Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Empirical Economics 2/2014

01-09-2014

Estimating noncooperative and cooperative models of bargaining: an empirical comparison

Authors: Masanori Mitsutsune, Takanori Adachi

Published in: Empirical Economics | Issue 2/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper examines the issue of model selection in studies of strategic situations. In particular, we compare estimation results from a noncooperative formulation of government formulation à la (Baron and Ferejohn in Am Poli Sci Rev 87:34–47, 1989) with those from two alternative cooperative formulations (Nash in Econometrica 18:155–162, 1950; Shapley and Shubik in Am Poli Sci Rev 48:787–792, 1954). Although the estimates of the ministerial ranking are similar, statistical testing suggests that the noncooperative formulation is best fitted to the observed data among the alternative models. This result implies that modeling the noncooperative structure in bargaining situations is crucially important at the risk of possibly misspecifying the details of the game.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The Nash solution concept is axiomatically constructed, and thus is free of negotiation procedure. See, e.g., Okada (2010) for a noncooperative foundation for the Nash solution and Okada (2007) for its application.
 
2
When a symmetric two-person Nash solution is analyzed, the maxmin values or the Nash equilibrium is customarily set as a breakdown point. However, such good ways do not exist to model the breakdown situation in the analysis of asymmetric \(n\)-person Nash solution.
 
3
See Hu (2006) for an extension of the Shapley–Shubik power index.
 
4
Note that a voter here is a party. Considering the reality, it would be more natural that a member of parliament, not a party, has a vote. We assume a hypothetical situation where each party as a whole decides on its vote, binding its members’ decisions.
 
5
How the distribution of party size affects the determination of \( v_{i}^{SS}(W)\) is understood in the following example. Suppose that there are four parties with \(W=(40,25,20,15)\). In the grand coalition formation starting party \(1\), followed by parties \(2\), \(3\), and \(4\) (this is one permutation), party \(2\) is pivotal and the winning coalition consists of parties \(1\) and \(2\), if the simple majority rule is employed. Party \(i\)’s Shapley–Shubik power index is the average of it being pivotal of all permutations.
 
6
It is obvious that \(v_{i}^{SS}(W)\) also depends on the majority quota rule (for example, the rule can require that more than two thirds, rather than half, of all votes be necessary for a winning coalition). We assume the simple majority within the ruling party of the data period (a faction of the party is a player of the bargaining game; see 3.4 below). We later consider the robustness of our empirical results by checking the case of the simple majoriy within all parliamentary members of the lower house, which is given a decisive power by law (see 4.4.1 below).
 
7
Hart and Mas-Colell (1996), Laruelle and Valenciano (2008), Miyakawa (2008), Britz et al. (2010) and Predtetchinski (2011), among others, study the asymptotic coincidence of a noncorporative equilibrium to a cooperative solution. In particular, stationary subgame perfect equilibria in a \(n\)-player game where a proposer drops from the game with a small probability if the agreement is not reached converge to asymmetric Nash solution with each player’s recognition probability being his or her power index.
 
8
See, e.g., Okada (2011) and Kawamori (2013) for recent extensions of Baron and Ferejohn (1989) model. Ray (2007) is an excellent survey of the noncooperative theory for coalition formation.
 
9
Eraslan (2002, p. 15) shows that proposer \(i\)’s stationary equilibrium payoff, \(v_{i}^{*}\), is obtained by
$$\begin{aligned} \left\{ \begin{array}{l} \underset{(z_{j})_{j\ne i}}{\!\!\!\!\!\max }1-\sum _{j\ne i}z_{j}v_{j}^{*} \\ \text {subject to }\sum _{j\ne i}=q-1 \\ z_{j}\in \{0,1\}\text {,} \end{array}\right. \end{aligned}$$
where \(q=n/2\) (when \(n\) is even) or \(q=(n+1)/2\) (\(n\) is odd), and \( v_{j}^{*}\) is nonproposer \(j\)’s stationary equilibrium payoff (\( v_{j}^{*}=\delta p_{j}\) if \(j\) is such that \(z_{j}=1\), and \(v_{j}^{*}=0\) if \(j\) is such that \(z_{j}=0\)). Clearly, there are some players who gain nothing if the unanimous agreement is not implemented.
 
10
Admittedly, the specification of bargaining power is a “reduced form” because we do not model how it is determined in bargaining models. However, our main results seem robust to alternative specifications. We are grateful to one of the referees for making us realize this issue.
 
11
See also McDonald (1984, p. 653, eq.(14)). We believe that there is a typo in equation (14); \(p+q\) in the denominator should be \(p+q-1\).
 
12
Note that we use the information on ex-post payoffs (i.e., after a proposer is selected). If we use functional forms of ex-ante payoffs, the scale effect parameter \(\alpha \) would be identified from the probability of becoming a proposer given the party size distribution. However, the identification of \(\delta \) would not be guaranteed.
 
13
During the period of the study, although the Prime Minister and the Cabinet Secretary were often occupied by the same party, there were still four exceptions (out of 44 government formations).
 
14
The page’s URL is: http://​hpcgi2.​nifty.​com/​TOMOMI/​index-e.​cgi (last accessed: November 2013).
 
15
Because the LDP attained a majority in the Lower House during the period of this study, this assumption is natural. See Appendix A of Adachi and Watanabe (2008) for details.
 
16
On the other hand, Ono (2012) uses detailed data on LDP leaders’ factions to empirically argue that they took tougher stance on ministerial allocation when their political positions were more stable.
 
17
As in Adachi and Watanabe (2008), the standard errors are calculated using the bootstrap method. The number of iteration is 500.
 
18
Notice that the values of log likelihood in Table 2 are positive. In Adachi and Watanabe (2008), it is incorrectly reported as a negative value. The reported estimates in Adachi and Watanabe (2008) are modified by Adachi and Watanabe (2010): the latter reestimates the model with the corrected data.
 
19
See, e.g., Greene (2008, pp. 498–500) and Wooldridge (2010, p. 481).
 
20
The chi-square values at different significance levels are given by \(2.7055\) (\(10\%), 3.8415 (5\,\%\)), and \(6.6349\) (\(1\%\)).
 
21
See, e.g., Greene (2008, pp. 140–142) and Wooldridge (2010, pp. 505–509).
 
22
In calculating these numbers with the help of Tomoki Matsui’s website (see Footnote 14), we assume the total number of LDP politicians is \(280\): the mean number of LDP politicians in the Lower House in each term is \(280.78\) (with the total number being \(18\)): the Prime Minister’s faction has \(84\) politicians, while each of the other factions have \(28\) politicians.
 
23
We owe this idea to Yusaku Horiuchi.
 
24
The likelihood statistics are calculated as \(21.8236\) (Adachi and Watanabe), \(21.8305\) (Nash), and \(19.3363\) (Shapley and Shubik), respectively. These values are all greater than \(11.34\) (at the \(1\%\) significance level with the degree of freedom being three).
 
25
Japan adopts a parliamentary regime with a bicameral legislature. If the House of Councilors (the upper house) and the House of Representatives (the lower house) disagree on the designation for 10 days, the latter’s decision is enforced.
 
26
For example, Ramseyer and Rosenbluth (1993:211) cite an interview with one faction leader of the LDP faction who answered that factions were not distinguishable based on policy areas.
 
27
See, e.g., Merlo and Wilson (1995, 1998), Merlo (1997), and Hanazono and Watanabe (2012) for bargaining models with equilibrium delays.
 
Literature
go back to reference Adachi T, Watanabe Y (2008) Ministerial weights and government formation: estimation using a bargaining model. J Law Econ Org 24:95–119 Adachi T, Watanabe Y (2008) Ministerial weights and government formation: estimation using a bargaining model. J Law Econ Org 24:95–119
go back to reference Baron DP, Ferejohn J (1989) Bargaining in legislatures. Am Poli Sci Rev 87:34–47CrossRef Baron DP, Ferejohn J (1989) Bargaining in legislatures. Am Poli Sci Rev 87:34–47CrossRef
go back to reference Bombardini M, Trebbi, F (2011) Votes or money? Theory and evidence from the US Congress. J Pub Econ 95:587–611 Bombardini M, Trebbi, F (2011) Votes or money? Theory and evidence from the US Congress. J Pub Econ 95:587–611
go back to reference Britz VP, Herings J-J, Predtetchinski A (2010) Non-cooperative support for the asymmetric nash bargaining solution. J Econ Theory 145:1951–1967CrossRef Britz VP, Herings J-J, Predtetchinski A (2010) Non-cooperative support for the asymmetric nash bargaining solution. J Econ Theory 145:1951–1967CrossRef
go back to reference Eraslan H (2002) Uniqueness of stationary equilibrium payoffs in the Baron–Ferejohn model. J Econ Theory 103:11–30CrossRef Eraslan H (2002) Uniqueness of stationary equilibrium payoffs in the Baron–Ferejohn model. J Econ Theory 103:11–30CrossRef
go back to reference Eraslan H, McLennan A (2013) Uniqueness of stationary equilibrium payoffs in coalitional bargaining. J Econ Theory 148:2196–2222 Eraslan H, McLennan A (2013) Uniqueness of stationary equilibrium payoffs in coalitional bargaining. J Econ Theory 148:2196–2222
go back to reference Francois P, Rainer I, Trebbi F (2012) How is power shared in Africa? NBER Working Paper No. 18425 Francois P, Rainer I, Trebbi F (2012) How is power shared in Africa? NBER Working Paper No. 18425
go back to reference Gamson WA (1961) A theory of coalition formation. Am Sociol Rev 26:373–382CrossRef Gamson WA (1961) A theory of coalition formation. Am Sociol Rev 26:373–382CrossRef
go back to reference Greene WH (2008) Econometric analysis, 6th edn. Pearson, Upper Saddle River Greene WH (2008) Econometric analysis, 6th edn. Pearson, Upper Saddle River
go back to reference Hanazono M, Watanabe Y (2012) Information aggregation in bargaining. (Unpublished manuscript) Hanazono M, Watanabe Y (2012) Information aggregation in bargaining. (Unpublished manuscript)
go back to reference Hart S, Mas-Colell A (1996) Bargaining and value. Econometrica 64:357–380CrossRef Hart S, Mas-Colell A (1996) Bargaining and value. Econometrica 64:357–380CrossRef
go back to reference Hu X (2006) An asymmetric Shapley–Shubik power index. Int J Game Theory 34:229–240CrossRef Hu X (2006) An asymmetric Shapley–Shubik power index. Int J Game Theory 34:229–240CrossRef
go back to reference Kawamori T (2013) Rejecter-proposer legislative bargaining with heterogeneous time and risk preferences. Soc Choice Welf 40:27–40 Kawamori T (2013) Rejecter-proposer legislative bargaining with heterogeneous time and risk preferences. Soc Choice Welf 40:27–40
go back to reference Laruelle A, Valenciano F (2008) Noncooperative foundations of bargaining power in committees and the Shapley–Shubik index. Games Econ Behav 63:341–353CrossRef Laruelle A, Valenciano F (2008) Noncooperative foundations of bargaining power in committees and the Shapley–Shubik index. Games Econ Behav 63:341–353CrossRef
go back to reference Matsui T, Matsui Y (1998) Calculating power indices of weighted majority games. Proc Tenth RAMP Symposium, Kyoudai Kaikan 24:17–30 Matsui T, Matsui Y (1998) Calculating power indices of weighted majority games. Proc Tenth RAMP Symposium, Kyoudai Kaikan 24:17–30
go back to reference McDonald JB (1984) Some generalized functions for the size sistributions of income. Econometrica 52:647–63CrossRef McDonald JB (1984) Some generalized functions for the size sistributions of income. Econometrica 52:647–63CrossRef
go back to reference Merlo A (1997) Bargaining over governments in a stochastic environment. J Poli Econ 105:101–131CrossRef Merlo A (1997) Bargaining over governments in a stochastic environment. J Poli Econ 105:101–131CrossRef
go back to reference Merlo A, Wilson C (1995) Stochastic model of sequential bargaining with complete information. Econometrica 63:371–399CrossRef Merlo A, Wilson C (1995) Stochastic model of sequential bargaining with complete information. Econometrica 63:371–399CrossRef
go back to reference Merlo A, Wilson C (1998) Efficient delays in a stochastic model of bargaining. Econ Theory 11:39–55CrossRef Merlo A, Wilson C (1998) Efficient delays in a stochastic model of bargaining. Econ Theory 11:39–55CrossRef
go back to reference Miyakawa T (2008) Note on the equal split solution in an n-person noncooperative bargaining game. Math Soc Sci 55:281–291 Miyakawa T (2008) Note on the equal split solution in an n-person noncooperative bargaining game. Math Soc Sci 55:281–291
go back to reference Okada A (2007) International negotiations on climate change: a noncooperative game analysis of the Kyoto protocol. In: Avenhaus R, Zartman IW (eds) Diplomacy games: formal models and international negotiations. Springer, Heidelberg Okada A (2007) International negotiations on climate change: a noncooperative game analysis of the Kyoto protocol. In: Avenhaus R, Zartman IW (eds) Diplomacy games: formal models and international negotiations. Springer, Heidelberg
go back to reference Okada A (2010) The Nash bargaining solution in general \(n\)-person cooperative games. J Econ Theory 145:2356–2379CrossRef Okada A (2010) The Nash bargaining solution in general \(n\)-person cooperative games. J Econ Theory 145:2356–2379CrossRef
go back to reference Okada A (2011) Coalitional bargaining games with random proposers: theory and application. Games Econ Behav 73:227–235CrossRef Okada A (2011) Coalitional bargaining games with random proposers: theory and application. Games Econ Behav 73:227–235CrossRef
go back to reference Ono Y (2012) Portfolio allocation as leadership strategy: intraparty bargaining in Japan. Am J Poli Sci 56:553–567CrossRef Ono Y (2012) Portfolio allocation as leadership strategy: intraparty bargaining in Japan. Am J Poli Sci 56:553–567CrossRef
go back to reference Osborne MJ, Rubinstein A (1994) A course in game theory. The MIT Press, Cambridge Osborne MJ, Rubinstein A (1994) A course in game theory. The MIT Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Raabe J, Linhart E (2012) Does substance matter? A model of qualitative portfolio allocation and application to German state governments between 1990 and 2010. Party Poli. doi:10.1177/1354068813487107 Raabe J, Linhart E (2012) Does substance matter? A model of qualitative portfolio allocation and application to German state governments between 1990 and 2010. Party Poli. doi:10.​1177/​1354068813487107​
go back to reference Predtetchinski A (2011) One-dimensional bargaining. Games Econ Behav 72:526–543CrossRef Predtetchinski A (2011) One-dimensional bargaining. Games Econ Behav 72:526–543CrossRef
go back to reference Ramseyer JM, Rosenbluth FM (1993) Japan’s political marketplace. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Ramseyer JM, Rosenbluth FM (1993) Japan’s political marketplace. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Ray D (2007) A game-theoretic perspective on coalition formation. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef Ray D (2007) A game-theoretic perspective on coalition formation. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
go back to reference Rubinstein A (1982) Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica 50:97–109CrossRef Rubinstein A (1982) Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica 50:97–109CrossRef
go back to reference Shapley LS (1953) A value for \(n\)-person games. In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games, vol II. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ Shapley LS (1953) A value for \(n\)-person games. In: Kuhn HW, Tucker AW (eds) Contributions to the theory of games, vol II. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ
go back to reference Shapley LS, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Poli Sci Rev 48:787–792CrossRef Shapley LS, Shubik M (1954) A method for evaluating the distribution of power in a committee system. Am Poli Sci Rev 48:787–792CrossRef
go back to reference Vuong QH (1989) Likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypothesis. Econometrica 57:307–333CrossRef Vuong QH (1989) Likelihood ratio tests for model selection and non-nested hypothesis. Econometrica 57:307–333CrossRef
go back to reference Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd edn. The MIT Press, Cambridge Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data, 2nd edn. The MIT Press, Cambridge
Metadata
Title
Estimating noncooperative and cooperative models of bargaining: an empirical comparison
Authors
Masanori Mitsutsune
Takanori Adachi
Publication date
01-09-2014
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Empirical Economics / Issue 2/2014
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Electronic ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0755-9

Other articles of this Issue 2/2014

Empirical Economics 2/2014 Go to the issue