Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Journal of Business Ethics 3/2015

23-09-2014

A Few Good Companies: Rethinking Firms’ Responsibilities Toward Common Pool Resources

Authors: Patricia Gabaldon, Stefan Gröschl

Published in: Journal of Business Ethics | Issue 3/2015

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

While a significant body of literature has highlighted the moral obligations of companies regarding the sustainable use of common pool resources, business activities that contribute to the sustenance of common pool resources remain embryonic. Studies in this area have largely focused on environmental stimuli rather than on the complex motivational structures that drive or hinder businesses’ contributions to common pool resources. We explore the different motives and behaviors of businesses and their contributions to common pool resources, and propose four roles by which companies’ motives and behaviors toward common pool resources can be categorized—namely, free riders, followers, believers, and altruists. We shift the focus from moral reasoning to Platt’s (Am Psychol 28(8):641–651, 1973) notion of social trapping and his “ways out” as Platt’s “ways out” include propositions that address not only environmental stimuli but also companies’ motives. Both types of propositions are important for businesses to be able to respond rapidly to the scarcity of certain common pool resources and to use and maintain common pool resources in a sustainable way. Based on our categorization and Platt’s typology of social traps and “ways out,” we propose a theoretical framework by which companies and other stakeholders are provided with a differentiating perspective that allows for propositions addressing the complex nature of motivational structures and common pool resources. Our framework helps business leaders, institutions, and policy makers decide on actions that can contribute to the sustainability of common pool resources and that differ from actions that solely serve organizational self-interests.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
The original term used by Samuelson and Buchanan was “rivalry of consumption”; it was replaced by Ostrom and Ostrom (1977) with “subtractability of use.”
 
2
“Another example is the decay of railroad service, as people begin to prefer using their cars. As the railroad begins to go downhill, still more people prefer cars. The process is self-accelerating, ending up with no one riding the trains, while there are traffic jams on the highways in which everyone involved would prefer—too late—to be using the railroad” (Platt 1973, p. 642).
 
3
Platt (1973) used the Kitty Genovese murder in New York City as an example of a countertrap. In this example, a girl was raped and killed in an alley, with numerous neighbors watching from their homes without calling the police. Platt assumed that the neighbors’ lack of (re)action was due to their fear of the killer’s revenge. “Each observer may have felt a strong prick of social conscience at the time but simply hoped that someone else would make the troublesome phone call first” (Platt 1973, p. 641).
 
Literature
go back to reference Anderson, L., & Seijo, J. (2010). Bioeconomics of fisheries management. Ames, IA: Wiley-Blackwell. Anderson, L., & Seijo, J. (2010). Bioeconomics of fisheries management. Ames, IA: Wiley-Blackwell.
go back to reference Badhwar, N. K. (1993). Altruism versus self-interest: Sometimes a false dichotomy. Social Philosophy and Policy, 10(01), 90–117.CrossRef Badhwar, N. K. (1993). Altruism versus self-interest: Sometimes a false dichotomy. Social Philosophy and Policy, 10(01), 90–117.CrossRef
go back to reference Brundtland, G. H. (1987). Report of the World Commission on Environment and Development: “Our common future”. New York, NY: United Nations. Brundtland, G. H. (1987). Report of the World Commission on Environment and Development: “Our common future”. New York, NY: United Nations.
go back to reference Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M. (1965). An economic theory of clubs. Economica, 32(125), 1–14.CrossRef
go back to reference De Bettignies, H. C., Lépineux, F., & de Lamartine, A. (2005). Should multinational corporations be concerned with the global common good? An interdisciplinary exploration. Fontainebleau: INSEAD Working Paper Series. De Bettignies, H. C., Lépineux, F., & de Lamartine, A. (2005). Should multinational corporations be concerned with the global common good? An interdisciplinary exploration. Fontainebleau: INSEAD Working Paper Series.
go back to reference Donaldson, T. (1982). Corporations and morality (pp. 36–58). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Donaldson, T. (1982). Corporations and morality (pp. 36–58). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
go back to reference Drucker, P. (2010). The frontiers of management. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Review Press. Drucker, P. (2010). The frontiers of management. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business Review Press.
go back to reference Fischer-Kowalski, M., Swilling, M., von Weizsäcker, E. U., Ren, Y., Moriguchi, Y., Crane, W., et al. (2011). Decoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic growth. Nairobi: United Nations Envrionmental Programme. Fischer-Kowalski, M., Swilling, M., von Weizsäcker, E. U., Ren, Y., Moriguchi, Y., Crane, W., et al. (2011). Decoupling natural resource use and environmental impacts from economic growth. Nairobi: United Nations Envrionmental Programme.
go back to reference Gröschl, S. (2013). Uncertainty, diversity and the common good: Changing norms and new leadership paradigms. Burlington: Gower Publishing. Gröschl, S. (2013). Uncertainty, diversity and the common good: Changing norms and new leadership paradigms. Burlington: Gower Publishing.
go back to reference Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.CrossRef Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.CrossRef
go back to reference Jonsen, K., Tatli, A., Özbilgin, M., & Bell, M. (2013). The tragedy of the uncommons: Reframing workforce diversity. Human Relations, 66(2), 271–294.CrossRef Jonsen, K., Tatli, A., Özbilgin, M., & Bell, M. (2013). The tragedy of the uncommons: Reframing workforce diversity. Human Relations, 66(2), 271–294.CrossRef
go back to reference Khalil, E. L. (1990). Beyond self-interest and altruism. Economics and Philosophy, 6(2), 255–273.CrossRef Khalil, E. L. (1990). Beyond self-interest and altruism. Economics and Philosophy, 6(2), 255–273.CrossRef
go back to reference Lacy, P. (2013). The United Nations Global Compact—Accenture CEO study on sustainability 2013. New York, NY: United Nations. Lacy, P. (2013). The United Nations Global Compact—Accenture CEO study on sustainability 2013. New York, NY: United Nations.
go back to reference Leal Filho, W. (2000). Dealing with misconceptions on the concept of sustainability. International Journal of Sustainability in Higher Education, 1(1), 9–19.CrossRef Leal Filho, W. (2000). Dealing with misconceptions on the concept of sustainability. International Journal of Sustainability in Higher Education, 1(1), 9–19.CrossRef
go back to reference López, M. M., Garcia, A., & Rodriguez, L. (2007). Sustainable development and corporate performance: A study based on the Dow Jones Sustainability Index. Journal of Business Ethics, 75(3), 285–300.CrossRef López, M. M., Garcia, A., & Rodriguez, L. (2007). Sustainable development and corporate performance: A study based on the Dow Jones Sustainability Index. Journal of Business Ethics, 75(3), 285–300.CrossRef
go back to reference Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H.-J. (2002). Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Nature, 415(6870), 424–426.CrossRef Milinski, M., Semmann, D., & Krambeck, H.-J. (2002). Reputation helps solve the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Nature, 415(6870), 424–426.CrossRef
go back to reference Millennium Ecosystem Assessment Board. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: Synthesis report. Washington, DC: Island Press. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment Board. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: Synthesis report. Washington, DC: Island Press.
go back to reference Narver, J. C., & Slater, S. F. (1990). The effect of a market orientation on business profitability. Journal of marketing, 54(4), 20–35.CrossRef Narver, J. C., & Slater, S. F. (1990). The effect of a market orientation on business profitability. Journal of marketing, 54(4), 20–35.CrossRef
go back to reference O’Brien, T. (2009). Reconsidering the common good in a business context. Journal of Business Ethics, 85(1), 25–37.CrossRef O’Brien, T. (2009). Reconsidering the common good in a business context. Journal of Business Ethics, 85(1), 25–37.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (2008). Institutions and the environment. Economic Affairs, 28(3), 24–31.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (2008). Institutions and the environment. Economic Affairs, 28(3), 24–31.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. The American Economic Review, 100(3), 641–672.CrossRef Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. The American Economic Review, 100(3), 641–672.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, E., Burger, J., Field, C., Norgaard, R., & Policansky, D. (1999). Revisiting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science, 284(5412), 278–282.CrossRef Ostrom, E., Burger, J., Field, C., Norgaard, R., & Policansky, D. (1999). Revisiting the commons: Local lessons, global challenges. Science, 284(5412), 278–282.CrossRef
go back to reference Ostrom, V., & Ostrom, E. (1977). Public goods and public choices. In E. S. Savas (Ed.), Alternatives for delivering public services: Toward improved performance (pp. 7–49). Boulder, CO: Westview Press. Ostrom, V., & Ostrom, E. (1977). Public goods and public choices. In E. S. Savas (Ed.), Alternatives for delivering public services: Toward improved performance (pp. 7–49). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
go back to reference Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.CrossRef Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 36(4), 387–389.CrossRef
go back to reference Schelling, T. (1971). On the ecology of micromotives. Public Interest, 25, 61–98. Schelling, T. (1971). On the ecology of micromotives. Public Interest, 25, 61–98.
go back to reference Sison, A. J. G., & Fontrodona, J. (2006). The nature of the firm, agency theory and shareholder theory: A critique from philosophical anthropology. Journal of Business Ethics, 66(1), 33–42.CrossRef Sison, A. J. G., & Fontrodona, J. (2006). The nature of the firm, agency theory and shareholder theory: A critique from philosophical anthropology. Journal of Business Ethics, 66(1), 33–42.CrossRef
go back to reference Skinner, B. F. (1963). Operant behavior. American Psychologist, 18(8), 503–515.CrossRef Skinner, B. F. (1963). Operant behavior. American Psychologist, 18(8), 503–515.CrossRef
go back to reference Skinner, B. F. (1969). Contingencies of reinforcement: A theoretical analysis. New York, NY: Appleton-Century-Crofts. Skinner, B. F. (1969). Contingencies of reinforcement: A theoretical analysis. New York, NY: Appleton-Century-Crofts.
go back to reference Velasquez, M. (1992). International business, morality, and the common good. Business Ethics Quarterly, 2(1), 27–40.CrossRef Velasquez, M. (1992). International business, morality, and the common good. Business Ethics Quarterly, 2(1), 27–40.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
A Few Good Companies: Rethinking Firms’ Responsibilities Toward Common Pool Resources
Authors
Patricia Gabaldon
Stefan Gröschl
Publication date
23-09-2014
Publisher
Springer Netherlands
Published in
Journal of Business Ethics / Issue 3/2015
Print ISSN: 0167-4544
Electronic ISSN: 1573-0697
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-014-2361-y

Other articles of this Issue 3/2015

Journal of Business Ethics 3/2015 Go to the issue