Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 3-4/2018

31-01-2018

Budget institutions and taxation

Author: Lasse Aaskoven

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 3-4/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

While a number of different studies have explored the effects of budgetary procedures and the centralization of the budget process on government debt, deficits and spending, few of them have explored whether such fiscal institutions matter for public revenue. This article argues that centralizing the budget process raises the levels of taxation by limiting the ability of individual government officials to veto tax increases in line with common-pool-problem arguments regarding public finances. Using detailed data on budgetary procedures from 15 EU countries, the empirical analysis shows that greater centralization of the budget process increases taxation as a share of GDP and that both the type of budget centralization and level of government fractionalization matter for the size of this effect. The results suggest that further centralizing the budget process limits government debt and deficits by increasing public revenues as well as constraining public spending.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See Alesina et al. (1999) for a study of the effects of different budgetary institutions in Latin America.
 
2
For exception to these findings, see Perotti and Kontopoulos (2002).
 
3
Or the minister responsible for preparing and implementing the public budget.
 
4
This can be represented as either an ideological preference for serving their constituency or an interest in securing future electoral support.
 
5
The finance minister is implicitly assumed to be concerned with balancing the public budget.
 
6
This line of argument resembles a situation where the government has fiscal room to implement tax cuts. Here, coalition members are incentivized to maximize cuts to their constituencies’ tax payments while freeriding on the tax payments of other constituencies. This leads to a common-pool problem, where total taxes end up lower than planned. In contrast, the finance minister takes the total budget balance into account when deciding the tax cut for each tax instrument. Consequently, the tax raised from each instrument—and the total level of taxation—will be greater when the finance minister has greater agenda-setting power than in a decentralized budget regime.
 
7
For a well-cited empirical study of the role of veto players in public budgets, see Tsebelis and Chang (2004).
 
8
These are the “old” EU countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden and the United Kingdom.
 
9
According to personal correspondence with one of the authors, the data most reliably captures actual budget practices and rules until the 2008 financial crisis, which is therefore the end year of the panel. Excluding the years after 2004 (the year of the last survey) from the analysis yields largely similar results.
 
10
In this article, the delegation centralization index is equal to the authors’ Delegation Index, while the contract centralization index is equal to the Fiscal Targets (Long-Term) index (Hallerberg et al. 2009, p. 74). The authors also construct a full Contracts Index, which includes aspects of the budget implementation. Replacing the one type of contracts index with the other yields mostly similar results (results available upon request).
 
11
As previously mentioned, the finance minister might still play an important role as “guardian” of the fiscal targets and their implementation (Hallerberg et al. 2009, p. 51), which might also include working to raise taxes to meet the financing requirements of these fiscal targets.
 
12
The index goes from 0 to 1, lower scores denoting larger government fractionalization, which should be noted when interpreting the results in Appendix C. It is also necessary to note that the government Herfindahl index only measures government size fractionalization, not ideological distances within the government.
 
13
The results are also similar if fractionalization is measured using the govfrac variable from the Database of Political Institutions, which measures the probability of two randomly picked government deputies being from different parties (Cruz et al. 2016). Results available upon request.
 
14
Source: the Comparative Political Dataset.
 
15
New theoretical and empirical studies of veto-player dynamics, which consider issues of time-extended policymaking and credible commitments (Tommasi et al. 2014; Bäck and Lindvall 2015), also generate different or amended theoretical predictions vis-à-vis the effect of veto players on government policy stability and government fiscal policy. This article can be seen as yet another contribution to the amendment of the veto-player framework in budgetary politics.
 
Literature
go back to reference Alesina, A., Hausmann, R., Hommes, R., & Stein, E. (1999). Budget institutions and fiscal performance in Latin America. Journal of Development Economics, 59, 253–273.CrossRef Alesina, A., Hausmann, R., Hommes, R., & Stein, E. (1999). Budget institutions and fiscal performance in Latin America. Journal of Development Economics, 59, 253–273.CrossRef
go back to reference Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Fiscal discipline and the budget process. The American Economic Review Paper and Proceedings, 86(2), 401–407. Alesina, A., & Perotti, R. (1996). Fiscal discipline and the budget process. The American Economic Review Paper and Proceedings, 86(2), 401–407.
go back to reference Armingeon, K., Isler, C., Knöpfel, L., Weisstanner, D., & Engler, S. (2015). Comparative political data set 1960–2013. Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne. Armingeon, K., Isler, C., Knöpfel, L., Weisstanner, D., & Engler, S. (2015). Comparative political data set 1960–2013. Bern: Institute of Political Science, University of Berne.
go back to reference Bäck, H., & Lindvall, J. (2015). Commitment problems in coalitions: a new look at the fiscal policies of multiparty governments. Political Science Research and Methods, 3(1), 53–72.CrossRef Bäck, H., & Lindvall, J. (2015). Commitment problems in coalitions: a new look at the fiscal policies of multiparty governments. Political Science Research and Methods, 3(1), 53–72.CrossRef
go back to reference Cruz, C., Keefer, P., & Scartascini, C. (2016). Database of Political Institutions codebook, 2015 Update (DPI2015). Inter-American Development Bank. Updated version of T. Beck, G. Clarke, A. Groff, P. Keefer, & P. Walsh. 2001. New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176. Cruz, C., Keefer, P., & Scartascini, C. (2016). Database of Political Institutions codebook, 2015 Update (DPI2015). Inter-American Development Bank. Updated version of T. Beck, G. Clarke, A. Groff, P. Keefer, & P. Walsh. 2001. New tools in comparative political economy: The database of political institutions. World Bank Economic Review, 15(1), 165–176.
go back to reference de Haan, J., Jong-A-Pin, R., & Mierau, J. O. (2013). Do budgetary institutions mitigate the common pool problem? New empirical evidence for the EU. Public Choice, 156, 423–441.CrossRef de Haan, J., Jong-A-Pin, R., & Mierau, J. O. (2013). Do budgetary institutions mitigate the common pool problem? New empirical evidence for the EU. Public Choice, 156, 423–441.CrossRef
go back to reference Hallerberg, M., & Scartascini, C. (2015). When do governments improve fiscal institutions Lessons? Lessons from financial crisis and fiscal reforms in Latin America. Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association, 16(1), 41–76. Hallerberg, M., & Scartascini, C. (2015). When do governments improve fiscal institutions Lessons? Lessons from financial crisis and fiscal reforms in Latin America. Economia: Journal of the Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association, 16(1), 41–76.
go back to reference Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R. R., & von Hagen, J. (2007). The design of fiscal rules and forms of governance in European Union countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 338–359.CrossRef Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R. R., & von Hagen, J. (2007). The design of fiscal rules and forms of governance in European Union countries. European Journal of Political Economy, 23, 338–359.CrossRef
go back to reference Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R. R., & von Hagen, J. (2009). Fiscal governance in Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Hallerberg, M., Strauch, R. R., & von Hagen, J. (2009). Fiscal governance in Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Lledó, V., Yoon, S., Fang, X., Mbaye, S., & Kim, Y. (2017). Fiscal rules at a glance. Washington D.C: International Monetary Fund. Lledó, V., Yoon, S., Fang, X., Mbaye, S., & Kim, Y. (2017). Fiscal rules at a glance. Washington D.C: International Monetary Fund.
go back to reference Martin, L. W., & Vanberg, G. (2013). Multiparty government, fiscal institutions, and public spending. The Journal of Politics, 75(4), 953–967.CrossRef Martin, L. W., & Vanberg, G. (2013). Multiparty government, fiscal institutions, and public spending. The Journal of Politics, 75(4), 953–967.CrossRef
go back to reference Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–1426.CrossRef Nickell, S. (1981). Biases in dynamic models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 49(6), 1417–1426.CrossRef
go back to reference Perotti, R., & Kontopoulos, Y. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of Public Economics, 86, 191–222.CrossRef Perotti, R., & Kontopoulos, Y. (2002). Fragmented fiscal policy. Journal of Public Economics, 86, 191–222.CrossRef
go back to reference Slemrod, J. (2004). Are corporate tax rates, or countries, converging? Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1169–1186.CrossRef Slemrod, J. (2004). Are corporate tax rates, or countries, converging? Journal of Public Economics, 88, 1169–1186.CrossRef
go back to reference Tommasi, M., Scartascini, C., & Stein, E. (2014). Veto players and policy adaptability: An intertemporal perspective. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 26(2), 222–248.CrossRef Tommasi, M., Scartascini, C., & Stein, E. (2014). Veto players and policy adaptability: An intertemporal perspective. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 26(2), 222–248.CrossRef
go back to reference Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto players: How political institutions work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Tsebelis, G., & Chang, E. C. C. (2004). Veto players and the structure of budgets in advanced industrialized countries. European Journal of Political Research, 43(3), 449–476.CrossRef Tsebelis, G., & Chang, E. C. C. (2004). Veto players and the structure of budgets in advanced industrialized countries. European Journal of Political Research, 43(3), 449–476.CrossRef
go back to reference Velasco, A. (2000). Debts and deficits with fragmented fiscal policymaking. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 105–125.CrossRef Velasco, A. (2000). Debts and deficits with fragmented fiscal policymaking. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 105–125.CrossRef
go back to reference von Hagen, J., & Harden, I. J. (1995). Budget processes and commitment to fiscal discipline. European Economic Review, 39, 771–779.CrossRef von Hagen, J., & Harden, I. J. (1995). Budget processes and commitment to fiscal discipline. European Economic Review, 39, 771–779.CrossRef
go back to reference Wehner, J. (2010). Institutional constraints on profligate politicians: The conditional effect of partisan fragmentation on budget deficits. Comparative Political Studies, 43(2), 208–229.CrossRef Wehner, J. (2010). Institutional constraints on profligate politicians: The conditional effect of partisan fragmentation on budget deficits. Comparative Political Studies, 43(2), 208–229.CrossRef
go back to reference Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.CrossRef Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Budget institutions and taxation
Author
Lasse Aaskoven
Publication date
31-01-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 3-4/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0507-7

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2018

Public Choice 3-4/2018 Go to the issue

Commissioned Editorial Commentary

Filip Palda: In memoriam