Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2014

01-10-2014

Constitutional verbosity and social trust

Authors: Christian Bjørnskov, Stefan Voigt

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

A common argument in the trust literature is that high-trust cultures allow efficient commercial contracts to be shorter, covering fewer contingencies. We take this idea to the topic of social contracts. Specifically, we ask whether social trust affects the length and detail of constitutions. Cross-country estimates suggest that national trust levels are indeed robustly and negatively associated with the length of countries’ constitutions.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
We are definitely not the first to be interested in the lengths of constitutions. There is, e.g., a small literature asking whether U.S. states with a more independent judiciary are less likely to amend their constitutions—and, in all likelihood, increase their lenghts—because in those states the “cheaper” option of passing new legislation would be sufficiently credible to convince those who demand special-interest legislation of the likely endurance of the newly passed legislation. Crain and Tollison (1979), Anderson et al. (1989, 1990) are examples of this literature.
 
2
Reksulak et al. (2004) inquire into the efficiency of language development from a more general point of view. They find that language as a spontaneous order does, indeed, display characteristics of a network good. In particular, they find that the number of additional words of the English language—as documented in the Oxford English Dictionary—is declining with increases in wealth and population.
 
3
This is similar, but not identical to the insurance function of constitutions mentioned by Ginsburg (2002). There, politicians who cannot be sure to constitute the majority tomorrow agree on introducing encompassing judicial review to establish a non-majoritarian actor who, they hope, will interpret the constitution according to the intentions of the framers. There are a host of questions closely related to the attempt of current societies to try to bind future societies via constitutional detail. We merely mention some of them here without discussing them, however: what is the relationship between constitutional detail (measured in the length of a constitution) and the formal difficulty of amending it? Are very precisely worded constitutions less likely to be implemented in practice than more open ones? On what normative grounds can current societies ever aspire to constrain the ways future societies make choices and so on.
 
4
Another area in which values and norms are extremely stable over very long periods of time has just been described by Alesina et al. (2013). They report a stable relationship between agricultural societies in which the plough traditionally played a dominant role and unequal gender norms today. Persistence holds even among immigrants into European countries and the United States although all of them were born and raised in the ‘new’ country.
 
5
Our major source for this information is the Encyclopaedia Britannica (2013). However, in many cases, we employed Wikipedia as an alternative source of information. We note that the two sources virtually never disagree.
 
6
In the full dataset, the observations for 110 countries are almost complete. Note that as Luxembourg is not covered in any databases of historical GDP data, the country drops out when adding GDP.
 
7
In principle, constitutional length and detail are count data, and we would therefore want to use a Poison estimator or similar discrete data estimator. However, the data in practice form 110 categories and do not form clusters of values, but are distributed as a continuous variable. In such cases, OLS remains consistent and is more efficient than the count data alternatives.
 
8
Among other instrumental variables used in previous versions are the severity of the winter climate (temperature average and variability), whether or not the predominant language allows dropping the personal pronoun, the level or salience of religious beliefs, and dummies for whether the predominant religion is Protestant, Catholic, Muslim or Eastern (Hindu or Buddhist). Combinations of these variables also yield good test statistics, as first stage F statistics are above 10 and no combinations exhibit significant Hansen J statistics.
 
9
Note that we also tested for the potential influence of predominant religions. When entering regional controls in the specification, we find no significant evidence of religious differences (F=.58; p<.719). Similar non-results apply to a long list of variables, including ethnic, linguistic and religious diversity, geography (country size, latitude and island status) and whether or not countries are former colonies.
 
10
As such, when Kurrild-Klitgaard (2001) finds that current levels of economic development are negatively associated with the lengths of constitutions, it therefore seems unlikely to be the result of wealth-based selection of constitutional features. Instead, the combination of a negative association between current wealth and constitutional garrulity and no association between garrulity and wealth levels when the constitution was written suggests either of two possibilities: (1) that shorter constitutions are somehow conducive to very long-run growth; or (2) that certain factors are common to long-run growth and the ability to write relatively short constitutions.
 
11
The point estimates (standard errors) when the other two instruments are entered individually are: Flag ratings −101.978 (75.875) and the Nordic dummy 237.987 (4931.473). None of the variables are redundant as instruments, with test statistics of p<.01 (Nordic), p<.056 (monarchy) and p<.01 (flag ratings). Finally, as shown by Bjørnskov and Méon (in press), this particular set of instruments is likely to provide identification of trust across the sample, thus avoiding the problem of heterogeneous first-stage identification.
 
12
In a working paper version, we provide simple evidence suggesting that constitutions that are overlong, by the arguments set out in Sect. 2, are indeed associated with better long-run economic consequences. To keep the argument succinct and the paper short, we do not present this evidence in the present paper.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401. CrossRef Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 91, 1369–1401. CrossRef
go back to reference Aghion, P., Algan, Y., Cahuc, P., & Shleifer, A. (2010). Regulations and distrust. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 25, 1015–1049. CrossRef Aghion, P., Algan, Y., Cahuc, P., & Shleifer, A. (2010). Regulations and distrust. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 25, 1015–1049. CrossRef
go back to reference Aidt, T. (2003). Economic analysis of corruption: a survey. The Economic Journal, 113, F632–F652. CrossRef Aidt, T. (2003). Economic analysis of corruption: a survey. The Economic Journal, 113, F632–F652. CrossRef
go back to reference Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (2003). The size of nations. Cambridge: MIT Press. Alesina, A., & Spolaore, E. (2003). The size of nations. Cambridge: MIT Press.
go back to reference Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2013). On the origins of gender roles: women and the plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(2), 469–530. CrossRef Alesina, A., Giuliano, P., & Nunn, N. (2013). On the origins of gender roles: women and the plough. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(2), 469–530. CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, G., Shugart, W. II., & Tollison, R. (1989). On the incentives of judges to enforce legislative wealth transfers. Journal of Law & Economics, 32, 215–228. CrossRef Anderson, G., Shugart, W. II., & Tollison, R. (1989). On the incentives of judges to enforce legislative wealth transfers. Journal of Law & Economics, 32, 215–228. CrossRef
go back to reference Anderson, G., Martin, D., Shugart, W. II., & Tollison, R. (1990). Behind the veil: the political economy of constitutional change. In W. Crain & R. Tollison (Eds.), Predicting politics—essays in empirical public choice (pp. 89–100). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Anderson, G., Martin, D., Shugart, W. II., & Tollison, R. (1990). Behind the veil: the political economy of constitutional change. In W. Crain & R. Tollison (Eds.), Predicting politics—essays in empirical public choice (pp. 89–100). Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
go back to reference Berggren, N., & Bjørnskov, C. (2011). Is the importance of religion in daily life related to social trust? Cross-country and cross-state comparisons. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 80, 459–480. CrossRef Berggren, N., & Bjørnskov, C. (2011). Is the importance of religion in daily life related to social trust? Cross-country and cross-state comparisons. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 80, 459–480. CrossRef
go back to reference Bjørnskov, C. (2010). How does social trust lead to better governance? An attempt to separate electoral and bureaucratic mechanisms. Public Choice, 144, 323–346. CrossRef Bjørnskov, C. (2010). How does social trust lead to better governance? An attempt to separate electoral and bureaucratic mechanisms. Public Choice, 144, 323–346. CrossRef
go back to reference Bjørnskov, C., Svendsen, G. T. (2013). Does social trust determine the size of the welfare state? Evidence using historical identification. Public Choice, 157, 269–286. CrossRef Bjørnskov, C., Svendsen, G. T. (2013). Does social trust determine the size of the welfare state? Evidence using historical identification. Public Choice, 157, 269–286. CrossRef
go back to reference Bjørnskov, C., & Méon, P.-G. Bjørnskov, C., Méon, P.-G. (in press). Is trust the missing root of institutions, education, and development? Forthcoming in Public Choice. Bjørnskov, C., & Méon, P.-G. Bjørnskov, C., Méon, P.-G. (in press). Is trust the missing root of institutions, education, and development? Forthcoming in Public Choice.
go back to reference Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2013). Comparative historical political economy. Journal of Institutional Economics, 9, 285–301. CrossRef Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2013). Comparative historical political economy. Journal of Institutional Economics, 9, 285–301. CrossRef
go back to reference Boix, C., & Posner, D. N. (1998). Social capital: explaining its origins and effects on government performance. British Journal of Political Science, 28, 686–695. CrossRef Boix, C., & Posner, D. N. (1998). Social capital: explaining its origins and effects on government performance. British Journal of Political Science, 28, 686–695. CrossRef
go back to reference Brown, M., & Uslaner, E. M. (2005). Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. American Political Research, 31, 1–27. Brown, M., & Uslaner, E. M. (2005). Inequality, trust, and civic engagement. American Political Research, 31, 1–27.
go back to reference Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press. Buchanan, J., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent: logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.
go back to reference Cox, J. C., Ostrom, E., Walker, J. M., Castillo, A. J., Coleman, E., Holahan, R., Schoon, M., & Steed, B. (2009). Trust in private and common property experiments. Southern Economic Journal, 75, 957–975. Cox, J. C., Ostrom, E., Walker, J. M., Castillo, A. J., Coleman, E., Holahan, R., Schoon, M., & Steed, B. (2009). Trust in private and common property experiments. Southern Economic Journal, 75, 957–975.
go back to reference Crain, W. M., & Tollison, R. (1979). Constitutional change in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 165–175. CrossRef Crain, W. M., & Tollison, R. (1979). Constitutional change in an interest-group perspective. Journal of Legal Studies, 8, 165–175. CrossRef
go back to reference Dinesen, P. T. (2012a). Does generalized (dis)trust travel? Examining the impact of cultural heritage and destination country environment on trust of immigrants. Political Psychology, 33, 495–511. CrossRef Dinesen, P. T. (2012a). Does generalized (dis)trust travel? Examining the impact of cultural heritage and destination country environment on trust of immigrants. Political Psychology, 33, 495–511. CrossRef
go back to reference Dinesen, P. T. (2012b). Parental transmission of trust or perceptions of institutional fairness: generalized trust of non-western immigrants in a high-trust society. Comparative Politics, 44, 273–289. CrossRef Dinesen, P. T. (2012b). Parental transmission of trust or perceptions of institutional fairness: generalized trust of non-western immigrants in a high-trust society. Comparative Politics, 44, 273–289. CrossRef
go back to reference Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2006). The intergenerational transmission of risk and trust attitudes. IZA working paper 2380, Bonn, Institute for the Study of Labor. Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2006). The intergenerational transmission of risk and trust attitudes. IZA working paper 2380, Bonn, Institute for the Study of Labor.
go back to reference Dunning, T. (2008). Model specification in instrumental variables regression. Political Analysis, 16, 290–302. CrossRef Dunning, T. (2008). Model specification in instrumental variables regression. Political Analysis, 16, 290–302. CrossRef
go back to reference Durante, R. (2011). Risk, cooperation and the economic origins of social trust: an empirical investigation. Mimeo, Paris: Science-Po. Durante, R. (2011). Risk, cooperation and the economic origins of social trust: an empirical investigation. Mimeo, Paris: Science-Po.
go back to reference Felton, E. (2001). Finders keepers? Reader’s Digest (pp. 103–107). Felton, E. (2001). Finders keepers? Reader’s Digest (pp. 103–107).
go back to reference Ginsburg, T. (2002). Economic analysis and the design of constitutional courts. Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 3, 49–85. CrossRef Ginsburg, T. (2002). Economic analysis and the design of constitutional courts. Theoretical Inquiries in Law, 3, 49–85. CrossRef
go back to reference Ginsburg, T., Elkins, Z., & Melton, J. (2009). The endurance of national constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Ginsburg, T., Elkins, Z., & Melton, J. (2009). The endurance of national constitutions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Glaeser, E., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Legal origins. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1193–1229. CrossRef Glaeser, E., & Shleifer, A. (2002). Legal origins. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1193–1229. CrossRef
go back to reference Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Long term persistence. NBER Working Paper 14278. Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2008). Long term persistence. NBER Working Paper 14278.
go back to reference Johnson, N. D., & Mislin, A. (2012). How much should we trust the world values survey trust question? Economics Letters, 116, 210–212. CrossRef Johnson, N. D., & Mislin, A. (2012). How much should we trust the world values survey trust question? Economics Letters, 116, 210–212. CrossRef
go back to reference Katz, H. A., & Rotter, J. B. (1969). Interpersonal trust scores of college students and their parents. Child Development, 40, 657–661. CrossRef Katz, H. A., & Rotter, J. B. (1969). Interpersonal trust scores of college students and their parents. Child Development, 40, 657–661. CrossRef
go back to reference Knack, S. (2002). Social capital and the quality of government: evidence from the states. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 772–785. CrossRef Knack, S. (2002). Social capital and the quality of government: evidence from the states. American Journal of Political Science, 46, 772–785. CrossRef
go back to reference Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic pay-off? A cross-country investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1251–1288. CrossRef Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does social capital have an economic pay-off? A cross-country investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112, 1251–1288. CrossRef
go back to reference Kong, D. T. (2013). Examining a climatoeconomic contexualization of generalized social trust mediated by uncertainty avoidance. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 44, 574–588. CrossRef Kong, D. T. (2013). Examining a climatoeconomic contexualization of generalized social trust mediated by uncertainty avoidance. Journal of Cross-Cultural Psychology, 44, 574–588. CrossRef
go back to reference Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2001). Velstandens grundlov: magtdeling, rettigheder og gevinstsøgning. Politica, 33(1), 41–65. Kurrild-Klitgaard, P. (2001). Velstandens grundlov: magtdeling, rettigheder og gevinstsøgning. Politica, 33(1), 41–65.
go back to reference La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Trust in large organizations. The American Economic Review, 87(2), 333–338. La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Trust in large organizations. The American Economic Review, 87(2), 333–338.
go back to reference Leff, N. (1964). Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. American Behavioral Scientist, 8, 8–14. CrossRef Leff, N. (1964). Economic development through bureaucratic corruption. American Behavioral Scientist, 8, 8–14. CrossRef
go back to reference Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2010). Polity IV project: political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2008: dataset users’ manual. Maryland: University of Maryland. Marshall, M. G., & Jaggers, K. (2010). Polity IV project: political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–2008: dataset users’ manual. Maryland: University of Maryland.
go back to reference Montenegro, A. (1995). Constitutional design and economic performance. Constitutional Political Economy, 6, 161–195. CrossRef Montenegro, A. (1995). Constitutional design and economic performance. Constitutional Political Economy, 6, 161–195. CrossRef
go back to reference Nunn, N. (2012). Culture and the historical process. Economic History of Developing Regions, 27, 108–126. CrossRef Nunn, N. (2012). Culture and the historical process. Economic History of Developing Regions, 27, 108–126. CrossRef
go back to reference Nunn, N., & Wantchekon, L. (2011). The trans-Atlantic slave trade and the evolution of mistrust in Africa: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 101, 3221–3252. CrossRef Nunn, N., & Wantchekon, L. (2011). The trans-Atlantic slave trade and the evolution of mistrust in Africa: an empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 101, 3221–3252. CrossRef
go back to reference Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press. Olson, M. (1982). The rise and decline of nations. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Pinotti, P. (2012). Trust, regulation and market failures. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94, 650–658. CrossRef Pinotti, P. (2012). Trust, regulation and market failures. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94, 650–658. CrossRef
go back to reference Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Putnam, R. (1993). Making democracy work. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Reksulak, M., Shugart, W. II., & Tollison, R. (2004). Economics and English: language growth in economic perspective. Southern Economic Journal, 71, 232–259. CrossRef Reksulak, M., Shugart, W. II., & Tollison, R. (2004). Economics and English: language growth in economic perspective. Southern Economic Journal, 71, 232–259. CrossRef
go back to reference Robbins, B. G. (2012). Institutional quality and generalized trust: a nonrecursive causal model. Social Indicators Research, 107, 235–258. CrossRef Robbins, B. G. (2012). Institutional quality and generalized trust: a nonrecursive causal model. Social Indicators Research, 107, 235–258. CrossRef
go back to reference Rothstein, B., Uslaner, E.M. (2005). All for all: equality, corruption, and social trust. World Politics, 58, 41–72. CrossRef Rothstein, B., Uslaner, E.M. (2005). All for all: equality, corruption, and social trust. World Politics, 58, 41–72. CrossRef
go back to reference Sapienza, P., Toldra, A., & Zingales, L. (2007). Understanding trust. NBER Working Paper no. 13387. Sapienza, P., Toldra, A., & Zingales, L. (2007). Understanding trust. NBER Working Paper no. 13387.
go back to reference Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Uslaner, E. M. (2002). The moral foundations of trust. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Uslaner, E. M. (2008). Where you stand depends on where your grandparents sat: the inheritability of generalized trust. Public Opinion Quarterly, 72, 725–740. CrossRef Uslaner, E. M. (2008). Where you stand depends on where your grandparents sat: the inheritability of generalized trust. Public Opinion Quarterly, 72, 725–740. CrossRef
go back to reference Voigt, S. (2009). Explaining constitutional garrulity. International Review of Law and Economics, 29, 290–303. CrossRef Voigt, S. (2009). Explaining constitutional garrulity. International Review of Law and Economics, 29, 290–303. CrossRef
go back to reference Williamson, O. E. (2000). The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 595–613. CrossRef Williamson, O. E. (2000). The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 595–613. CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Constitutional verbosity and social trust
Authors
Christian Bjørnskov
Stefan Voigt
Publication date
01-10-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-013-0129-z

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2014

Public Choice 1-2/2014 Go to the issue