Skip to main content
Top

2012 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

20. Antitrust Law and Regulation

Authors : Victor J. Tremblay, Carol Horton Tremblay

Published in: New Perspectives on Industrial Organization

Publisher: Springer New York

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Laws and regulations touch nearly every aspect of our lives. Most states require children to wear a helmet when riding a bicycle. The US Department of Agriculture requires that your “cheese pizza” contain no more than 11% of a cheese substitute. Food containing more than one ingredient can be labeled “organic” only if at least 95% of its contents are organic. Your power company cannot raise its rates without regulatory approval.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
For a detailed list of helmet laws by state, see the Web page of the Bicycle Helmet Safety Institute at http://​www.​bhsi.​org/​mandator.​htm.
 
2
This means that it must be produced without chemical fertilizers, insecticides, chemical herbicides, or given growth hormones or antibiotics. For a discussion of US Department of Agriculture (USDA) regulations, see http://​www.​fsis.​usda.​gov and http://​usda-fda.​com.
 
3
Although we focus primarily on efficiency issues in this chapter, as discussed in Chaps.​ 1 and 19 both equity and efficiency are important to society.
 
4
Comparing market outcomes with and without a government policy that ignores the cost of government is called the “nirvana” approach to public policy analysis by Demsetz (1969). Noll (1989a, b) argued that ideally (1) a corrective policy is enacted only when genuine market failure exists and after an optimal policy is identified; (2) the policy is rescinded once it is no longer socially beneficial.
 
5
When discussing public policy, we restrict our attention to issues involving antitrust and regulation. We do not discuss “industrial policy,” which is aimed toward supporting domestic firms in one or more key sectors of the economy to gain a strategic advantage over foreign competitors.
 
6
For those interested in further discussion of law and economics, see Cooter and Ulen (2012) and Harrison and Theeuwes (2008).
 
7
Discussion in this section derives from Wacks (2006), Murphy (2007), Cooter and Ulen (2012), and Harrison and Theeuwes (2008).
 
8
These include Aquinas (1225–1274), Rousseau (1712–1778), and Finnis (1949-).
 
9
Horowitz (2009) argued that a similar problem exists on college campuses. He is concerned that the majority of college professors are liberal, which makes it difficult to hire conservatives and leads to a lack of intellectual diversity.
 
10
When considering two alternatives x and y (e.g., different baskets of goods or different legal options), preferences are complete when they clearly identify whether x is preferred to y, y is preferred to x, or that x and y are equally valued. When we add a third alternative (z), preferences are transitive when the following condition holds: if x is preferred to y and y is preferred to z, then x is preferred to z. Monotonicity implies welfare does not decline with the increase of a good.
 
11
For an excellent summary of welfare economics and of Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem, see Varian (2010, Chap. 33).
 
12
We do not want to over generalize, however. As Cooter and Ulen (2012) pointed out, US states have adopted a set of codes for commercial business (the Uniform Commercial Code), which is in keeping with civil law. In addition, La Porta et al. (2008) pointed out that French courts have gained greater discretion over time.
 
13
For example, see Demsetz (1967), Alchian and Demsetz (1972), Priest (1977), Rubin (1977), and Posner (1980). For a summary of this argument, see Harrison and Theeuwes (2008).
 
14
Recall that this means that everyone could use the land, and no one could be excluded from use.
 
15
The literature is too extensive to list here. For a review of the evidence, see Dam (2006), La Porta et al. (2008), and Roe and Siegel (2009).
 
16
Not all agree with the simple interpretation and with La Porta et al.’s argument that the common law system is more flexible than the civil law system today. For alternative viewpoints, see Dam (2006), Fairfax (2009), and Roe and Siegel (2009).
 
17
Glaeser and Shleifer (2002, 1194) concluded that “[o]n just about any measure, common law countries are more financially developed than civil law countries.”
 
18
For further discussion of these trade-offs as they relate to antitrust enforcement, see Beckner and Salop (1999) and Baker and Bresnahan (2008).
 
19
For example, Heart (1994) argued that discretion is especially valuable in the “penumbra,” or grey areas of the law, where a judge may use the entire body of legal knowledge to make a decision and set a precedent.
 
20
The Robinson-Patman Act (1936) amended Section 2 and gave greater protection to small retailers who were battling the growing chain-store movement in the USA.
 
21
This information is obtained from Andrew E. Ebere, “Private Antitrust Cases Decreased in 2009,” Princeton Economics Group, available at http://​econgroup.​com/​peg_​news_​view.​asp?​newid=​40&​pageno=​1, accessed October 13, 2010.
 
22
For example, Elzinga (1969) investigated 39 cases involving divesture and found that only 25% were successful.
 
23
Reviews of important antitrust cases, including those discussed in this chapter, can be found in Asch (1983), Waldman (1986), Breit and Elzinga (1989), Scherer and Ross (1990), Posner (2001), Hovenkamp (2008), Sherman (2008), Blair and Kaserman (2009), and Kwoka and White (2009).
 
24
This new Chicago critique is clearly expressed by Milton Friedman, a leader of the Chicago School, who said: “Because we all believed in competition 50 years ago, we are generally in favor of antitrust…. We’ve gradually come to the conclusion that, on the whole, it does more harm than good. [Antitrust laws] tend to become prey to the special interests.” This quote is taken from an interview for the Wall Street Journal by Sieb (1998).
 
25
Furthermore, Posner (2009), a Chicago economist and legal scholar, argued uncharacteristically that the recent crisis is due to insufficient government involvement in financial markets. See Wright (2009) for an alternative viewpoint.
 
26
However, McGee (1958) argued that Standard Oil did not gain market share through predatory pricing tactics.
 
27
Quote taken from Breit and Elzinga (1989, 138).
 
28
These are sometimes called “bright-line rules,” because behavior is per se illegal when it crosses a clear and distinct line.
 
29
Quote taken from Breit and Elzinga (1989, 145).
 
30
An important issue was the definition of the market for aluminum. As in all antitrust cases, a first step in determining whether or not a firm has a monopoly position is to correctly define the market. In practice, this is a difficult task, and the courts have sometimes chosen a broad definition and in others a narrow definition of the market. In the Alcoa case, the company’s market share was 90% of US ingot production but only 33% of ingot and scrap aluminum production (not including aluminum retained for its own use). Thus, the company argued in favor of a broad definition and the government argued in favor of a narrow definition of the market. The courts chose a narrow definition, which implied that Alcoa had market power. See Scherer and Ross (1990) for further discussion of this issue and its effect on antitrust rulings.
 
31
Alcoa was not broken up though. A final remedy was postponed until 1950 when aluminum plants built by the government during World War II and operated by Alcoa were sold at public auction. Alcoa was barred from bidding, and winning bidders formed two new competitors, Reynolds Aluminum and Kaiser Aluminum.
 
32
For a detailed discussion of this case, see Fisher et al. (1983).
 
33
This led to the creation of seven regional phone companies, or “baby bells”: NYNEX, Bell Atlantic, Bell South, Ameritech, Southwestern Bell, US West, and Pacific Telesis.
 
34
For similar views, see Brozen (1971) and McGee (1971).
 
35
For a review of the potential costs and benefits of breaking up Microsoft, see Elzinga et al. (2001). For a more detailed account of Microsoft’s success and run-ins with antitrust authorities, see the Microsoft case study in Chap.​ 21.
 
36
Quote taken from Waldman (1986, 139).
 
38
Quote taken from Waldman (1986, 152).
 
39
In Sugar Institute, Inc. v. United States (1936), the Sugar Institute was found guilty of violating Section 1 of the Sherman Act because of the steps it took to eliminate price cutting, whereas in Tag Manufacturers Institute v. Federal Trade Commission (1949), the Tag Manufacturers Institute (of business tags) was found innocent of price fixing. Even though members were required to report prices, they were encouraged to set prices independently. Thus, the Institute collected market information but did not facilitate price fixing.
 
40
For a complete list of antitrust exemptions that apply to many different industries, see von Kalinowski (1982).
 
41
For a review of court precedents on the decision to view a league as a “single entity”, see Lehn and Sykuta (1997).
 
42
For a discussion of similar antitrust issues involving college athletics, see NCAA v. University of Oklahoma, 1984.
 
43
For a more detailed discussion of this case, see LaFraniere (1991) and Austin (2006). The Ivy League schools are Brown University, Columbia University, Cornell University, Dartmouth College, Harvard University, Princeton University, the University of Pennsylvania, and Yale University.
 
44
LaFraniere (1991, A3).
 
45
Quote taken from Waldman (1986, 91).
 
46
Quote taken from Scherer and Ross (1990, 177).
 
47
Similarly, Bok (1960, 299) argued that “there is much to be said for a simple standard which can at least be fairly and inexpensively administered in a fashion that is understandable to the businessman contemplating merger.”
 
49
Quote taken from Breit and Elzinga (1989, 170).
 
50
Additional information on this premerger notification program can be found at http://​www.​ftc.​gov/​bc/​hsr/​index.​shtm.
 
51
Given the high cost of a trial, this is socially desirable as long as government enforcement is consistent with the law and court precedent. The National Association of Attorneys General Antitrust Enforcement (1993) questioned the desirability of giving so much power to the DOJ and the FTC, claiming that they put too much weight on efficiency and too little weight on consumer welfare and the incipiency precedent.
 
52
For further detail of this complex agreement, see V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay (2005).
 
53
For a more complete discussion of this case, see McAfee et al. (2009).
 
54
The main difference between the 1982 and 1984 Merger Guidelines is that the 1984 Merger Guidelines clarify the efficiency defense.
 
56
Recall from Chap.​ 18 that when firms 1 and 2 are in the same industry and have respective market shares of ms1 and ms2, their merger will cause HHI to increase by 2·ms1 · ms2. For example, consider a market with 4 firms, 1 through 4, that have the following market shares in percent: ms1 = 5, ms2 = 20, ms3 = 40, and ms4 = 45. If firms 1 and 2 merge, this increases HHI by 100 points (2 · 5 · 10). That is, before the merger HHI = 3,750 = 52 + 102 + 402 + 452, and after the merger HHI = 3,850 = 152 + 402 + 452.
 
57
The 1992 and 1997 Guidelines are available at http://​www.​justice.​gov/​atr/​hmerger/​11251.​htm.
 
59
For a discussion of the methods of measuring UPP, see Farrell and Shapiro (2010). For further discussion, see Schmalensee (2009), Carlton (2010), Epstein and Rubinfield (2010), and Willig (2011).
 
60
The 2010 structural standard for a highly concentrated industry is that HHI cannot increase by more than 200 points. However, because the cutoff for a highly concentrated industry differs (is 1,800 in the 1982–1984 Guidelines and 2,500 in the 2010 Guidelines), the 2010 constraint is reduced by 38.9% for consistency. This implies that a merger would be challenged in 2010 if HHI increases by more than 144 points, 200·(1,800/2,500).
 
61
For example, see Meadows (1981), Adams and Brock (1988), Krattenmaker and Pitofsky (1988), and Baker and Shapiro (2007).
 
62
Although there is no support for the political cycle using merger cases, Ghosal (2007) did find support for the political cycle when the sample includes all civil cases.
 
63
For a more complete discussion of antitrust enforcement in brewing, see Elzinga and Swisher (2005, 2011), V. Tremblay (1993), and V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay (2005).
 
64
Another factor that complicated the analysis is that the beer market was regional in scope until the 1970s.
 
65
Moral hazard is the tendency of firms and consumers to exert less effort and diligence when their investments are insured against loss, damage, or theft.
 
66
These agencies were also given greater power to oversee or regulate consumer loans, bank executive bonuses, and the percent of their investments in derivatives and hedge funds. The Federal Reserve Bank is also given the power to break up excessively large financial institutions. For additional discussion, see Davidson et al. (2010), Gordon (2010), and Paletta and Hitt (2010).
 
67
Recall that cartels were legal until 1890. Porter found that railroad companies used a trigger strategy to support collusion. Given the cost of detecting cheating, collusion occasionally broke down, resulting in a temporary punishment phase of tougher competition. In addition, railroads have very high fixed costs, causing them to compete in price during periods of low demand to reduce excess capacity and help cover these costs. Thus, prices were unstable.
 
68
This was amended by the Motor Carrier Act of 1935 to regulate bus lines, trucking, and common carriers.
 
69
Since the seminal work by Stigler and Friedland (1962), there have been hundreds of studies on the economic effect of government regulation. For a review of the evidence, see Jordon (1972), Joskow and Rose (1989), Winston (1993, 1998), and Viscusi et al. (2005).
 
70
See Noll (1989a, b) for a review of the political causes of regulation.
 
71
In other words, individual consumers and voters have little influence on the political process. As Noll (1989, 1263) notes, “The central problem of a citizen in dealing with government is powerlessness.”
 
72
This does not mean that there must be economies of scale throughout the entire region of market demand. It simply means that industry costs are minimized when there is just one producer. When this occurs, the cost function is said to be subadditive (Baumon 1977; Braeutigam 1989; Viscusi et al. 2005, 404–408).
 
73
Along similar lines, Robinson (1933) proposed the following solution. Much like a Piguovian tax (Pigou 1920), the regulatory authority provides the monopolist with a per-unit subsidy sufficient to induce the firm to produce the socially optimal level of output. This eliminates the deadweight loss. To prevent the monopolist from profiting from the subsidy, the regulatory authority imposes a lump-sum tax that is sufficient to reduce the firm’s profit to zero. The drawback with such a policy is that it requires knowledge of the appropriate subsidy and tax. An alternative solution would be for the firm to engage in perfect price discrimination. This too would eliminate all deadweight loss but would favor the producer over the consumer (Braeutigam 1989).
 
74
Demsetz (1968) showed that this outcome could also be reached if there was competitive bidding to serve the market, with the winner being the firm that offered to serve the market at lowest price. Sufficient competition would then drive the winning bid to average cost.
 
75
We derive this rule in Appendix 20.A.
.
 
76
For a more complete discussion, see Takayama (1969) and Sherman (1992).
 
77
To review the evidence, see Stevenson (1982), Jones and Biases (1983), Joskow and Rose (1989), Winston (1993, 1998), and Viscusi et al. (2005).
 
78
A number of types of incentive regulations have been proposed, with some being more practical than others. For a review of the literature, see Vogelsang (2002), Viscusi et al. (2005), and Sherman (2008).
 
79
This idea derives from Baumol (1967), who observed that a regulatory lag (i.e., the lag between the time in which a regulated price can change) creates an incentive for the firm to minimize its costs. During the period between regulatory meetings, any cost reduction leads to higher profits which will persist until the next regulatory meeting.
 
80
It is important to realize, however, that although there was a general trend toward deregulation, government restrictions on business persisted to varying degrees throughout the economy. Not only did antitrust enforcement continue, but there has also been a trend toward increased social regulation of health, safety, and the environment (Gruenspecht and Lave 1989). In addition, Gattuso (2010) reported that the Obama administration has increased government regulation and red tape dramatically in response to the 2008–2009 financial crisis.
 
81
These estimates ignore the additional benefit that would occur if unregulated markets were to behave optimally.
 
82
According to Noll (1989a, b) and Winston (1993), the evidence also shows that labor generally benefited from deregulation.
 
83
For a more complete discussion of the economics of social regulations, see Asch (1988), Gruenspecht and Lave (1989), Greer (1992), Viscusi et al. (2005), and Sherman (2008).
 
84
In addition, since 1994 the Food and Drug Administration has required firms to list basic food facts on their labels. The Nutrition Labeling and Education Act (1990) extended labeling requirements to dietary supplements.
 
86
For a more complete discussion, see the White House Fact Sheet, Reforms to Protect American Credit Card Holders, available at http://​www.​whitehouse.​gov/​the_​press_​office/​Fact-Sheet-Reforms-to-Protect-American-Credit-Card-Holders/​.
 
87
For a discussion of concerns with the behavioral policy approach, see Wright (2007), Werden et al. (2010), and Salinger (2010). Wright argues that paternalism will reduce learning and the incentive to behave rationally, which makes for less effective consumers in the long run.
 
88
Thaler and Sunstein (2008) argued that this approach applies to all consumer decisions that are complex. For example, they advocate that if senior citizens are required to enroll for a drug benefit program, they should be given a limited number of options and the default should be a sensible one.
 
89
For further discussion, see the FTC’s statement on the cooling-off rule at http://​www.​ftc.​gov/​bcp/​edu/​pubs/​consumer/​products/​pro03.​shtm.
 
90
For a more complete discussion of the politically incorrect marketing actions of US beer companies, see V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay (2005, 2007).
 
91
For the remainder of the chapter, we will discuss problems associated with information and advertising. For those interested in issues of product safety, see Asch (1988).
 
92
Failure to disclose relevant information can be just as misleading as providing false information. For example, if a used car salesperson knew that a car needed new brakes within the next month and failed to disclose this information to a buyer, this would be considered deceptive.
 
93
Targeted groups could include the terminally ill or children. Regarding ads targeted at children, a higher standard is used because of the “limited ability of children to detect exaggerated or untrue statements” (“The ABCs at the FTC: Marketing and Advertising to Children,” at http://​www.​ftc.​gov/​).
 
94
For a more complete discussion of regulatory issues involving advertising, see Pitofsky (1977).
 
95
Unfortunately, the evidence shows that higher taxes lead to higher prices and less alcohol consumption but not less alcohol abuse (V. Tremblay and C. Tremblay 2005; Cooper and Wright, 2010).
 
96
In addition, the Master Settlement Agreement of 1998 between the tobacco industry and most state governments prohibited most outdoor and transit advertising and the use of cartoon characters in cigarette ads (Chaloupka 2007). In 2009, Congress passed the Family Smoking Prevention and Tobacco Control Act, which required that warning labels cover the top 50% of the front and back panels of the package. See Curfman et al. (2009) for a discussion of the law. The complete transcript can be found at http://​www.​govtrack.​us/​congress/​bill.​xpd?​bill=​h111-1256.
 
Literature
go back to reference Adams W, Brock JW (1988) Reaganomics and the transmogrification of Merger Policy. Antitrust Bulletin 33(2):309–359 Adams W, Brock JW (1988) Reaganomics and the transmogrification of Merger Policy. Antitrust Bulletin 33(2):309–359
go back to reference Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organziation. Am Econ Rev 62:777–795 Alchian AA, Demsetz H (1972) Production, information costs, and economic organziation. Am Econ Rev 62:777–795
go back to reference Arrow KJ (1951) Individual values and social choice. Wiley, New York (2nd edition, 1963) Arrow KJ (1951) Individual values and social choice. Wiley, New York (2nd edition, 1963)
go back to reference Asch P (1983) Industrial organization and antitrust policy. Wiley, New York Asch P (1983) Industrial organization and antitrust policy. Wiley, New York
go back to reference Asch P (1988) Consumer safety regulation: putting a price on life and limb. New York, Oxford University Press Asch P (1988) Consumer safety regulation: putting a price on life and limb. New York, Oxford University Press
go back to reference Austin A (2006) Ivy league price-fixing: conflict from the intersection of education and commerce. St John’s J Legal Comment 21(1):1–52 Austin A (2006) Ivy league price-fixing: conflict from the intersection of education and commerce. St John’s J Legal Comment 21(1):1–52
go back to reference Baker J, Bresnahan T (2008) Economic evidence in antitrust: defining markets and measuring market power. In: Buccirossi P (ed) The economics of antitrust law. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA Baker J, Bresnahan T (2008) Economic evidence in antitrust: defining markets and measuring market power. In: Buccirossi P (ed) The economics of antitrust law. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
go back to reference Bar-Gill O (2004) Seduction by plastic. Northwestern University Law Review. 1395–1411 Bar-Gill O (2004) Seduction by plastic. Northwestern University Law Review. 1395–1411
go back to reference Baumon WJ (1967) Reasonable rules for rate regulation: plausible policies for an imperfect world. In: Phillips A, Williamson OE (eds) Prices: issues in theory, practice, and public policy. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia Baumon WJ (1967) Reasonable rules for rate regulation: plausible policies for an imperfect world. In: Phillips A, Williamson OE (eds) Prices: issues in theory, practice, and public policy. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia
go back to reference Baumon WJ (1977) On the proper cost test for natural monopoly in a multiproduct industry. Am Econ Rev 67:809–822 Baumon WJ (1977) On the proper cost test for natural monopoly in a multiproduct industry. Am Econ Rev 67:809–822
go back to reference Baumol WJ, Panzar JC, Willig R (1982) Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. Harcort Brace Javonovich, Inc., New York Baumol WJ, Panzar JC, Willig R (1982) Contestable markets and the theory of industry structure. Harcort Brace Javonovich, Inc., New York
go back to reference Becker G (1983) A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quart J Econ 98:371–400CrossRef Becker G (1983) A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quart J Econ 98:371–400CrossRef
go back to reference Becker G (1985) Public policies, pressure groups, and deadweight costs. J Public Econ 28(3):329–347CrossRef Becker G (1985) Public policies, pressure groups, and deadweight costs. J Public Econ 28(3):329–347CrossRef
go back to reference Bernstein MH (1955) Regulating business by independent commission. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ Bernstein MH (1955) Regulating business by independent commission. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ
go back to reference Beuttenmuller RW (1979) The goal of the new premerger notification requirements: preliminary relief against anticompetitive mergers. Duke Law Rev 249(1):249–285CrossRef Beuttenmuller RW (1979) The goal of the new premerger notification requirements: preliminary relief against anticompetitive mergers. Duke Law Rev 249(1):249–285CrossRef
go back to reference Blair RD, Kaserman DL (2009) Antitrust economics. Oxford University Press, New York Blair RD, Kaserman DL (2009) Antitrust economics. Oxford University Press, New York
go back to reference Bork RH (1978) The antitrust paradox: a policy at war with itself. Basic Books, New York Bork RH (1978) The antitrust paradox: a policy at war with itself. Basic Books, New York
go back to reference Braeutigam RR (1989) Optimal policies for natural monopoly. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1289–1346CrossRef Braeutigam RR (1989) Optimal policies for natural monopoly. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1289–1346CrossRef
go back to reference Breit W, Elzinga KG (1989) The antitrust casebook: milestones in economic regulation. Dryden, Chicago Breit W, Elzinga KG (1989) The antitrust casebook: milestones in economic regulation. Dryden, Chicago
go back to reference Breyer S (1982) Regulation and its reform. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA Breyer S (1982) Regulation and its reform. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
go back to reference Brozen Y (1971) Concentration and structural and market disequilibria. Antitrust Bull 16:244–248 Brozen Y (1971) Concentration and structural and market disequilibria. Antitrust Bull 16:244–248
go back to reference Camerer C, Issacharoff S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T, Rabin M (2003) Regulation for conservatives: behavioral economics and the case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism’. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 151(3):1211–1254CrossRef Camerer C, Issacharoff S, Loewenstein G, O’Donoghue T, Rabin M (2003) Regulation for conservatives: behavioral economics and the case for ‘Asymmetric Paternalism’. University of Pennsylvania Law Review 151(3):1211–1254CrossRef
go back to reference Carlton DW (2010) Revising the horizontal merger guidelines. J Competition Law Econ 6(3):617–652 Carlton DW (2010) Revising the horizontal merger guidelines. J Competition Law Econ 6(3):617–652
go back to reference Carlton DW, Bamberger GE, Epstein RJ (1995) Antitrust and higher education: was there a conspiracy to restrict financial aid? Rand J Econ 26(Spring):131–147CrossRef Carlton DW, Bamberger GE, Epstein RJ (1995) Antitrust and higher education: was there a conspiracy to restrict financial aid? Rand J Econ 26(Spring):131–147CrossRef
go back to reference Chaloupka FJ (2007) Cigarettes: old firms facing new challenges. In: Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (eds) Industry and firm studies. M.E. Sharpe, Amonk, NY, pp 80–118 Chaloupka FJ (2007) Cigarettes: old firms facing new challenges. In: Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (eds) Industry and firm studies. M.E. Sharpe, Amonk, NY, pp 80–118
go back to reference Cooter R, Ulen T (2007) Law and economics. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA Cooter R, Ulen T (2007) Law and economics. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA
go back to reference Crandall R, Winston C (2003) Does antitrust policy improve consumer welfare? Assessing the evidence. J Econ Perspect 17:2–26CrossRef Crandall R, Winston C (2003) Does antitrust policy improve consumer welfare? Assessing the evidence. J Econ Perspect 17:2–26CrossRef
go back to reference Crane DA (2009) Chicago, Post-Chicago, and Neo-Chicago. University of Chicago Law Review 76:1911–1933 Crane DA (2009) Chicago, Post-Chicago, and Neo-Chicago. University of Chicago Law Review 76:1911–1933
go back to reference Curfman GD, Morrissey S, Drazen JM (2009) Tobacco, public health, and the FDA. New Engl J Med 23:402–403CrossRef Curfman GD, Morrissey S, Drazen JM (2009) Tobacco, public health, and the FDA. New Engl J Med 23:402–403CrossRef
go back to reference Dam K (2006) The law – growth nexus: The rule of law and economic development. Brookings Institution Press Dam K (2006) The law – growth nexus: The rule of law and economic development. Brookings Institution Press
go back to reference Davidson P, Wiseman P, Waggoner J (2010) Will new financial regulations prevent future meltdowns? USA Today, June 28, 2010 Davidson P, Wiseman P, Waggoner J (2010) Will new financial regulations prevent future meltdowns? USA Today, June 28, 2010
go back to reference Demsetz H (1969) Information and efficiency: another view. J Law Econ 12:1–22CrossRef Demsetz H (1969) Information and efficiency: another view. J Law Econ 12:1–22CrossRef
go back to reference Demsetz H (1973) Industry structure, market rivalry, and public policy. J Law Econ 16(1):1–9CrossRef Demsetz H (1973) Industry structure, market rivalry, and public policy. J Law Econ 16(1):1–9CrossRef
go back to reference Demsetz H (1974) Two systems of belief about monopoly. In: Goldschmidt H, Michael Mann H, Fred Weston J (eds) Industrial concentration: the new learning. Little Brown, Boston, pp 164–183 Demsetz H (1974) Two systems of belief about monopoly. In: Goldschmidt H, Michael Mann H, Fred Weston J (eds) Industrial concentration: the new learning. Little Brown, Boston, pp 164–183
go back to reference Eckard EW Jr (1991) Competition and the cigarette TV advertising ban. Econ Inq 29:119–133CrossRef Eckard EW Jr (1991) Competition and the cigarette TV advertising ban. Econ Inq 29:119–133CrossRef
go back to reference Elzinga KG (1969) The antimerger law: pyrrhic victories? J Law Econ 12:43–73CrossRef Elzinga KG (1969) The antimerger law: pyrrhic victories? J Law Econ 12:43–73CrossRef
go back to reference Elzinga KG, Swisher AW (2005) The supreme court and beer Mergers: from Pabst/Blatz to the DOJ-FTC Merger guidelines. J Ind Organ 26(3):245–267CrossRef Elzinga KG, Swisher AW (2005) The supreme court and beer Mergers: from Pabst/Blatz to the DOJ-FTC Merger guidelines. J Ind Organ 26(3):245–267CrossRef
go back to reference Elzinga KG, Swisher AW (2011) Development in US Merger policy: the beer industry as lens. In: Swinnen JFM (ed) The economics of beer. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 196–212CrossRef Elzinga KG, Swisher AW (2011) Development in US Merger policy: the beer industry as lens. In: Swinnen JFM (ed) The economics of beer. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 196–212CrossRef
go back to reference Epstein RJ, DL Rubinfield (2010) Understanding UPP. Berkeley Electron J Theor Econ 10(1) Epstein RJ, DL Rubinfield (2010) Understanding UPP. Berkeley Electron J Theor Econ 10(1)
go back to reference Evans WN, Farrelly MC (1998) The compensating behavior of smokers: taxes, tar, and nicotine. Rand J Econ 29(3):578–595CrossRef Evans WN, Farrelly MC (1998) The compensating behavior of smokers: taxes, tar, and nicotine. Rand J Econ 29(3):578–595CrossRef
go back to reference Fairfax LM (2009) The legal origins theory in crisis. Brigham Young University Law Rev, 1571–1618 Fairfax LM (2009) The legal origins theory in crisis. Brigham Young University Law Rev, 1571–1618
go back to reference Farr S, Tremblay Carol Horton, Tremblay Victor J (2001) The welfare effect of advertising restrictions in the U.S. Cigarette industry. Rev Ind Organ 18(2):147–160CrossRef Farr S, Tremblay Carol Horton, Tremblay Victor J (2001) The welfare effect of advertising restrictions in the U.S. Cigarette industry. Rev Ind Organ 18(2):147–160CrossRef
go back to reference Farrell J, Pappalardo JK, Shelanski H (2010) Economics at the FTC: Mergers, dominant-firm conduct, and consumer behavior. Rev Ind Organ 37:263–277CrossRef Farrell J, Pappalardo JK, Shelanski H (2010) Economics at the FTC: Mergers, dominant-firm conduct, and consumer behavior. Rev Ind Organ 37:263–277CrossRef
go back to reference Farrell J, Shapiro C (2010) Antitrust evaluation of horizontal Mergers: an economic alternative to market definition. Berkeley Electron J Theor Econ 10(1) Farrell J, Shapiro C (2010) Antitrust evaluation of horizontal Mergers: an economic alternative to market definition. Berkeley Electron J Theor Econ 10(1)
go back to reference Federal Trade Commission v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568 (1967) Federal Trade Commission v. Procter & Gamble Co., 386 U.S. 568 (1967)
go back to reference Fillion R (2008) MillerCoors execs face difficult to-do list cutting jobs among tasks for joint outfit. Rocky Mountain News, Denver, June 28, 2008 Fillion R (2008) MillerCoors execs face difficult to-do list cutting jobs among tasks for joint outfit. Rocky Mountain News, Denver, June 28, 2008
go back to reference Fisher AA, Lande RH (1983) Efficiency considerations in Merger enforcement. California Law Rev 71(6):1582–1696 Fisher AA, Lande RH (1983) Efficiency considerations in Merger enforcement. California Law Rev 71(6):1582–1696
go back to reference Fisher FM, McGowan JJ, Greenwood J (1983) Folded, spindled, and mutilated: economic analysis and US v IBM. MIT Press, Cambridge Fisher FM, McGowan JJ, Greenwood J (1983) Folded, spindled, and mutilated: economic analysis and US v IBM. MIT Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Fort R (2007) The sports industry and antitrust. In: Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (eds) Industry and firm studies. Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe, pp 245–266 Fort R (2007) The sports industry and antitrust. In: Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (eds) Industry and firm studies. Armonk, NY, M.E. Sharpe, pp 245–266
go back to reference Gattuso JL (2010) Red tape rising: Obama’s torrent of new regulation. Wall Street Journal, October 29, 2010 Gattuso JL (2010) Red tape rising: Obama’s torrent of new regulation. Wall Street Journal, October 29, 2010
go back to reference Ghosal V (2007) Economics, politics, and merger control. In: Choi JP (ed) Recent developments in antitrust: theory and evidence. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 123–151 Ghosal V (2007) Economics, politics, and merger control. In: Choi JP (ed) Recent developments in antitrust: theory and evidence. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA, pp 123–151
go back to reference Glaeser EL, Shleifer A (2002) Legal origins. Quart J Econ 117(4):1193–1229CrossRef Glaeser EL, Shleifer A (2002) Legal origins. Quart J Econ 117(4):1193–1229CrossRef
go back to reference Gordon M (2010) Bernanke, others working together on overhaul. Washington Post, September 30, 2010 Gordon M (2010) Bernanke, others working together on overhaul. Washington Post, September 30, 2010
go back to reference Greer DF (1992) Industrial organization and public policy. MacMillan, New York Greer DF (1992) Industrial organization and public policy. MacMillan, New York
go back to reference Gruenspecht HK, Lave LB (1989) The economics of health, safety, and the environmental regulation. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1507–1550CrossRef Gruenspecht HK, Lave LB (1989) The economics of health, safety, and the environmental regulation. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1507–1550CrossRef
go back to reference Harrison JL, Theeuwes J (2008) Law and economics. W. W. Norton, New York Harrison JL, Theeuwes J (2008) Law and economics. W. W. Norton, New York
go back to reference Von Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in our society. Am Econ Rev 45(4):519–530 Von Hayek F (1945) The use of knowledge in our society. Am Econ Rev 45(4):519–530
go back to reference Heart HLA (1994) The concept of the law. Clarendon, Oxford, U.K Heart HLA (1994) The concept of the law. Clarendon, Oxford, U.K
go back to reference Higgs R (1978) Landless by law: Japanese immigrants in California agriculture to 1941. J Econ Hist 38(1):205–225CrossRef Higgs R (1978) Landless by law: Japanese immigrants in California agriculture to 1941. J Econ Hist 38(1):205–225CrossRef
go back to reference Horowitz D (2009) Indoctrination U: the left’s war against academic freedom. Encounter Books Horowitz D (2009) Indoctrination U: the left’s war against academic freedom. Encounter Books
go back to reference Hovenkamp H (2008) The antitrust enterprise: principles and execution. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA Hovenkamp H (2008) The antitrust enterprise: principles and execution. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
go back to reference Hoxby CM (2000) Benevolent Colluders? The effects of antitrust action on college financial aid and tuition. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 7754 Hoxby CM (2000) Benevolent Colluders? The effects of antitrust action on college financial aid and tuition. National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper No. 7754
go back to reference Iwasaki N, Tremblay VJ (2009) The effect of marketing regulations on efficiency: LeChatelier versus coordination effects. J Prod Anal 32(1):41–54CrossRef Iwasaki N, Tremblay VJ (2009) The effect of marketing regulations on efficiency: LeChatelier versus coordination effects. J Prod Anal 32(1):41–54CrossRef
go back to reference Johnson RL, Smith DD (1987) A Antitrust division merger procedures and policy, 1968–1984. Antitrust Bull 32(4):967–988, Winter Johnson RL, Smith DD (1987) A Antitrust division merger procedures and policy, 1968–1984. Antitrust Bull 32(4):967–988, Winter
go back to reference Jordon WA (1972) Producer protection, prior market structure and the effects of government regulation. J Law Econ 5:151–176CrossRef Jordon WA (1972) Producer protection, prior market structure and the effects of government regulation. J Law Econ 5:151–176CrossRef
go back to reference Joskow PL, Rose NL (1989) The effects of economic regulation. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1449–1506CrossRef Joskow PL, Rose NL (1989) The effects of economic regulation. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1449–1506CrossRef
go back to reference Keeler TE, The-Wei H, Barnett PG, Manning WG (1993) Taxation, regulation, and addiction: a demand function for cigarettes based on time-series evidence. J Health Econ 12(1):1–18CrossRef Keeler TE, The-Wei H, Barnett PG, Manning WG (1993) Taxation, regulation, and addiction: a demand function for cigarettes based on time-series evidence. J Health Econ 12(1):1–18CrossRef
go back to reference Krattenmaker TG, Pitofsky R (1988) A Antitrust merger policy and the reagan administration. Antitrust Bull 33(2):211–232 Krattenmaker TG, Pitofsky R (1988) A Antitrust merger policy and the reagan administration. Antitrust Bull 33(2):211–232
go back to reference Kwoka JE Jr, White LJ (2009) Antitrust revolution: economics, competition, and policy. Oxford University Press, New York Kwoka JE Jr, White LJ (2009) Antitrust revolution: economics, competition, and policy. Oxford University Press, New York
go back to reference Ladha KK (1990) The pivotal role of the judiciary in the deregulation battle between the executive and legislature. Washington University, Washington Ladha KK (1990) The pivotal role of the judiciary in the deregulation battle between the executive and legislature. Washington University, Washington
go back to reference LaFraniere S (1991) Ivy league schools agree to halt collaboration on financial aid. The Washington Post, May 23, 1991. LaFraniere S (1991) Ivy league schools agree to halt collaboration on financial aid. The Washington Post, May 23, 1991.
go back to reference Landes W, Posner R (1981) Market power in antitrust cases. Harv Law Rev 94:937–996CrossRef Landes W, Posner R (1981) Market power in antitrust cases. Harv Law Rev 94:937–996CrossRef
go back to reference La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2008) The economic consequences of legal origins. J Econ Lit 46(2):285–332CrossRef La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2008) The economic consequences of legal origins. J Econ Lit 46(2):285–332CrossRef
go back to reference Lehn K, Sykuta M (1997) Antitrust and franchise relocation in professional sports: an economic analysis of the raiders case. Antitrust Bull 42:541–563, Fall Lehn K, Sykuta M (1997) Antitrust and franchise relocation in professional sports: an economic analysis of the raiders case. Antitrust Bull 42:541–563, Fall
go back to reference Littlechild SC (1983) Regulation of British telecommunications’ profitability, report to the secretary of state. Department of Industry: Her Majesty’s Stationary Office, London Littlechild SC (1983) Regulation of British telecommunications’ profitability, report to the secretary of state. Department of Industry: Her Majesty’s Stationary Office, London
go back to reference Madrian BC, Shea D (2001) The power of suggestion: Inertia 401(k) participation and savings behavior. Quart J Econ 116(4):1149–1187CrossRef Madrian BC, Shea D (2001) The power of suggestion: Inertia 401(k) participation and savings behavior. Quart J Econ 116(4):1149–1187CrossRef
go back to reference McAfee RP, Sibley DS, Williams MA (2009) Oracle’s acquisition of PeopleSoft: U.S. v. Oracle (2004). In: Kwoka, JE Jr, LJ White (eds) Antitrust revolution: economics, competition, and policy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp 67–88 McAfee RP, Sibley DS, Williams MA (2009) Oracle’s acquisition of PeopleSoft: U.S. v. Oracle (2004). In: Kwoka, JE Jr, LJ White (eds) Antitrust revolution: economics, competition, and policy. New York: Oxford University Press, pp 67–88
go back to reference McGee JS (1958) Predatory price cutting: the standard oil (N.J.) case. J Law Econ 1:137–169CrossRef McGee JS (1958) Predatory price cutting: the standard oil (N.J.) case. J Law Econ 1:137–169CrossRef
go back to reference McGee JS (1971) In defense of industrial concentration. Praeger, New York McGee JS (1971) In defense of industrial concentration. Praeger, New York
go back to reference Meadows E (1981) Bold Departures in Antitrust. Fortune, October 5, 1981, 180–188 Meadows E (1981) Bold Departures in Antitrust. Fortune, October 5, 1981, 180–188
go back to reference Nagler MG (1993) Rather bait than switch: deceptive advertising with bounded consumer rationality. J Public Econ 51:359–378CrossRef Nagler MG (1993) Rather bait than switch: deceptive advertising with bounded consumer rationality. J Public Econ 51:359–378CrossRef
go back to reference National Association of Attorneys General Antitrust Enforcement (1993) Horizontal merger guidelines of the national association of Attorneys general. The Association, Washington, D.C., March 30, 1993 National Association of Attorneys General Antitrust Enforcement (1993) Horizontal merger guidelines of the national association of Attorneys general. The Association, Washington, D.C., March 30, 1993
go back to reference Murphy MC (2007) Philosophy of law. Blackwell, Malden, MA Murphy MC (2007) Philosophy of law. Blackwell, Malden, MA
go back to reference Noll RG (1989a) Economic perspectives on the politics of regulation. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1253–1287CrossRef Noll RG (1989a) Economic perspectives on the politics of regulation. In: Schmalensee R, Willig RD (eds) Handbook of industrial organization, vol II. North-Holland, New York, pp 1253–1287CrossRef
go back to reference Noll RG (1989) The economic theory of regulation after a decade: comments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 48–58 Noll RG (1989) The economic theory of regulation after a decade: comments. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 48–58
go back to reference Paletta D, Hitt G (2010) House vote sends finance overhaul to senate. Wall Street Journal. July 1, 2010 Paletta D, Hitt G (2010) House vote sends finance overhaul to senate. Wall Street Journal. July 1, 2010
go back to reference Pate RH (2004) International anti-cartel enforcement. Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice, November 21, 2004 Pate RH (2004) International anti-cartel enforcement. Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice, November 21, 2004
go back to reference Peltzman S (1976) Toward a more general theory of regulation. J Law Econ, April 1976, 211–240. Peltzman S (1976) Toward a more general theory of regulation. J Law Econ, April 1976, 211–240.
go back to reference Pigou AC (1920) The economics of welfare. MacMillan, London Pigou AC (1920) The economics of welfare. MacMillan, London
go back to reference Pitofsky R (1977) Beyond Nader: consumer protection and the regulation of advertising. Harv Law Rev 90(4):661–701CrossRef Pitofsky R (1977) Beyond Nader: consumer protection and the regulation of advertising. Harv Law Rev 90(4):661–701CrossRef
go back to reference Pitofsky R (ed) (2008) How the Chicago school overshot the mark. Oxford University Press, New York Pitofsky R (ed) (2008) How the Chicago school overshot the mark. Oxford University Press, New York
go back to reference Pollay RW (1994) Promises, promises: self-regulation of US cigarette broadcast advertising in the 1960s. Tob Control 3:134–144CrossRef Pollay RW (1994) Promises, promises: self-regulation of US cigarette broadcast advertising in the 1960s. Tob Control 3:134–144CrossRef
go back to reference Porter RH (1983) A study of cartel stability: the joint executive committee, 1880–1886. Bell J Econ 14:301–314CrossRef Porter RH (1983) A study of cartel stability: the joint executive committee, 1880–1886. Bell J Econ 14:301–314CrossRef
go back to reference Posner RA (1974) Theories of economic regulation. Bell J Econ, Autumn 1974, 335–358. Posner RA (1974) Theories of economic regulation. Bell J Econ, Autumn 1974, 335–358.
go back to reference Posner RA (2001) Antitrust law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Posner RA (2001) Antitrust law. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
go back to reference Posner RA (2009) The failure of capitalism: the crisis of 08 and the descent into depression. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA Posner RA (2009) The failure of capitalism: the crisis of 08 and the descent into depression. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA
go back to reference Priest GL (1977) The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. J Legal Stud 6(1):65–82CrossRef Priest GL (1977) The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. J Legal Stud 6(1):65–82CrossRef
go back to reference Ramsey F (1927) A contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ J 37:47–61CrossRef Ramsey F (1927) A contribution to the theory of taxation. Econ J 37:47–61CrossRef
go back to reference Robinson J (1933) The economics of imperfect competition. Macmillan, London Robinson J (1933) The economics of imperfect competition. Macmillan, London
go back to reference Roe MJ (1996) Chaos and evolution in law and economics. Harv Law Rev 109(3):641–668CrossRef Roe MJ (1996) Chaos and evolution in law and economics. Harv Law Rev 109(3):641–668CrossRef
go back to reference Roe MJ, Siegel JI (2009) Finance and politics: a review essay based on Kenneth Dam’s analysis of legal traditions in the law – growth Nexus. J Econ Lit 47(3):781–800CrossRef Roe MJ, Siegel JI (2009) Finance and politics: a review essay based on Kenneth Dam’s analysis of legal traditions in the law – growth Nexus. J Econ Lit 47(3):781–800CrossRef
go back to reference Salinger MA (2010) Behavioral economics, consumer protection, and antitrust. Competition Policy International, Spring 2010 Salinger MA (2010) Behavioral economics, consumer protection, and antitrust. Competition Policy International, Spring 2010
go back to reference Salop S, Stiglitz J (1977) Bargains and ripoffs: a model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion. Rev Econ Stud 44(3):493–510CrossRef Salop S, Stiglitz J (1977) Bargains and ripoffs: a model of monopolistically competitive price dispersion. Rev Econ Stud 44(3):493–510CrossRef
go back to reference Sappington DEM (1983) Optimal regulation of a multiproduct monopoly with unknown technological capabilities. Bell J Econ 14(2):453–463CrossRef Sappington DEM (1983) Optimal regulation of a multiproduct monopoly with unknown technological capabilities. Bell J Econ 14(2):453–463CrossRef
go back to reference Sappington DEM (2002) Price Regulation. In: Cave ME, Majemdar SK, Vogelsang I (eds) Handbook of telecommunications. Vol. 1, Structure, regulation, and competition. Elsevier, Amsterdam: Sappington DEM (2002) Price Regulation. In: Cave ME, Majemdar SK, Vogelsang I (eds) Handbook of telecommunications. Vol. 1, Structure, regulation, and competition. Elsevier, Amsterdam:
go back to reference Scherer FM, Ross D (1990) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Houghton Mifflin Co., Boston Scherer FM, Ross D (1990) Industrial market structure and economic performance. Houghton Mifflin Co., Boston
go back to reference Sen A (1970) The impossibility of a paretian liberal. J Polit Econ 78(1):152–157CrossRef Sen A (1970) The impossibility of a paretian liberal. J Polit Econ 78(1):152–157CrossRef
go back to reference Sherman R (1992) Capital waste in the rate-of-return regulated firm. J Regul Econ 4:197–204CrossRef Sherman R (1992) Capital waste in the rate-of-return regulated firm. J Regul Econ 4:197–204CrossRef
go back to reference Sherman R (2008) Market regulation. Pearson Addison-Wesley, Boston Sherman R (2008) Market regulation. Pearson Addison-Wesley, Boston
go back to reference Simon CP, Blume L (1994) Mathematical economics. W.W. Norton, New York Simon CP, Blume L (1994) Mathematical economics. W.W. Norton, New York
go back to reference Stevenson R (1982) X-efficiency and interfirm rivarly: evidence in the electric utility industry. Land Econ 58:52–66CrossRef Stevenson R (1982) X-efficiency and interfirm rivarly: evidence in the electric utility industry. Land Econ 58:52–66CrossRef
go back to reference Stigler GJ, Friedland C (1962) What can regulators regulate: the case of electricity. J Law Econ 5:1–16CrossRef Stigler GJ, Friedland C (1962) What can regulators regulate: the case of electricity. J Law Econ 5:1–16CrossRef
go back to reference Takayama A (1969) Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. Am Econ Rev 59:255–260 Takayama A (1969) Behavior of the firm under regulatory constraint. Am Econ Rev 59:255–260
go back to reference Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2003) Libetarian paternalism. Am Econ Rev 93(2):175–179CrossRef Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2003) Libetarian paternalism. Am Econ Rev 93(2):175–179CrossRef
go back to reference Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven Thaler RH, Sunstein CR (2008) Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. Yale University Press, New Haven
go back to reference Tremblay CH, Tremblay VJ (2011b) Recent economic developments in the import and craft segments of the U.S. brewing industry. In: Swinnen JFM (ed) The economics of beer. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 141–160CrossRef Tremblay CH, Tremblay VJ (2011b) Recent economic developments in the import and craft segments of the U.S. brewing industry. In: Swinnen JFM (ed) The economics of beer. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 141–160CrossRef
go back to reference Tremblay VJ (1993) Consistency between the law and its enforcement: the case of mergers. Antitrust Bull 38(2):327–348 Tremblay VJ (1993) Consistency between the law and its enforcement: the case of mergers. Antitrust Bull 38(2):327–348
go back to reference Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (1988) The determinants of horizontal acquisitions: evidence from the U.S. brewing industry. J Ind Econ 37(1):21–45CrossRef Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (1988) The determinants of horizontal acquisitions: evidence from the U.S. brewing industry. J Ind Econ 37(1):21–45CrossRef
go back to reference Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2005) The U.S. brewing industry: data and economic analysis. MIT Press, Cambridge Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2005) The U.S. brewing industry: data and economic analysis. MIT Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2007) Brewing: games firms play. In: Tremblay CH, Tremblay VJ (eds) Industry and firm studies. ME Sharpe, Armonk, NY Tremblay VJ, Tremblay CH (2007) Brewing: games firms play. In: Tremblay CH, Tremblay VJ (eds) Industry and firm studies. ME Sharpe, Armonk, NY
go back to reference Varian HR (2010) Intermediate microeconomics: a modern approach. W.W. Norton, New York Varian HR (2010) Intermediate microeconomics: a modern approach. W.W. Norton, New York
go back to reference Viscusi WK, Harrington JE, Vernon JM (2005) Economics of regulation and antitrust. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA Viscusi WK, Harrington JE, Vernon JM (2005) Economics of regulation and antitrust. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA
go back to reference Vogelsang I (2002) Incentive regulation and competition in public utility markets: a 20-year perspective. J Regul Econ 22(1):5–27CrossRef Vogelsang I (2002) Incentive regulation and competition in public utility markets: a 20-year perspective. J Regul Econ 22(1):5–27CrossRef
go back to reference Von Kalinowski J (1982) Antitrust laws and trade regulation. Mathew Bender and Co, New York Von Kalinowski J (1982) Antitrust laws and trade regulation. Mathew Bender and Co, New York
go back to reference Wacks R (2006) Philosophy of law: a very short introduction. Oxford University Press, New York Wacks R (2006) Philosophy of law: a very short introduction. Oxford University Press, New York
go back to reference Waldman DE (1986) The economics of antitrust: cases and analysis. Little, Brown, and Company, Boston Waldman DE (1986) The economics of antitrust: cases and analysis. Little, Brown, and Company, Boston
go back to reference Werden GJ, Froeb L, Shor M (2010) Behavioral antitrust and merger control. Vanderbilt University Law School, Working Paper Number 10–14, May 2010 Werden GJ, Froeb L, Shor M (2010) Behavioral antitrust and merger control. Vanderbilt University Law School, Working Paper Number 10–14, May 2010
go back to reference Williamson OE (1968) Economies as an antitrust defense: the welfare trade-offs. Am Econ Rev 58(1):18–36 Williamson OE (1968) Economies as an antitrust defense: the welfare trade-offs. Am Econ Rev 58(1):18–36
go back to reference Willig R (2011) Unilateral competitive effects of mergers: upward pricing pressure, product quality, and other extensions. Rev Ind Organ 39(1–2):19–38CrossRef Willig R (2011) Unilateral competitive effects of mergers: upward pricing pressure, product quality, and other extensions. Rev Ind Organ 39(1–2):19–38CrossRef
go back to reference Wright JD (2007) Behavioral law and economics, paternalism, and consumer contracts: an empirical investigation. New York University Journal of law and Liberty, 470–511 Wright JD (2007) Behavioral law and economics, paternalism, and consumer contracts: an empirical investigation. New York University Journal of law and Liberty, 470–511
go back to reference Wright JD (2009) Overshot the Mark? A simple explanation of the Chicago School’s influence on antitrust. Competition Policy International, March 31, 2009 Wright JD (2009) Overshot the Mark? A simple explanation of the Chicago School’s influence on antitrust. Competition Policy International, March 31, 2009
Metadata
Title
Antitrust Law and Regulation
Authors
Victor J. Tremblay
Carol Horton Tremblay
Copyright Year
2012
Publisher
Springer New York
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4614-3241-8_20