Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2018

20-06-2018

Dynamic estimation of ideal points for the US Congress

Authors: Brandon Marshall, Michael Peress

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Theories of candidate positioning suggest that candidates will respond dynamically to their electoral environment. Because of the difficulty of obtaining “bridge votes”, most existing approaches for estimating the ideal points of members of Congress generate static ideal points or ideal points that move linearly over time. We propose an approach for dynamic ideal point estimation using Project Vote Smart’s National Political Awareness Test to construct bridge votes. We use our dynamic estimates to measure aggregate change, to measure individual-level change, and to study the institutional and structural factors that explain the changing positions of House candidates and members of Congress. We demonstrate that while the Republican Party has been selecting increasingly extreme candidates, Democratic incumbents have become more extreme while in office. We also find that the congruence between elected members of Congress and their constituents is mostly explained by the selection as opposed to the responsiveness of the candidate. Nonetheless, we find evidence of dynamic responsiveness of incumbents in specific circumstances. We find that competitiveness, midterm elections, and sharing the president’s party affiliation are associated with greater responsiveness. Conversely, retirement is not associated with a change in responsiveness. We find no evidence of responsiveness of challengers. Finally, we find that close elections draw challengers who are more in line with the district’s ideology.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
To clarify, DW-Nominate Common Space scores are static estimates for members of the House and Senate on the same scale. DW-Nominate scores allow for linear change in the estimates of members of the House and Senate, though the House and Senate estimates are not on the same scale.
 
2
The coded responses are not archived and are over-written each time a candidate runs for election. The candidates’ responses to the NPAT are archived.
 
3
Each member of Congress would thus have a separate ideal point for each term they served and each candidate would have a separate ideal point for each congressional election in which they participated.
 
4
Treier (2009) uses the term "conversion" to refer to the change in ideology in a legislature due to continuing members changing their positions.
 
5
The extent of measurement error is quantified by the standard errors of the estimates.
 
6
Bernhardt and Ingberman (1985) have argued that the ability of incumbents to change their positions may be limited because such changes may lead voters to become more uncertain about the positions of the candidates and voters may be risk averse.
 
7
Note that base the party of the incumbent is omitted because fixed effects for individual members of Congress have been entered.
 
8
The mean district ideology in the sample is 0.141, implying that the point estimate of the marginal effect of retiring for Democratic candidates in the mean district is \(0.219 + 0.170\,*\,0.141 = 0.243\).
 
Literature
go back to reference Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Alesina, A., & Rosenthal, H. (1995). Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., & Stewart, C. (2001). Candidate positioning in U.S. House elections. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 136–159.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., & Stewart, C. (2001). Candidate positioning in U.S. House elections. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 136–159.CrossRef
go back to reference Asmussen, N., & Jo, J. (2016). Anchors away: A new approach for estimating ideal points comparable across time and chambers. Political Analysis, 24, 172–188.CrossRef Asmussen, N., & Jo, J. (2016). Anchors away: A new approach for estimating ideal points comparable across time and chambers. Political Analysis, 24, 172–188.CrossRef
go back to reference Bafumi, J., Erikson, R., & Wlezien, C. (2010). Balancing, generic polls and midterm congressional elections. Journal of Politics, 72, 705–719.CrossRef Bafumi, J., Erikson, R., & Wlezien, C. (2010). Balancing, generic polls and midterm congressional elections. Journal of Politics, 72, 705–719.CrossRef
go back to reference Battista, J., Peress, M., & Richman, J. (2013). Common space ideal points, committee assignments, and financial interests in the state legislatures. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 13, 70–87.CrossRef Battista, J., Peress, M., & Richman, J. (2013). Common space ideal points, committee assignments, and financial interests in the state legislatures. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 13, 70–87.CrossRef
go back to reference Battista, J., Peress, M., & Richman, J. (2015). Policy representation in the state legislatures. Working Paper. Battista, J., Peress, M., & Richman, J. (2015). Policy representation in the state legislatures. Working Paper.
go back to reference Bernhardt, D., & Ingberman, D. (1985). Candidate reputations and the incumbency effect. Journal of Public Economics, 27, 47–67.CrossRef Bernhardt, D., & Ingberman, D. (1985). Candidate reputations and the incumbency effect. Journal of Public Economics, 27, 47–67.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, A. (1960). Surge and decline: A study of electoral change. Public Opinion Quarterly, 24, 397–418.CrossRef Campbell, A. (1960). Surge and decline: A study of electoral change. Public Opinion Quarterly, 24, 397–418.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, J. E. (1987). The revised theory of surge and decline. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 965–979.CrossRef Campbell, J. E. (1987). The revised theory of surge and decline. American Journal of Political Science, 31, 965–979.CrossRef
go back to reference Carroll, R., & Kim, H. A. (2010). Party government and the cohesive power of public plunder. American Journal of Political Science, 54, 34–44.CrossRef Carroll, R., & Kim, H. A. (2010). Party government and the cohesive power of public plunder. American Journal of Political Science, 54, 34–44.CrossRef
go back to reference Carson, J. L., Crespin, M. H., Jenkins, J. A., & Vander Wielen, R. J. (2004). Shirking in the contemporary congress: A reappraisal. Political Analysis, 12, 176–179.CrossRef Carson, J. L., Crespin, M. H., Jenkins, J. A., & Vander Wielen, R. J. (2004). Shirking in the contemporary congress: A reappraisal. Political Analysis, 12, 176–179.CrossRef
go back to reference Clark, J. H., & Williams, R. L. (2014). Parties, term limits, and representation in the U.S. states. American Politics Research, 42, 171–193.CrossRef Clark, J. H., & Williams, R. L. (2014). Parties, term limits, and representation in the U.S. states. American Politics Research, 42, 171–193.CrossRef
go back to reference Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1993). Legislative leviathan: Party government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press. Cox, G. W., & McCubbins, M. D. (1993). Legislative leviathan: Party government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press.
go back to reference Erikson, R. S., Wright, G. C., & McIver, J. P. (1994). Statehouse democracy: Public opinion and the American states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Erikson, R. S., Wright, G. C., & McIver, J. P. (1994). Statehouse democracy: Public opinion and the American states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Fiorina, M. P. (1974). Representatives, roll-calls, and constituencies. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books. Fiorina, M. P. (1974). Representatives, roll-calls, and constituencies. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
go back to reference Fowler, J. (2005). Dynamic responsiveness in the U.S. Senate. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 299–312.CrossRef Fowler, J. (2005). Dynamic responsiveness in the U.S. Senate. American Journal of Political Science, 49, 299–312.CrossRef
go back to reference Gill, P. E., Murray, W., & Wright, M. H. (1981). Practical optimization. Cambridge: Academic Press. Gill, P. E., Murray, W., & Wright, M. H. (1981). Practical optimization. Cambridge: Academic Press.
go back to reference Griffin, J. D. (2006). Electoral competition and democratic responsiveness: A defense of the marginality hypothesis. Journal of Politics, 68, 911–921.CrossRef Griffin, J. D. (2006). Electoral competition and democratic responsiveness: A defense of the marginality hypothesis. Journal of Politics, 68, 911–921.CrossRef
go back to reference Groseclose, T. (2001). A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 862–886.CrossRef Groseclose, T. (2001). A model of candidate location when one candidate has a valence advantage. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 862–886.CrossRef
go back to reference Gulati, G. J. (2004). Revisiting the link between electoral competition and policy extremism in the U.S. Congress. American Politics Research, 32, 495–520.CrossRef Gulati, G. J. (2004). Revisiting the link between electoral competition and policy extremism in the U.S. Congress. American Politics Research, 32, 495–520.CrossRef
go back to reference Herron, M. (2004). Studying dynamics in legislator ideal points: Scale matters. Political Analysis, 12, 182–190.CrossRef Herron, M. (2004). Studying dynamics in legislator ideal points: Scale matters. Political Analysis, 12, 182–190.CrossRef
go back to reference Jackman, S. (2001). Multidimensional analysis of roll call data via bayesian simulation: Identification, estimation, inference, and model checking. Political Analysis, 9, 227–241.CrossRef Jackman, S. (2001). Multidimensional analysis of roll call data via bayesian simulation: Identification, estimation, inference, and model checking. Political Analysis, 9, 227–241.CrossRef
go back to reference Jenkins, J. A., & Monroe, N. W. (2012). Buying negative agenda control in the U.S. House. American Journal of Political Science, 56, 897–912.CrossRef Jenkins, J. A., & Monroe, N. W. (2012). Buying negative agenda control in the U.S. House. American Journal of Political Science, 56, 897–912.CrossRef
go back to reference Lindstadt, R., & Vander Wielen, R. J. (2011). Timely shirking: Time-dependent monitoring and its effects on legislative behavior in the U.S. Senate. Public Choice, 148, 119–148.CrossRef Lindstadt, R., & Vander Wielen, R. J. (2011). Timely shirking: Time-dependent monitoring and its effects on legislative behavior in the U.S. Senate. Public Choice, 148, 119–148.CrossRef
go back to reference Lott, J. R., Jr., & Davis, M. L. (1992). A critical review and an extension of the political shirking literature. Public Choice, 74, 461–484. Lott, J. R., Jr., & Davis, M. L. (1992). A critical review and an extension of the political shirking literature. Public Choice, 74, 461–484.
go back to reference Martin, A. D., & Quinn, K. M. (2002). Dynamic ideal point estimation via markov chain monte carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953–1999. Political Analysis, 10, 134–153.CrossRef Martin, A. D., & Quinn, K. M. (2002). Dynamic ideal point estimation via markov chain monte carlo for the U.S. Supreme Court, 1953–1999. Political Analysis, 10, 134–153.CrossRef
go back to reference Mayhew, D. (1974). Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven: Yale University Press. Mayhew, D. (1974). Congress: The electoral connection. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Nokken, T. P., & Poole, K. T. (2004). Congressional Party Defection in American History. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 29, 545–568.CrossRef Nokken, T. P., & Poole, K. T. (2004). Congressional Party Defection in American History. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 29, 545–568.CrossRef
go back to reference Peress, M. (2010). The spatial model with non-policy factors: A theory of policy-motivated candidates. Social Choice and Welfare, 34, 265–294.CrossRef Peress, M. (2010). The spatial model with non-policy factors: A theory of policy-motivated candidates. Social Choice and Welfare, 34, 265–294.CrossRef
go back to reference Peress, M., & Spirling, A. (2010). Scaling the critics: Uncovering the latent dimensions of movie criticism. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105, 71–83.CrossRef Peress, M., & Spirling, A. (2010). Scaling the critics: Uncovering the latent dimensions of movie criticism. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 105, 71–83.CrossRef
go back to reference Poole, K. T. (1998). Estimating a basic space from a set of issue scales. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 954–993.CrossRef Poole, K. T. (1998). Estimating a basic space from a set of issue scales. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 954–993.CrossRef
go back to reference Poole, K. T. (2005). Spatial models of parliamentary voting. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Poole, K. T. (2005). Spatial models of parliamentary voting. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Poole, K. T. (2007). Changing minds? Not in Congress! Public Choice, 131, 435–451.CrossRef Poole, K. T. (2007). Changing minds? Not in Congress! Public Choice, 131, 435–451.CrossRef
go back to reference Poole, K. T., & Romer, T. (1993). Ideology, “shirking”, and representation. Public Choice, 77, 185–196.CrossRef Poole, K. T., & Romer, T. (1993). Ideology, “shirking”, and representation. Public Choice, 77, 185–196.CrossRef
go back to reference Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1991). Patterns of congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science, 35, 228–278.CrossRef Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1991). Patterns of congressional voting. American Journal of Political Science, 35, 228–278.CrossRef
go back to reference Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press. Poole, K. T., & Rosenthal, H. (1997). Congress: A political economic history of roll call voting. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Rothenberg, L. S., & Sanders, M. S. (2000). Severing the electoral connection: Shirking in the contemporary congress. American Journal of Political Science, 44, 316–325.CrossRef Rothenberg, L. S., & Sanders, M. S. (2000). Severing the electoral connection: Shirking in the contemporary congress. American Journal of Political Science, 44, 316–325.CrossRef
go back to reference Serra, G. (2010). Polarization of what? A model of elections with endogenous valence. Journal of Politics, 72, 426–437.CrossRef Serra, G. (2010). Polarization of what? A model of elections with endogenous valence. Journal of Politics, 72, 426–437.CrossRef
go back to reference Shor, B., & McCarty, N. (2011). The ideological mapping of american legislatures. American Political Science Review, 105, 530–551.CrossRef Shor, B., & McCarty, N. (2011). The ideological mapping of american legislatures. American Political Science Review, 105, 530–551.CrossRef
go back to reference Tausanovitch, C., & Warshaw, C. (2013). Measuring constituent policy preferences in Congress, state legislatures and cities. Journal of Politics, 75, 330–342.CrossRef Tausanovitch, C., & Warshaw, C. (2013). Measuring constituent policy preferences in Congress, state legislatures and cities. Journal of Politics, 75, 330–342.CrossRef
go back to reference Treier, S. (2009). Electoral pressure and policy change: Conversion or replacement? Working Paper. Treier, S. (2009). Electoral pressure and policy change: Conversion or replacement? Working Paper.
go back to reference Wright, G. C. (2007). Do term limits affect legislative roll call voting? Representation, polarization, and participation. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 7, 256–280.CrossRef Wright, G. C. (2007). Do term limits affect legislative roll call voting? Representation, polarization, and participation. State Politics and Policy Quarterly, 7, 256–280.CrossRef
go back to reference Wrone, B. C., Brady, D. W., & Cogan, J. F. (2002). Out of step, out of office: Electoral accountability and house members’ voting. American Political Science Review, 96, 127–140.CrossRef Wrone, B. C., Brady, D. W., & Cogan, J. F. (2002). Out of step, out of office: Electoral accountability and house members’ voting. American Political Science Review, 96, 127–140.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Dynamic estimation of ideal points for the US Congress
Authors
Brandon Marshall
Michael Peress
Publication date
20-06-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0572-y

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2018

Public Choice 1-2/2018 Go to the issue