Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2021

03-01-2021

Cold bacon: co-partisan politics in Brazil

Authors: Diogo Baerlocher, Rodrigo Schneider

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper provides evidence of alignment effects between the executive and the legislative branches of the central government. We rely on detailed data on Brazilian intergovernmental grants whose allocations are determined by legislators. The executive branch cannot interfere with the destinies or volumes of grants, but it can control the transfer pace. We group the data into municipalities and estimate the effects of the share of aligned legislators associated with a municipality on the average time to receive grants. We show that legislators politically aligned to the executive branch transfer resources to their constituencies nine months faster than unaligned legislators. To achieve a causal interpretation of these results, we rely on exogenous variations in the shares of elected aligned legislators caused by the phased-in introduction of electronic voting. Our findings regarding how political alignment affects the speed of transfer are consistent across different periods and alternative definitions of the dependent variable.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
See Firpo et al. (2015) for a detailed definition of associated legislators. We also discuss the variable in Sect. 3.2.
 
2
Although possible, that source of endogeneity is less of an issue because voters do not know the party of the executive central government before they elect their federal legislators since all politicians comprising the central government are elected simultaneously in Brazil.
 
3
Voters had to write the name or number of their legislative candidates on the old paper ballot, but for executive elections, they were required only to make a mark close to the candidates’ names that already were printed on the ballot. The new voting system, by requiring voters to type the number of their preferred candidate into a machine, did not affect votes for executive branch candidates.
 
4
Effective candidates are measured as the inverse of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI) of the votes candidates received in each municipality. The effective number of candidates is based on Laakso and Taagepera (1979)’s measure of the effective number of parties and is used commonly in the literature.
 
5
In an interview conducted in Brasília, a bureaucrat working at the Confederação Nacional de Municípios, a branch of the government responsible for the execution of projects, confirmed that they have instructions to speed up the grant process for legislators belonging to the same coalition as the president.
 
6
For example, Finan and Mazzocco (2016) estimate that 26% of legislators’ funds in Brazil are misallocated, compared a social planner’s allocation, suggesting that politicians allocate public funds for political benefits.
 
7
Rodden and Arretche (2004) is an example.
 
8
A competing theory, with seminal contributions by Lindbeck and Weibull (1987) and Dixit and Londregan (1998), suggests that politicians should target “swing voters” to maximize votes. That hypothesis was tested successfully for many countries, e.g., Australia (Worthington and Dollery 1998) and Sweden (Dahlberg and Johansson 2002; Johansson 2003).
 
9
Although that feature helps to understand the mechanism behind our empirical strategy, it is not necessary. As we show in Table 4, our results extend when we include the reelection of Cardoso in 1998 to our sample. Also, Table OA.21 in the Appendix—available on request—shows that the result holds when we enter only 1998 into the analysis.
 
10
The choice of the cutoff (40,500 voters) was based on the number of voting machines available in Brazil at the time. The number of registered voters in 1996 was used to determine the cutoff to avoid manipulation of the electorate in response to EV. Finally, the selection of the four states where EV was introduced was based on geography (remote locations with difficult access, i.e., Amapá and Roraima) and military reasons (states with military bases, i.e., Rio de Janeiro and Alagoas) to test both the ability of electoral authorities to access remote places and to rely on military assistance to implement EV (Fujiwara 2015).
 
11
Fujiwara (2015) shows that enfranchisement was exceptionally high among illiterates and that the consequence was an increase in state expenditure on public healthcare, which improved health outcomes. Schneider et al. (2019) construct a theoretical model showing that as electronic voting disproportionately enfranchised low-income voters, policymakers provided more public goods from which low-income voters cannot be excluded, but contribute smaller shares of the tax revenue collected for their provision. The authors report empirical evidence at the municipality level that local taxation and public provision of health, education, and public employment rose, corroborating their empirical model.
 
12
As in Montero (2012), we define left wing parties as being one of the following: Partido dos Trabalhadores, Partido Democrático Trabalhista, Partido Comunista Brasileiro, Partido Popular Socialista, Partido Comunista do Brasil, Partido Socialista Brasileiro, Partido Socialista dos Trabalhadores Unificados, Partido Verde, Partido Socialismo e Liberdade, or Partido da Causa Operária.
 
13
A maximum amount of money and requests for amendments is set for each member of Congress. Each member currently can claim up to 25 amendments and has approximately USD 4 million to allocate across municipalities. In the period we analyze, close to 85% of the approved amendments’ total value was executed. Thus, the discretion over project execution is less of a concern in our analysis.
 
14
On January 15th, 1997, the normative instruction number one of the Brazilian National Treasury Secretariat. established in chapter six, article 21, provided that grants allocated to public projects should be transferred obeying a schedule that was proposed previously and approved by the central government.
 
15
See, for example, Modzeleski (2017).
 
16
See Angrist (1991) and Lleras-Muney (2005) for examples of grouped data estimates.
 
17
We obtain the same conclusions when we exclude the last year from the construction of the dependent variable. The results are presented in the Appendix Tables OA.19 and OA.20, available on request.
 
18
We also estimate the models on the average number of days to transfer. The results are unchanged and are available in the Appendix Tables OA.16 to OA.19, available on request.
 
19
The definition of associated candidates is crucial because there is no formal relationship between legislators and municipalities. To that point, we follow Firpo et al. (2015) who assign associated candidates to municipalities according to their performance in the local election and the degree of political competition. Specifically, they define associated candidates for municipality m in election year t as legislators elected in year t whose ranks in municipality m and election year t are less than the number of effective candidates in the same municipality and election year. The number of effective candidates depends on vote’s concentration computed by the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.
 
20
The coalition that supported the president elected in 1998 was formed by the following political parties: Partido da Social Democracia Brasileira, Partido do Movimento Democrático Brasileiro, Partido da Frente Liberal, Partido Progressista Brasileiro, Partido Trabalhista Brasileiro, and Partido Social Democrático. The following parties built the coalition that supported the president elected in 2002: Partido dos Trabalhadores, Partido Democrático Trabalhista, Partido Popular Socialista, Partido Verde, Partido Liberal, Partido Comunista do Brasil, Partido da Mobilização, Partido Comunista Brasileiro, Partido Progressista Brasileiro, and Partido Trabalhista Brasileiro.
 
21
We omit the few projects with negative times to transfer.
 
22
We also report results comparing treatment and control groups only in 1998 to avoid this double effect of persistence plus the change in the president’s ideology. The results are in Table OA.21 in the Appendix—available on request—and are unchanged.
 
23
Although we observe increases in the share of votes to left wing parties in presidential elections in the group that adopted EV in 1998, the increase was not enough to elect a left wing president in 1998. Still, one may be concerned about the president punishing such municipalities. In the Appendix Tables OA.6 to OA.15, available on request, we provide evidence that our results hold when we restrict our sample to municipalities with less than 50,000 and 40,500 voters. In these samples, we do not observe a difference in the shares of votes of leftist candidates in the presidential elections. We also show that our results hold when we control for this variable in the Appendix Tables OA.22 and OA.23.
 
24
See Schneider et al. (2019) for a comprehensive discussion concluding that the two groups are comparable.
 
25
The conclusions stand when we perform the analysis assuming the same weights for all municipalities. The results are presented in Appendix Tables OA.1 to OA.5, available on request.
 
26
Recall that in the first year the grants were approved by the previous legislator holding the authority to amend budgets.
 
Literature
go back to reference Albouy, D. (2013). Partisan representation in congress and the geographic distribution of federal funds. The Review of Economic and Statistics, 95(1), 127–141.CrossRef Albouy, D. (2013). Partisan representation in congress and the geographic distribution of federal funds. The Review of Economic and Statistics, 95(1), 127–141.CrossRef
go back to reference Ames, B. (1995). Electoral strategy under open-list proportional representation. American Journal of Political Science, 39(2), 406–433.CrossRef Ames, B. (1995). Electoral strategy under open-list proportional representation. American Journal of Political Science, 39(2), 406–433.CrossRef
go back to reference Ames, B. (2001). The deadlock of democracy in Brazil: Interests, identities, and institutions in comparative politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Ames, B. (2001). The deadlock of democracy in Brazil: Interests, identities, and institutions in comparative politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Angrist, J. D. (1991). Grouped-data estimation and testing in simple labor-supply models. Journal of Econometrics, 47(2–3), 243–266.CrossRef Angrist, J. D. (1991). Grouped-data estimation and testing in simple labor-supply models. Journal of Econometrics, 47(2–3), 243–266.CrossRef
go back to reference Arulampalam, W., Dasgupta, S., Dhillon, A., & Dutta, B. (2009). Electoral goals and center-state transfers: A theoretical model and empirical evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 103–119.CrossRef Arulampalam, W., Dasgupta, S., Dhillon, A., & Dutta, B. (2009). Electoral goals and center-state transfers: A theoretical model and empirical evidence from India. Journal of Development Economics, 88(1), 103–119.CrossRef
go back to reference Azulai, M. D. (2018). The political economy of government formation and local public goods. PhD thesis, London School of Economics and Political Science (United Kingdom). Azulai, M. D. (2018). The political economy of government formation and local public goods. PhD thesis, London School of Economics and Political Science (United Kingdom).
go back to reference Baskaran, T., & Hessami, Z. (2017). Political alignment and intergovernmental transfers in parliamentary systems: Evidence from Germany. Public Choice, 171(1–2), 75–98.CrossRef Baskaran, T., & Hessami, Z. (2017). Political alignment and intergovernmental transfers in parliamentary systems: Evidence from Germany. Public Choice, 171(1–2), 75–98.CrossRef
go back to reference Bracco, E., Lockwood, B., Porcelli, F., & Redoano, M. (2015). Intergovernmental grants as signals and the alignment effect: Theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 123, 78–91.CrossRef Bracco, E., Lockwood, B., Porcelli, F., & Redoano, M. (2015). Intergovernmental grants as signals and the alignment effect: Theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 123, 78–91.CrossRef
go back to reference Brollo, F., & Nannicini, T. (2012). Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: The politics of federal transfers in Brazil. American Political Science Review, 106(4), 742–761.CrossRef Brollo, F., & Nannicini, T. (2012). Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: The politics of federal transfers in Brazil. American Political Science Review, 106(4), 742–761.CrossRef
go back to reference Brollo, F., Nannicini, T., Perotti, R., & Tabellini, G. (2013). The political resource curse. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1759–96.CrossRef Brollo, F., Nannicini, T., Perotti, R., & Tabellini, G. (2013). The political resource curse. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1759–96.CrossRef
go back to reference Bugarin, M., & Marciniuk, F. (2017). Strategic partisan transfers in a fiscal federation: Evidence from a new Brazilian database. Journal of Applied Economics, 20(2), 211–239.CrossRef Bugarin, M., & Marciniuk, F. (2017). Strategic partisan transfers in a fiscal federation: Evidence from a new Brazilian database. Journal of Applied Economics, 20(2), 211–239.CrossRef
go back to reference Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1986). Electoral politics as a redistributive game. The Journal of Politics, 48(2), 370–389.CrossRef Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1986). Electoral politics as a redistributive game. The Journal of Politics, 48(2), 370–389.CrossRef
go back to reference Dahlberg, M., & Johansson, E. (2002). On the vote-purchasing behavior of incumbent governments. American Political Science Review, 96(1), 27–40.CrossRef Dahlberg, M., & Johansson, E. (2002). On the vote-purchasing behavior of incumbent governments. American Political Science Review, 96(1), 27–40.CrossRef
go back to reference Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1998). Fiscal federalism and redistributive politics. Journal of Public Economics, 68(2), 153–180.CrossRef Dixit, A., & Londregan, J. (1998). Fiscal federalism and redistributive politics. Journal of Public Economics, 68(2), 153–180.CrossRef
go back to reference Evans, D. (2011). Pork barrel politics. In The Oxford Handbook of the American Congress. Evans, D. (2011). Pork barrel politics. In The Oxford Handbook of the American Congress.
go back to reference Ferreira, I. F., & Bugarin, M. S. (2007). Transferências voluntárias e ciclo político-orçamentário no federalismo fiscal brasileiro. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 61(3), 271–300.CrossRef Ferreira, I. F., & Bugarin, M. S. (2007). Transferências voluntárias e ciclo político-orçamentário no federalismo fiscal brasileiro. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 61(3), 271–300.CrossRef
go back to reference Finan, F., & Mazzocco, M. (2016). Electoral incentives and the allocation of public funds. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report. Finan, F., & Mazzocco, M. (2016). Electoral incentives and the allocation of public funds. National Bureau of Economic Research: Technical report.
go back to reference Firpo, S., Ponczek, V., & Sanfelice, V. (2015). The relationship between federal budget amendments and local electoral power. Journal of Development Economics, 116, 186–198.CrossRef Firpo, S., Ponczek, V., & Sanfelice, V. (2015). The relationship between federal budget amendments and local electoral power. Journal of Development Economics, 116, 186–198.CrossRef
go back to reference Fujiwara, T. (2015). Voting technology, political responsiveness, and infant health: Evidence from Brazil. Econometrica, 83, 423–464.CrossRef Fujiwara, T. (2015). Voting technology, political responsiveness, and infant health: Evidence from Brazil. Econometrica, 83, 423–464.CrossRef
go back to reference Greggianin, E. (2014). Emendas orçamentárias: importância para os municípios, execução das emendas, orçamento impositivo, orçamento participativo. Pesquisa de Opinião junto aos Gabinetes Parlamentares da Câmara dos Deputados. Estudo Técnico, 16:14. Greggianin, E. (2014). Emendas orçamentárias: importância para os municípios, execução das emendas, orçamento impositivo, orçamento participativo. Pesquisa de Opinião junto aos Gabinetes Parlamentares da Câmara dos Deputados. Estudo Técnico, 16:14.
go back to reference Hidalgo, D. (2012). Renovating democracy: The political consequences of election reforms in post-war Brazil. PhD thesis, UC Berkeley. Hidalgo, D. (2012). Renovating democracy: The political consequences of election reforms in post-war Brazil. PhD thesis, UC Berkeley.
go back to reference Hodler, R., & Raschky, P. A. (2014). Regional favoritism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(2), 995–1033.CrossRef Hodler, R., & Raschky, P. A. (2014). Regional favoritism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(2), 995–1033.CrossRef
go back to reference Johansson, E. (2003). Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: Empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 87(5–6), 883–915.CrossRef Johansson, E. (2003). Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: Empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 87(5–6), 883–915.CrossRef
go back to reference Kauder, B., Potrafke, N., & Reischmann, M. (2016). Do politicians reward core supporters? Evidence from a discretionary grant program. European Journal of Political Economy, 45, 39–56.CrossRef Kauder, B., Potrafke, N., & Reischmann, M. (2016). Do politicians reward core supporters? Evidence from a discretionary grant program. European Journal of Political Economy, 45, 39–56.CrossRef
go back to reference Klašnja, M., & Titiunik, R. (2017). The incumbency curse: Weak parties, term limits, and unfulfilled accountability. American Political Science Review, 111(1), 129–148.CrossRef Klašnja, M., & Titiunik, R. (2017). The incumbency curse: Weak parties, term limits, and unfulfilled accountability. American Political Science Review, 111(1), 129–148.CrossRef
go back to reference Kleibergen, F., & Paap, R. (2006). Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition. Journal of Econometrics, 133(1), 97–126.CrossRef Kleibergen, F., & Paap, R. (2006). Generalized reduced rank tests using the singular value decomposition. Journal of Econometrics, 133(1), 97–126.CrossRef
go back to reference Kriner, D. L., Reeves, A., et al. (2015). Presidential particularism and divide-the-dollar politics. American Political Science Review, 109(1), 155–171.CrossRef Kriner, D. L., Reeves, A., et al. (2015). Presidential particularism and divide-the-dollar politics. American Political Science Review, 109(1), 155–171.CrossRef
go back to reference Laakso, M., & Taagepera, R. (1979). “Effective” number of parties: A measure with application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 12(1), 3–27.CrossRef Laakso, M., & Taagepera, R. (1979). “Effective” number of parties: A measure with application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies, 12(1), 3–27.CrossRef
go back to reference Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. W. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52(3), 273–297.CrossRef Lindbeck, A., & Weibull, J. W. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52(3), 273–297.CrossRef
go back to reference Lleras-Muney, A. (2005). The relationship between education and adult mortality in the United States. The Review of Economic Studies, 72(1), 189–221.CrossRef Lleras-Muney, A. (2005). The relationship between education and adult mortality in the United States. The Review of Economic Studies, 72(1), 189–221.CrossRef
go back to reference Migueis, M. (2013). The effect of political alignment on transfers to Portuguese municipalities. Economics & Politics, 25(1), 110–133.CrossRef Migueis, M. (2013). The effect of political alignment on transfers to Portuguese municipalities. Economics & Politics, 25(1), 110–133.CrossRef
go back to reference Montero, A. P. (2012). A reversal of political fortune: The transitional dynamics of conservative rule in the Brazilian Northeast. Latin American Politics and Society, 54(1), 1–36.CrossRef Montero, A. P. (2012). A reversal of political fortune: The transitional dynamics of conservative rule in the Brazilian Northeast. Latin American Politics and Society, 54(1), 1–36.CrossRef
go back to reference Novaes, L. M. (2018). Disloyal brokers and weak parties. American Journal of Political Science, 62(1), 84–98.CrossRef Novaes, L. M. (2018). Disloyal brokers and weak parties. American Journal of Political Science, 62(1), 84–98.CrossRef
go back to reference Oates, W. E. (1972). Fiscal federalism. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. Oates, W. E. (1972). Fiscal federalism. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.
go back to reference Porto, A., & Sanguinetti, P. (2001). Political determinants of intergovernmental grants: Evidence from Argentina. Economics & Politics, 13(3), 237–256.CrossRef Porto, A., & Sanguinetti, P. (2001). Political determinants of intergovernmental grants: Evidence from Argentina. Economics & Politics, 13(3), 237–256.CrossRef
go back to reference Sakurai, S. N., & Theodoro, M. I. A. (2018). On the relationship between political alignment and government transfers: Triple differences evidence from a developing country. Empirical Economics, 58, 1107–1141.CrossRef Sakurai, S. N., & Theodoro, M. I. A. (2018). On the relationship between political alignment and government transfers: Triple differences evidence from a developing country. Empirical Economics, 58, 1107–1141.CrossRef
go back to reference Schneider, R., Athias, D., & Bugarin, M. (2019). Does enfranchisement affect fiscal policy? Theory and empirical evidence on Brazil. Economics of Governance, 20, 389–412.CrossRef Schneider, R., Athias, D., & Bugarin, M. (2019). Does enfranchisement affect fiscal policy? Theory and empirical evidence on Brazil. Economics of Governance, 20, 389–412.CrossRef
go back to reference Schneider, R., Athias, D., & Bugarin, M. (2020). Electronic voting and public spending: The impact of de facto enfranchisement on federal budget amendments in Brazil. Journal of Applied Economics, 23(1), 299–315.CrossRef Schneider, R., Athias, D., & Bugarin, M. (2020). Electronic voting and public spending: The impact of de facto enfranchisement on federal budget amendments in Brazil. Journal of Applied Economics, 23(1), 299–315.CrossRef
go back to reference Schneider, R., & Senters, K. N. (2018). Winners and losers of the ballot: Electronic vs. traditional paper voting systems in Brazil. Latin American Politics and Society, 60(2), 41–60.CrossRef Schneider, R., & Senters, K. N. (2018). Winners and losers of the ballot: Electronic vs. traditional paper voting systems in Brazil. Latin American Politics and Society, 60(2), 41–60.CrossRef
go back to reference Solé-Ollé, A., & Sorribas-Navarro, P. (2008). The effects of partisan alignment on the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. Differences-in-differences estimates for Spain. Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2302–2319.CrossRef Solé-Ollé, A., & Sorribas-Navarro, P. (2008). The effects of partisan alignment on the allocation of intergovernmental transfers. Differences-in-differences estimates for Spain. Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2302–2319.CrossRef
go back to reference Worthington, A. C., & Dollery, B. E. (1998). The political determination of intergovernmental grants in Australia. Public Choice, 94(3), 299–315.CrossRef Worthington, A. C., & Dollery, B. E. (1998). The political determination of intergovernmental grants in Australia. Public Choice, 94(3), 299–315.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Cold bacon: co-partisan politics in Brazil
Authors
Diogo Baerlocher
Rodrigo Schneider
Publication date
03-01-2021
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2021
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-020-00869-4

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2021

Public Choice 1-2/2021 Go to the issue