
Merger cases for clearance from the Commission was after notification of the relevant sections (5 & 6) only in 2011 i.e. full two years after the Act became operational in May 2009. Complex cases are those which go into Form II with strong possibility of raising anti-competitive outcomes and therefore require more data and market analysis.
 
9
See Shapiro Carl, (1995), ‘Aftermarkets and Consumer Welfare: Making Sense of Kodak’, Antitrust Law Journal, Vol. 63, pp. 483–511
 
10
Case No. 3/2011, Shamsher Kataria v Honda /Siel car and Ors. (dated 25/8/14). In India the servicing market consists of authorized service stations of the respective car maker and the local garages and service stations. Spare parts again are sold in authorized service stations and in retails dealer showrooms. Several spare parts are copied and manufactured and sold in spare part shops all over.
 
11
Order refers to the Orders of CCI and will be so unless the Order pertains to another competition authority. A distinction is drawn between the majority Order and the minority Order if there are two Orders.
 
12
Section 2(t) of the Act defines the: “ relevant product market” means a market comprising all those products or services which are regarded as interchangeable or substitutable by the consumer, by reason of characteristics of the products or services, their prices and intended use;
 
13
The argument of OEMs that on the basis of substitutability in line with Section 2(t) would result in thousands of separate relevant markets, “The Commission is of the view that such submissions of the OEMs are misleading and erroneous. This is because markets where several goods are jointly demanded and supplied are referred to as cluster markets. Cluster markets are characterized by transaction complementarities between various components of a bundle of products or services. The relevant unit with respect to market definition is the bundle of goods or services that is demanded by consumers and supplied by the producers and not the individual units of such bundle although such units may not be interchangeable or substitutable with each other. In this context, the concept of substitutability or exchangeability applies to the bundle rather than to its separate components where a bundle of products or services serves as a first candidate market. Thus, the fact that bundles of goods or services are demanded and supplied in a market does not affect the basic principle of market definition, i.e., interchangeability or substitutability between competing products.” (Op. cit. Order Case No 3/2011).
 
14
EC Quoting from the U.S. Supreme Court judgment on life cycle costs in the Eastman Kodak case. The ‘Auto Parts’ case is the Commission’s ‘Kodak’ case.
 
15
The premised economic evidence was with reference to consumer response to energy products in the U.S. This no doubt is a progressive move towards using economics but changing consumer profile with a growing young and mobile crowd whose life style and patterns are more in keeping with the developed countries discussed in the earlier Transition India case was not taken into account.
 
16
Section 4. [(1) No enterprise or group] shall abuse its dominant position.] (2) There shall be an abuse of dominant position 4[under sub-section (1), if an enterprise or a group].—(a) directly or indirectly, imposes unfair or discriminatory—
(i) condition in purchase or sale of goods or service; or
(ii) price in purchase or sale (including predatory price) of goods or service.
Explanation.— For the purposes of this clause, the unfair or discriminatory condition in purchase or sale of goods predatory price) or service referred to in sub-clause (ii) shall not include such discriminatory condition or which may be adopted to meet the competition;
(b) “predatory price” means the sale of goods or provision of services, at a. price which is below the cost, as may be determined by regulations, of production of the goods or provision of services, with a view to reduce competition or eliminate the competitors.
 
17
Section 4(2) (e) uses its dominant position in one relevant market to enter into, or protect, other relevant market.
 
18
The stock exchange services consist of several products which are not substitutable (Section 2(h)). Currency derivative the product in question cannot be said to be interchangeable or substitutable with the other instruments traded on a stock exchange, namely equity, debt instruments.
 
19
Explanation(a) to Section 4 of the Act:
For the purposes of this section, the expression —
(a) “dominant position” means a position of strength, enjoyed by an enterprise, in the relevant market, in India, which enables it to—
(i) operate independently of competitive forces prevailing in the relevant market; or
(ii) affect its competitors or consumers or the relevant market in its favour.
The Commission has held in MCX Stock Exchange Ltd. &Ors. v. National Stock Exchange of India Ltd. &Ors., (Case No.13/2009), as follows:
In terms of explanation (a) of Section 4 of the Competition Act, ‘the position of strength’ is not some objective attribute that can be measured along a prescribed mathematical index or equation. Rather, it has to be a rational consideration of relevant facts, holistic interpretation of (at times) seemingly unconnected statistics or information and application of several aspects of the Indian economy. What has to be seen is whether a particular player in a relevant market has clear comparative advantages in terms of financial resources, technical capabilities, brand value, historical legacy etc. to be able to do things which would affect its competitors who, in turn, would be unable to do or would find it extremely difficult to do so on a sustained basis. The reason is that such an enterprise can force its competitors into taking a certain position in the market which would make the market and consumers respond or react in a certain manner which is beneficial to the dominant enterprise but detrimental to the competitors.”
 
20
In India the attempt to introduce Over the Counter OTC’s as against the prevailing Bombay Stock Exchange and NSE met with little success. The counterfactual of single stock exchanges or two exchanges as happened in India or on stock exchanges in other countries was not analyzed.
 
21
The habit which I call as ‘firing from the shoulders of the Commission’.
 
22
Juridically the Competition Act is applicable only to markets that fall within India. In the case of virtual markets as consumers have access world over the issue of jurisdictional claims have not yet been resolved. Even in financial markets such as Bitcoin there is no clarity under whose jurisdiction is the market regulated. The aspect of geographical markets was again raised in Case No. 6 of 2014, Vishal Gupta v Google Inc., in a divided prima facie opinion.
 
23
(Case No. 17/2014), Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal.com through Mr. Kunal Bahl, CEO &Ors., (Case No. 61/2014) M/s Jasper Infotech Private Limited v. M/s Kaff Appliances (India) Private Ltd., (Case No 80/2014), Mohit Manglani v. Flipkart India Private Limited & Ors., The market definition was premised on the prevalence of competitive constraints offered by brick and mortar companies.
 
24
(Case No. 30/2012), Consumer Unity Trust v Google Inc., and Google India Private Ltd, (Case No.7 of 2012), Consim Info Private Limited v Google Inc. and Google India Private Limited,(Case No. 6 of 2014), Vishal Gupta v Google Inc.,
 
25
See, for example, the decision of the European Commission in the Microsoft/Skype merger. In that case the European Commission found that usage shares of 80–90 % would not give the combined entity market power. The European Commission stated in its clearance decision that in the relevant services, such shares “are not the best proxy to evaluate the market power of providers” (Case COMP/M.6281, Microsoft/Skype, Commission decision of 7 October 2011, paragraph 99). The European Commission’s decision was upheld on appeal to the General Court (see Case T-79/12 Cisco Systems v. Commission, judgment of the General Court delivered 11 December 2013). In particular, the General Court found that “the consumer communications sector is a recent and fast-growing sector which is characterized by short innovation cycles in which large market shares may turn out to be ephemeral. In such a dynamic context, high market shares are not necessarily indicative of market power and, therefore, of lasting damage to competition” (paragraph 69).Similarly, in its clearance of the Facebook/WhatsApp merger, the European Commission found that in innovation-driven technology markets “high market shares are not necessarily indicative of market power” (Case COMP/M.7217, Facebook/WhatsApp, Commission decision of October 3, 2014, paragraph 99).It is notable that even under the EU regime these progressive economics-focused decisions relate to mergers, rather than antitrust enforcement.
 
26
The German Competition Commission in their recent guidelines on competition in the digital age have as per reports raised this issue with reference to the emerging digital market where intervention could suppress competition and the possibility of new entrepreneurs spawned by the internet. See, German Monopolies Commission Publishes its Report on Digital Markets, Covington and Burlington LLP.
 
27
The Qihoo/Tencent Case in China and Naver case in South Korea present interesting insights into how legalese are more comfortable with a structured approach as outlined in their respective Acts. Two young scholars Yong Lim and Yunyu Shen brought to my attention the dynamics of interactions between law and economics in their paper, “A Tale of Two Courts: Handling Market Definition in Abuse of Dominance Cases under Market Share-Based Statutory Power Presumptions in China and Korea”, CPI Antitrust Chronicle, February 2015.
 
28
Economic evidence have been effectively used to mention Kapoor Glass v Schott (Minority Order) Kapoor Glass., op.cit. Transitions India (Majority Order), Case No. 61/2014, Ramakant Kini v Dr. L.H.Hiranandani Hospitals (Minority Order).
 
29
References to case laws of European Union or of Department of Justice in lieu of economic evidence can best be a supplementary. Selection of economic articles have also not been discerning.
 
30
The possibility of divergence between consumer welfare and total welfare and the administrator’s inclination to intervene is seen in undue market activism of young competition authorities.
 
31
To quote from the Order pertaining to the automotive aftermarket case; “the determination of the relevant market is not an end by itself but is a means to analyze the position of strength enjoyed by an enterprise in such a market, as per the provisions of explanation (a) to Section 4 of the Act, to determine if such an enterprise is in a dominant position in such a relevant market. Therefore, the task of the Commission is to identify that relevant market where the dominance of the enterprise is being felt”.
 
32
Alan Greenspan is said to have commented that interventions of anti-trust act against innovations is ultimately to the detriment of consumers.
 
33
“We are closer to the EU competition law” as explained by the Chairman of Competition Commission of India in a recent interview to The Economic Times (13th November)
 
34
I refer to the emerging debates on whether the Law in these countries have to be modified.
 
35
As pointed by Richard Wish, Article 2(3) of the European Community Merger Regulation, as part of test for mergers with common market compatibility reference is made to ‘effective competition’.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat ((1977)2 SCC 55), Tata Engineering & Locomotive Co. Ltd., Bombay v. Registrar of the Restrictive Trade Agreement. ((1977)2 SCC 55), Tata Engineering & Locomotive Co. Ltd., Bombay v. Registrar of the Restrictive Trade Agreement.
Zurück zum Zitat ((1979)2SCC529), Mahindra & Mahindra v. Union of India. ((1979)2SCC529), Mahindra & Mahindra v. Union of India.
Zurück zum Zitat (Appeal No. 15 of 2011, August 2014), National Stock Exchange of India Limited v/Competition Commission of India and Another. (Appeal No. 15 of 2011, August 2014), National Stock Exchange of India Limited v/Competition Commission of India and Another.
Zurück zum Zitat (Appeal No. 91 of 2012, 2 April 2014), Competition Appellate Tribunal (COMPAT) Schott Glass India Pvt. Ltd., v Competition Commission of India. (Appeal No. 91 of 2012, 2 April 2014), Competition Appellate Tribunal (COMPAT) Schott Glass India Pvt. Ltd., v Competition Commission of India.
Zurück zum Zitat Blair, R., & Daniel, S. (2013). Welfare standards in U.S. and E.U. Anti-trust enforcement. Fordham Law Review, 81, 2497–2541. Blair, R., & Daniel, S. (2013). Welfare standards in U.S. and E.U. Anti-trust enforcement. Fordham Law Review, 81, 2497–2541.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case COMP/M.6281), Microsoft/Skype, European Commission decision of 7 October 2011, paragraph 99. (Case COMP/M.6281), Microsoft/Skype, European Commission decision of 7 October 2011, paragraph 99.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case COMP/M.7217), Facebook/WhatsApp, European Commission decision of October 3, 2014, paragraph 99. (Case COMP/M.7217), Facebook/WhatsApp, European Commission decision of October 3, 2014, paragraph 99.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 2/2010), Kapoor Glass Private Limited v Schott Glass India Private Limited Order (dated 29/03/2012). (Case No. 2/2010), Kapoor Glass Private Limited v Schott Glass India Private Limited Order (dated 29/03/2012).
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 3/2011), Shamsher Kataria v Honda/Siel car and Ors (dated 25/8/14). (Case No. 3/2011), Shamsher Kataria v Honda/Siel car and Ors (dated 25/8/14).
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No 10/2010) GKB Hi Tech Lenses Pvt. Ltd., v Transitions Optical India Pvt. Ltd., (dated 16/5/2012). (Case No 10/2010) GKB Hi Tech Lenses Pvt. Ltd., v Transitions Optical India Pvt. Ltd., (dated 16/5/2012).
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 7 of 2012), Consim Info Private Limited v Google Inc. and Google India Private Limited. (Case No. 7 of 2012), Consim Info Private Limited v Google Inc. and Google India Private Limited.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 30/2012), Consumer Unity Trust v Google Inc., and Google India Private Ltd. (Case No. 30/2012), Consumer Unity Trust v Google Inc., and Google India Private Ltd.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 39 of 2012), Ramakant Kini v Dr. L.H.Hiranandani Hospitals. (Case No. 39 of 2012), Ramakant Kini v Dr. L.H.Hiranandani Hospitals.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 6 of 2014), Vishal Gupta v Google Inc. (Case No. 6 of 2014), Vishal Gupta v Google Inc.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 17/2014), Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal through Mr. Kunal Bahl, CEO &Ors. (Case No. 17/2014), Ashish Ahuja v. Snapdeal through Mr. Kunal Bahl, CEO &Ors.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 17/2014), M/s Jasper Infotech Private Limited v. M/s Kaff Appliances (India) Private Ltd. (Case No. 17/2014), M/s Jasper Infotech Private Limited v. M/s Kaff Appliances (India) Private Ltd.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case No. 61/2014), Mohit Manglani v. Flipkart India Private Limited & Ors. (Case No. 61/2014), Mohit Manglani v. Flipkart India Private Limited & Ors.
Zurück zum Zitat (Case T-79/12), Cisco Systems v. Commission, judgment of the General Court (delivered 11 December 2013). (Case T-79/12), Cisco Systems v. Commission, judgment of the General Court (delivered 11 December 2013).
Zurück zum Zitat Covington and Burlington LLP. German Monopolies Commission publishes its report on digital markets. Covington and Burlington LLP. German Monopolies Commission publishes its report on digital markets.
Zurück zum Zitat Kuhn, K. -U. (2013). “Good economics in” administrative proceedings: Three challenges. Concurrences, Competition Law Journal, No. 3, 1–3. Kuhn, K. -U. (2013). “Good economics in” administrative proceedings: Three challenges. Concurrences, Competition Law Journal, No. 3, 1–3.
Zurück zum Zitat Lim, Y., & Shen, Y. (2015). A tale of two courts: Handling market definition in abuse of dominance cases under market share-based statutory power presumptions in China and Korea. CPI Antitrust Chronicle (pp. 2–17). Lim, Y., & Shen, Y. (2015). A tale of two courts: Handling market definition in abuse of dominance cases under market share-based statutory power presumptions in China and Korea. CPI Antitrust Chronicle (pp. 2–17).
Zurück zum Zitat Notice C2014/05/170, Sun Pharmaceutical Industries Limited and Ranbaxy Laboratories Limited Notice C-2013/05/122 Etihad Airways and Jet Airway, Notice C 2012/12/97 for Acquisition of United Spirit Limited by Relay B.V. (Diageo). Notice C2014/05/170, Sun Pharmaceutical Industries Limited and Ranbaxy Laboratories Limited Notice C-2013/05/122 Etihad Airways and Jet Airway, Notice C 2012/12/97 for Acquisition of United Spirit Limited by Relay B.V. (Diageo).
Zurück zum Zitat Shapiro, C. (1995). Aftermarkets and consumer welfare: Making sense of Kodak. Antitrust Law Journal, 63, 483–511. Shapiro, C. (1995). Aftermarkets and consumer welfare: Making sense of Kodak. Antitrust Law Journal, 63, 483–511.
Zurück zum Zitat U.S. Department of Justice Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 2009. U.S. Department of Justice Horizontal Merger Guidelines, 2009.
Zurück zum Zitat Wish, R. Competition policy and economics. Wish, R. Competition policy and economics.
Metadaten
Titel
Economic Evidence in Competition Law Enforcement in India
verfasst von
Geeta Gouri
Copyright-Jahr
2016
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-30948-4_9