Skip to main content
Top
Published in:
Cover of the book

2015 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

Demand for Wealth-Reducing Institutional Change: The Role of Ideas and Interests

Author : Thráinn Eggertsson

Published in: The Political Economy of Governance

Publisher: Springer International Publishing

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Rodrik (Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(1):189–208, Winter 2014), in a recent paper, calls on economists to recognize the role of ideas in institutional change. This chapter takes up the challenge by considering ideas about how the world works and ideas about the legitimacy of social arrangements, distinguishing between instrumental models (the relations between instruments and outcomes) and moral models (issues of legitimacy). I then explore an empirical case, the efforts by the government of Iceland 2009–2013 to dismantle the country’s regulatory system of ocean fisheries, which is based on individual transferable quotas and widely seen as the most efficient system of its kind in Europe. The exports of fish products have for more than a century been Iceland’s engine of growth. The attempts at introducing inefficient institutions came in the wake of, and even as a response to the country’s dramatic 2008 financial collapse. I identify seven instrumental and moral theories that were crucial for the reform process. The decision makers’ varying understanding and acceptance of these ideas gave substance to the traditional variables of power and interests and influenced how the agents responded to individual transferable quotas.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
See Kuran (1995) on preference falsification. We may theorize about types of environments that are most likely to stimulate creativity but obviously we do not foresee new ideas.
 
2
The distinction between the top-down and bottom-up paradigms bears a superficial but misleading resemblance to the macroeconomics and microeconomics distinction in economic theory. The content of mainstream economics changes as the ideological pendulum swings between the two paradigms. In the bottom-up phase, macroeconomics takes on the appearance of microeconomics.
 
3
Bhagwati (1978), in an early recognition of the limits to reform, refers to the implications of endogenous policy as the “determinacy paradox.” Eggertsson (2005, 142–145) discusses the determinacy paradox.
 
4
The authorities in China maintained existing planning quotas but allowed economic agents to produce for the market once they had met the assigned planning targets, thus creating opportunities for the agents to profit. The dual-track system, at least in theory, came close to meeting the marginal efficiency conditions of neoclassical economics (Qian 2003).
 
5
Instruments of policy are visible and unambiguous but the related outcomes are not, for instance, in the case of the death penalty. Uncertainty about outcomes creates an opportunity for competing social entrepreneurs to make their cases for and against particular institutions.
 
6
The same agent can be simultaneously both material and moral duty bearer, although empirically it may be impossible to measure the impact of each component on behavior.
 
7
In theory, a fisheries ministry could complement a TAC with a long list of constraints intended to prevent indirect open access. The industry would then be micromanaged by the ministry. Such attempts have not been successful.
 
8
In 2011 the fishing industry employed some 5 % of the Icelandic labor force. The industry contributed 11 % to GDP and 38 % to the country’s goods exports. The export share underestimates the importance of the fisheries because the other major export item is primary aluminum and ferrosilicon made from imported metallic minerals. The producers use the country’s abundant geothermal and hydroelectric energy to power their smelters.
 
9
On the EU fisheries policy, see Khalilian et al. (2010).
 
10
Eggertsson (1990) discusses these models in greater detail and provides basic references.
 
11
The industry’s average EBITDA was 7 % in 1980–1984, 15 % in 1984–1992, and 21 % in 1992–2010. The rise and fall of the exchange value of the króna have also influenced EBITDA Íslandsbanki 2012, Figure 11). Note that Iceland caught 430,000 tons of cod in 1980 and only 157,000 in 2012. Currently the cod stocks appear to be recovering fast. The allowed catch for the 2013–2014 season is 215,000 tons.
 
12
The fishing industry, of course, contributes toward the war chests of the Independence Party.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2008). The role of institutions in growth and development. Working Paper No. 10, Commission on Growth and Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2008). The role of institutions in growth and development. Working Paper No. 10, Commission on Growth and Development. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity and poverty. New York: Crown. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity and poverty. New York: Crown.
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2013). Economics versus politics: Pitfalls of policy advice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 173–192.CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2013). Economics versus politics: Pitfalls of policy advice. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23(2), 173–192.CrossRef
go back to reference Barzel, Y. (1989). The economic analysis of property rights. New York: Cambridge University Press. Barzel, Y. (1989). The economic analysis of property rights. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Bhagwati, J. (1978). Anatomy and consequences of exchange control regimes. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger. Bhagwati, J. (1978). Anatomy and consequences of exchange control regimes. Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.
go back to reference Caplan, B. (2001). Rational ignorance versus rational irrationality. Kyklos, 54(2), 3–26.CrossRef Caplan, B. (2001). Rational ignorance versus rational irrationality. Kyklos, 54(2), 3–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Chai, S. K. (1998). Endogenous ideology formation and economic policy in former colonies. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 46, 263–290.CrossRef Chai, S. K. (1998). Endogenous ideology formation and economic policy in former colonies. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 46, 263–290.CrossRef
go back to reference Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef
go back to reference Eggertsson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and organization. New York: Cambridge University Press. Eggertsson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and organization. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Eggertsson, T. (2005). Imperfect institutions: Possibilities and limits of reform. New York: Cambridge University Press. Eggertsson, T. (2005). Imperfect institutions: Possibilities and limits of reform. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Íslandsbanki. (2012). íslenski sjávarútvegurinn [The fishing industry]. Reykjavik. Íslandsbanki. (2012). íslenski sjávarútvegurinn [The fishing industry]. Reykjavik.
go back to reference Khalilian, S., Froese, R., Proelss, A., & Requate, T. (2010). Designed for failure: A critique of the common fisheries policy of the European Union. Marine Policy, 34(6), 1178–1182.CrossRef Khalilian, S., Froese, R., Proelss, A., & Requate, T. (2010). Designed for failure: A critique of the common fisheries policy of the European Union. Marine Policy, 34(6), 1178–1182.CrossRef
go back to reference Knight, F. H. (1933). Review of the philosophy of Henry George, by George R. Geiger. Journal of Political Economy, 41(5), 687–690.CrossRef Knight, F. H. (1933). Review of the philosophy of Henry George, by George R. Geiger. Journal of Political Economy, 41(5), 687–690.CrossRef
go back to reference Knight, F. H. (1953). The fallacies of the single tax. Freeman, 809–811. Knight, F. H. (1953). The fallacies of the single tax. Freeman, 809–811.
go back to reference Knútsson, O., & Kristófersson, D. M. (2014). Samanburdur a fiskveidistjornunarkerfum [A comparison of systems of fisheries regulation]. Frjals verslun, (5), 64–69. Knútsson, O., & Kristófersson, D. M. (2014). Samanburdur a fiskveidistjornunarkerfum [A comparison of systems of fisheries regulation]. Frjals verslun, (5), 64–69.
go back to reference Kuran, T. (1995). Private truths, public lies: The social consequences of preference falsification. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Kuran, T. (1995). Private truths, public lies: The social consequences of preference falsification. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Leighton, W., & López, E. (2013). Madmen, intellectuals, and academic scribblers: The economic engine of political change. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Leighton, W., & López, E. (2013). Madmen, intellectuals, and academic scribblers: The economic engine of political change. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
go back to reference North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic development. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic development. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of economic change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Qian, Y. (2003). How reform worked in China. In D. Rodrik (Ed.), In search of prosperity: Analytical narratives on economic growth (pp. 297–333). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Qian, Y. (2003). How reform worked in China. In D. Rodrik (Ed.), In search of prosperity: Analytical narratives on economic growth (pp. 297–333). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Rodrik, D. (2014). When ideas trump interests: Preferences, worldviews, and policy innovations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(1), 189–208.CrossRef Rodrik, D. (2014). When ideas trump interests: Preferences, worldviews, and policy innovations. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(1), 189–208.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Demand for Wealth-Reducing Institutional Change: The Role of Ideas and Interests
Author
Thráinn Eggertsson
Copyright Year
2015
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-15551-7_1