Skip to main content
Top

2020 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

4. Estimation of Residential Property Price Index: Methodology and Data Sources

Authors : W. Erwin Diewert, Kiyohiko G. Nishimura, Chihiro Shimizu, Tsutomu Watanabe

Published in: Property Price Index

Publisher: Springer Japan

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Fluctuations in real estate prices have substantial impacts on economic activities. In Japan, a sharp rise in real estate prices during the latter half of the 1980s and its decline in the early 1990s led to a decade-long stagnation of the Japanese economy. More recently, a rapid rise in housing prices and its reversal in the United States triggered a global financial crisis. In such circumstances, the development of appropriate indexes that allow one to capture changes in real estate prices with precision is extremely important, not only for policy makers but also for market participants who are looking for the time when housing prices hit bottom. Recent research has focussed on methods of compiling appropriate residential property price indexes. The location, maintenance and the facilities of each house are different from each other in varying degrees, so there are no two houses that are identical in terms of quality. Even if the location and basic structure are the same at two periods of time, the building ages over time and the houses are not identical across time. In other words, it is very difficult to apply the usual matching methodology (where the prices of exactly the same item are compared over time) to housing.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
This chapter–Chap. 7 deal with the following methods: stratification or mix adjustment methods, hedonic regression methods, repeat sales methods, and appraisal based methods.
 
2
This decomposition is required in order to construct the national accounts for a country.
 
3
The Advisory Board was set up by the Ministry of Land, Infrastructure, Transport and Tourism, with the participation of the Bank of Japan, Financial Services Agency, Ministry of Justice (which is the department responsible for the land registry), Statistics Japan (the department responsible for the consumer price index), the Cabinet Office (the department responsible for SNA), the Japan Association of Real Estate Appraisers and various realtor associations. As of 2013, the Advisory Board also began developing a official Commercial Property Price Index in addition to developing the Residential Property Price Index.
 
4
Sections 4.2 and 4.3 draw heavily on the paper by Shimizu et al. (2010a).
 
5
See Clapp and Giaccotto (1992). Repeat sales that occur in very short time periods are often not regarded as “ typical” sales. In particular, the initial sale may take place at a below market price and the subsequent rapid resale takes place at the market price, and this phenomenon may lead to an upward bias in the resulting repeat sales price index. Of course, this source of upward bias is partially offset by the downward bias in the repeat sales method due to its neglect to make a quality adjustment for the depreciation of the structure.
 
6
See Case and Shiller (1987, 1989), Clapp and Giaccotto (1992, 1998), Goodman and Thibodeau (1998), Case et al. (1991) and Diewert (2010).
 
7
See Case and Quigley (1991) and Ekeland et al. (2004).
 
8
See Diewert (2003a, b).
 
9
See Case et al. (1991), Clapp and Giaccotto (1992, 1998), Shimizu and Nishimura (2006, 2007) and Shimizu et al. (2010a).
 
10
See Bourassa et al. (2006). The hedonic method requires information on property characteristics whereas the repeat sales method does not require any characteristics information. However, this informational advantage of the repeat sales method is offset by its informational sparseness disadvantage; i.e., repeat sales information may be so infrequent so as to make the construction of accurate price indexes impossible. Moreover, unless the sample selection bias exactly offsets the depreciation bias, we can say that the repeat sales method is definitely biased whereas we cannot definitely assert that the hedonic method is biased.
 
11
This may be partly due to the presence of legal restrictions in Japan on reselling a house within a short period of time.
 
12
McMillen (2003) adopted the same Cobb-Douglas production function for housing services. Thorsnes (1997) described housing output as a constant elasticity substitution production function of the lot size and housing capital, and provided some empirical evidence that the elasticity of substitution is close to unity, which implies that the Cobb-Douglas production function is a good approximation of the technology used in the production of housing services. In contrast, Diewert (2010, 2011) suggested some possible hedonic regression models that might lead to additive decompositions of an overall property price into land and structures components. Additive decomposition models have been estimated by Diewert et al. (2011a, b) and Eurostat (2011) using Dutch data and by Diewert and Shimizu (2013) using data for Tokyo. We will discuss these additive models in Sect. 4.5 below.
 
13
Note that we are assuming that the vector of house i attributes \(\varvec{x}_{i}\) does not depend on the time of sale, t.
 
14
Time dummy hedonic regression models date back to Court (1939).
 
15
The repeat sales method is due to Bailey et al. (1963).
 
16
Thus the regression model defined by (4.5) does not require characteristics information on the house( except that information on the age of the house at the time of each transaction is required).
 
17
However, if s and t are very close, the variance could also increase due to the “flipping phenomenon”; i.e., a house that is sold twice in a short time period may have a rate of price change between the two time periods that is unusually large on an annualized basis, causing the error variance to increase.
 
18
As usual, set \(d_{1}^{*}\equiv d_{1}\equiv 1\) so that \(P_{1}\equiv 1\).
 
19
Note that the depreciation model defined by (4.2) can be regarded as a net depreciation model; i.e., it is depreciation less “normal” renovation and maintenance expenditures. See Diewert (2011) for more on the topic of constructing a house price index taking depreciation and renovation into consideration.
 
20
The analysis which follows is due to Shimizu et al. (2010a).
 
21
It should be noted that the official S&P/Case-Shiller home price index is adjusted in the following way to take the age effect into account. Standard and Poor’s (2008: 7) states that “sales pairs are also weighted based on the time interval between the first and second sales. If a sales pair interval is longer, then it is more likely that a house may have experienced physical changes. Sales pairs with longer intervals are, therefore, given less weight than sales pairs with shorter intervals.”
 
22
However, one would expect approximate multicollinearity to hold in McMillen’s model so that the estimated dummy variable parameters may not be too reliable.
 
23
See Chau et al. (2005) for another example where a nonlinear specification of the age effect was introduced into the hedonic regression in order to eliminate multicollinearity between the age variable and the time dummy variables.
 
24
If the estimated \(\lambda \) parameter for the model defined by (4.8) turns out to be close to one, then as is the case for McMillen’s model, there may be an approximate multicollinearity problem with the Shimizu, Nishimura and Watanabe repeat sales model.
 
25
The two period time dummy variable hedonic regression was considered explicitly by Court (1939: 109–111) as his hedonic suggestion number two. Griliches (1971: 7) coined the term “adjacent year regression” to describe the two period dummy variable hedonic regression model.
 
26
They called their method the Overlapping Period Hedonic Housing Model (OPHM).
 
27
This is the approach used by Shimizu et al. (2010a) to form an overall price index. Ivancic et al. (2009) recommended a variant of the rolling window model where their basic hedonic regression model was the Time Product Dummy model which is the application of Summer’s (1973) Country Product Dummy model to the time series context (from the original application to multilateral comparisons of prices across countries). IDF recommended a (weighted) Rolling Year Time Product Dummy method where the window length was chosen to be 13 months. For extensions of the IDF model to more general hedonic regression models, see de Haan and Krsinich (2014). Diewert and Shimizu (2013) implemented a Rolling Window hedonic regression model for Tokyo houses which will be described later in Sect. 4.5. The Rolling Window Hedonic Regression approach to the construction of house price indexes has also been applied by Eurostat (2011; Chap. 8) and by Diewert et al. (2011b).
 
28
Shimizu et al. (2004) reported that the Recruit data cover more than 95% of all transactions in the 23 special wards of Tokyo but the coverage for suburban areas is very limited. Therefore the study by Shimizu, Nishimura and Watanabe used only information for the units located in the special wards of Tokyo.
 
29
There are two reasons for removal of the listing of a unit from the magazine: a successful deal or a withdrawal; i.e., in the second case, the seller gives up looking for a buyer and thus withdraws the listing. SNW were allowed to access information regarding which of the two reasons applied for individual cases and they discarded prices where the seller withdrew the listing.
 
30
Recruit Co. Ltd. provided SNW with information on contract prices for about 24% of the population of listings. Using this information, SNW were able to confirm that prices in the final week were almost always identical to the contract prices; i.e., they differed at less than a 0.1% probability.
 
31
More specifically, the imputed land area attributed to a condo unit was calculated by dividing the sum of the floor space for each unit in the structure by \(FAR\times BLR\), where FAR and BLR stand for the floor area ratio and the building to land ratio, respectively. The sum of the floor space of each unit in a structure was available in the original dataset. The maximum values for FAR and BLR are subject to regulation under city planning law. It was assumed that this regulation was binding.
 
32
Japanese people are particularly fond of sunshine!
 
33
Travel time to the CBD was measured as follows. The metropolitan area of Tokyo is composed of wards and contains a dense railway network. Within this area, SNW chose seven railway or subway stations as central business district stations: Tokyo, Shinagawa, Shibuya, Shinjuku, Ikebukuro, Ueno, and Otemachi. SNW then defined travel time to the CBD as the minutes needed to commute to the nearest of the seven stations in the daytime.
 
34
The time to the nearest station, TS, was defined as the walking time to the nearest station if a house was located within walking distance from a station, and the sum of the walking time to a bus stop and the bus travel time from the bus stop to the nearest station if a house is located in a bus transportation area. SNW used a bus dummy, BD, to indicate whether a house was located in walking distance from a railway station or in a bus transportation area.
 
35
Note that the estimated coefficient for \(\lambda \) in the age adjusted repeat sales model was 0.89 for condos and 1.10 for single family houses. Thus the exact multicollinearity problem does not arise for these regressions.
 
36
Their Rolling Window results used a window length of 12 months and used the updating procedure explained at the end of Sect. 4.2 above.
 
37
Note that the age adjusted repeat sales index is well above the other two repeat sales indexes which do not make an adjustment for depreciation of the structure. This result is to be expected. What is perhaps more surprising is that the age adjusted repeat sales index ends up well below the two hedonic indexes. This result may be due to sample selectivity bias in the repeat sales method or to an incorrect specification of the hedonic models.
 
38
The annual depreciation rate for houses appears to be much smaller than the corresponding rate for condos and thus the age bias in the repeat sales models will be much smaller for houses than for condos. The relatively large differences in the two hedonic indexes is a bit of a puzzle. Diewert and Shimizu (2013) also compared Rolling Window house price indexes with a corresponding index based on a single time dummy regression and did not find large differences (but the sample period was much shorter in the Diewert and Shimizu study).
 
39
It can be seen from the upper right panel of Fig. 4.4 that several dots in the right upper quadrant are well above the 45 degree line, indicating that the growth rates of the standard hedonic index are substantially higher than those of the standard repeat sales index at least for these quarters. These dots correspond to the quarters between 1986 and 1987, during which the standard hedonic index exhibited much more rapid growth than the standard repeat sales index, as was seen in Fig. 4.2.
 
40
The material in this section is drawn from Shimizu et al. (2011, 2012). In this section, we will refer to these two papers as SNW.
 
41
See for example Case et al. (1991), Diewert (2010), Dorsey et al. (2010), Eurostat (2011) and Sect. 4.2 above. Recently, McMillen and Thorsnes (2006), McMillen (2012) and Deng et al. (2012) proposed a new index estimation method, the matching model method, which focused on the distribution of housing prices.
 
42
Eurostat (2011) provides a summary of the sources of price information in various countries. For example, in Bulgaria, Canada, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Ireland, Spain, France, Latvia, Luxembourg, Poland and the USA price data collected by statistical institutes or ministries is used. In Denmark, Lithuania, the Netherlands, Norway, Finland, Hong Kong, Slovenia, Sweden and the UK information gathered for registration or taxation purposes is used. In Belgium, Germany, Greece, France, Italy, Portugal and Slovakia data from real estate agents and associations, research institutes or property consultancies is used. Finally, in Malta, Hungary, Austria and Romania data from newspapers or websites is used.
 
43
There are several papers that focused on data sources for housing price indexes; see Gatzlaff and Haurin (1998), Genesove and Mayer (2001), Goetzmann and Peng (2006). However, these papers did not compare multiple data sources.
 
44
See Allen and Dare (2004), Haurin et al. (2010), Knight et al. (1998).
 
45
See Genesove and Mayer (1997, 2001) and Engelhardt (2003).
 
46
An alternative approach would be to compare the four prices in terms of their average prices or in terms of their median prices. However, these summary statistics capture only one aspect of cross-sectional price distributions.
 
47
As was noted in the previous section, Shimizu et al. (2010a) constructed five different house price indexes, including hedonic and repeat sales indexes, using Japanese data for 1986 to 2008. They found that there were substantial differences in terms of turning points between hedonic and repeat sales indexes. In particular, the repeat sales measure signaled turning points later than the hedonic measure. For example, the hedonic measure of condominium prices bottomed out at the beginning of 2002, while the corresponding repeat sales measure exhibited a reversal only in the spring of 2004.
 
48
See Chapter 11 of Eurostat (2011) for detailed information on house price datasets currently available in Japan.
 
49
The number of housing units that appear both in the realtor data set and in the registry data set is 22,613; the number of housing units that are in the realtor data set but not in the registry data set is 99,934; and the number of housing units that are in the registry data set but not in the realtor data set is 36,336.
 
50
Eurostat (2011: 147) sums up the situation as follows: “Each source of prices information has its advantages and disadvantages. For example a disadvantage of advertised prices and prices on mortgage applications and approvals is that not all of the prices included end in transactions, and the price may differ from the final negotiated transaction price. But these prices are likely to be available sometime before the final transaction price. Indices that measure the price earlier in the purchase process are able to detect price changes first, but will measure final prices with error because prices can be renegotiated extensively before the deal is finalized.”
 
51
DS deleted 9.2% of the observations because they fell outside their range limits for the variables VLSANB and W. DS noted that it is risky to estimate hedonic regression models over wide ranges when observations are sparse at the beginning and end of the range of each variable. The a priori range limits for these variables were as follows: \(2\le V\le 20;0.5\le S\le 2.5;1\le A\le 50;2\le NB\le 8;2.5\le W\le 9\).
 
52
See Diewert et al. (2011a, b) for evidence on this multicollinearity problem using Dutch data.
 
53
The period index t runs from 1 to 44 where period 1 corresponds to Q1 of 2000 and period 44 corresponds to Q4 of 2010.
 
54
Other papers that have suggested hedonic regression models that lead to additive decompositions of property values into land and structure components include Clapp (1980), Francke and Vos (2004), Gyourko and Saiz (2004), Bostic et al. (2007), Davis and Heathcote (2007), Francke (2008), Koev et al. (2008), Statistics Portugal (2009), Diewert (2010, 2011), Rambaldi et al. (2010) and Diewert et al. (2011a, b).
 
55
This formulation follows that of Diewert (2010, 2011) and Diewert et al. (2011a, b). It is a special case of Clapp’s (1980; 258) hedonic regression model.
 
56
This estimate of depreciation is regarded as a net depreciation rate because it is equal to a “ true” gross structure depreciation rate less an average renovations appreciation rate. Since we do not have information on renovations and additions to a structure, our age variable will only pick up average gross depreciation less average real renovation expenditures. Note that we excluded sales of houses from our sample if the age of the structure exceeded 50 years when sold. Very old houses tend to have larger than normal renovation expenditures and thus their inclusion can bias the estimates of the net depreciation rate for younger structures.
 
57
See Schwann (1998), Diewert et al. (2011a, b) and Eurostat (2011) on the multicollinearity problem.
 
58
All of the \(R^{2}\) reported in this section are equal to the square of the correlation coefficient between the dependent variable in the regression and the corresponding predicted variable. The estimated net annual straight line depreciation rate was \(\delta =1.25\%\), with a T statistic of 17.3.
 
59
See Eurostat (2011).
 
60
The 21 Wards of Tokyo that had at least one transaction during the DS sample period (with the total number of transactions for that Ward in brackets) are as follows: 1: Minato (69); 2: Shinjuku (136); 3: Bunkyo (82); 4: Taito (15); 5: Sumida (32); 6: Koto (38); 7: Shinagawa (144); 8: Meguro (349); 9: Ota (409); 10: Setagaya (1158); 11: Shibuya (107); 12: Nakano (305); 13: Suginami (773); 14: Toshima (124); 15: Kita (53); 16: Arakawa (34); 17: Itabashi (214); 18: Nerima (925); 19: Adachi (271); 20: Katsushika (143); 21: Edogawa (197). Note that for each observation tn, \(\sum _{j=1}^{21}D_{W,tn,j}=1\); i.e., for each observation tn, the 21 ward dummy variables sum to one.
 
61
The annual net depreciation rate for this model was estimated as \(\delta =1.39\%\) with a T statistic of 26.8.
 
62
Diewert and Shimizu (2013) estimated several additional models that were generalizations of the model defined by (4.14). These models made use of the NBWITW and TT variables defined above in Sect. 4.5.2. Their final most general Model 5 had an \(R^{2}\) equal to 0.8476 and the corresponding log likelihood was \(-8709.9\).
 
63
An alternative way of viewing the land model is that land in each Ward can be regarded as a distinct commodity with its own price and quantity. But since all Ward land prices move proportionally over time, virtually all index number formulae will generate an overall land price series that is proportional to the \(\alpha _{t}\).
 
64
Our method for aggregating over different house “ models” that have varying amounts of constant quality land and structures can be viewed as a hedonic imputation method but it can also be viewed as an application of Hicks’ Aggregation Theorem; i.e., if the prices in a group of commodities vary in strict proportion over time, then the factor of proportionality can be taken as the price of the group and the deflated group expenditures will obey the usual properties of a microeconomic commodity. “Thus we have demonstrated mathematically the very important principle, used extensively in the text, that if the prices of a group of goods change in the same proportion, that group of goods behaves just as if it were a single commodity.” Hicks (1946; 312–313).
 
65
DS normalized the price indexes \(P_{Lt}\) and \(P_{St}\) to equal 1 in quarter 1, which is quarter 1 of the year 2000.
 
66
The Fisher chained index \(P_{t}\) is defined as follows. For \(t=1\), define \(P_{t}\equiv 1\). For \(t>1\), define \(P_{t}\) in terms of \(P_{t-1}\) and \(P_{F,t}\) as \(P_{t}\equiv P_{t-1}P_{F,t}\) where \(P_{F,t}\) is the quarter t Fisher chain link index. The chain link Fisher index for \(t\ge 2\) is defined as \(P_{F,t}\equiv [P_{La,t}P_{Pa,t}]^{1/2}\) where the Laspeyres and Paasche chain link indexes are defined as \(P_{La,t}\equiv [P_{L,t}Q_{L,t-1}+P_{S,t}Q_{S,t-1}]/[P_{L,t-1}Q_{L,t-1}+P_{S,t-1}Q_{S,t-1}]\) and \(P_{Pa,t}\equiv [P_{L,t}Q_{L,t}+P_{S,t}Q_{S,t}]/[P_{L,t-1}Q_{L,t}+P_{S,t-1}Q_{S,t}]\). Diewert (1976, 1992) showed that the Fisher formula had good justifications from both the perspectives of the economic and axiomatic approaches to index number theory.
 
67
The mean and median series cannot adjust properly for changes in the relative prices of land and structures or for changes in the average age of the houses sold. Also our mean and median series are for all sales of houses in Tokyo and thus these series were not adjusted for changes in the number of properties sold in expensive wards and less expensive wards. We cannot expect the mean and median series to be very accurate constant quality indexes of house prices; see Eurostat (2011).
 
68
The end of sample period price levels range from approximately 0.4 to 0.7. These differences were generated over a period of approximately 30 years so that the small differences in quarterly growth rates eventually cumulate into fairly substantial differences between the indexes.
 
69
We note that in order to implement the age adjusted repeat sales model, a form of hedonic regression is required.
 
70
In particular, the MLIT data base does not include the age of the structure, which is a key variable. MLIT has therefore constructed a system that collects location related information using Geographic Information Systems or GIS. In addition, a system was established for real estate appraisers to survey detailed characteristics.
 
Literature
go back to reference Allen, M.T., and W.H. Dare. 2004. The effects of Charm listing prices on house transaction prices. Real Estate Economics 32: 696–713.CrossRef Allen, M.T., and W.H. Dare. 2004. The effects of Charm listing prices on house transaction prices. Real Estate Economics 32: 696–713.CrossRef
go back to reference Bai, J., and P. Perron. 1998. Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica 66: 47–78.CrossRef Bai, J., and P. Perron. 1998. Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica 66: 47–78.CrossRef
go back to reference Bailey, M.J., R.F. Muth, and H.O. Nourse. 1963. A regression model for real estate price index construction. Journal of the American Statistical Association 58: 933–942.CrossRef Bailey, M.J., R.F. Muth, and H.O. Nourse. 1963. A regression model for real estate price index construction. Journal of the American Statistical Association 58: 933–942.CrossRef
go back to reference Bostic, R.W., S.D. Longhofer, and C.L. Readfearn. 2007. Land leverage: decomposing home price dynamics. Real Estate Economics 35 (2): 183–208.CrossRef Bostic, R.W., S.D. Longhofer, and C.L. Readfearn. 2007. Land leverage: decomposing home price dynamics. Real Estate Economics 35 (2): 183–208.CrossRef
go back to reference Bourassa, S.T., M. Hoesli, and J. Sun. 2006. A simple alternative house price index method. Journal of Housing Economics 15: 80–97.CrossRef Bourassa, S.T., M. Hoesli, and J. Sun. 2006. A simple alternative house price index method. Journal of Housing Economics 15: 80–97.CrossRef
go back to reference Case, B., H.O. Pollakowski, and S.M. Wachter. 1991. On choosing among house price index methodologies. AREUEA Journal 19: 286–307.CrossRef Case, B., H.O. Pollakowski, and S.M. Wachter. 1991. On choosing among house price index methodologies. AREUEA Journal 19: 286–307.CrossRef
go back to reference Case, B., and J.M. Quigley. 1991. The dynamics of real estate prices. Review of Economics and Statistics 22: 50–58.CrossRef Case, B., and J.M. Quigley. 1991. The dynamics of real estate prices. Review of Economics and Statistics 22: 50–58.CrossRef
go back to reference Case, K.E., and R.J. Shiller. 1987. Prices of single family homes since 1970: new indexes for four cities. New England Economic Review:45–56. Case, K.E., and R.J. Shiller. 1987. Prices of single family homes since 1970: new indexes for four cities. New England Economic Review:45–56.
go back to reference Case, K.E., and R.J. Shiller. 1989. The efficiency of the market for single family homes. The American Economic Review 79: 125–137. Case, K.E., and R.J. Shiller. 1989. The efficiency of the market for single family homes. The American Economic Review 79: 125–137.
go back to reference Chau, K.W., S.K. Wong, and C.Y. Yiu. 2005. Adjusting for non-linear age effects in the repeat sales index. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 31: 137–153.CrossRef Chau, K.W., S.K. Wong, and C.Y. Yiu. 2005. Adjusting for non-linear age effects in the repeat sales index. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 31: 137–153.CrossRef
go back to reference Clapp, J.M. 1980. The elasticity of substitution for land: the effects of measurement errors. Journal of Urban Economics 8: 255–263.CrossRef Clapp, J.M. 1980. The elasticity of substitution for land: the effects of measurement errors. Journal of Urban Economics 8: 255–263.CrossRef
go back to reference Clapp, J.M., and C. Giaccotto. 1992. Estimating price trends for residential property: a comparison of repeat sales and assessed value methods. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 5: 357–374.CrossRef Clapp, J.M., and C. Giaccotto. 1992. Estimating price trends for residential property: a comparison of repeat sales and assessed value methods. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 5: 357–374.CrossRef
go back to reference Clapp, J.M., and C. Giaccotto. 1998. Price indexes based on the hedonic repeat-sales method: application to the housing market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 16: 5–26.CrossRef Clapp, J.M., and C. Giaccotto. 1998. Price indexes based on the hedonic repeat-sales method: application to the housing market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 16: 5–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Court, A. T. 1939. Hedonic Price Indexes with Automotive Examples. In The Dynamics of Automobile Demand, pp. 98–117. New York: General Motors Corporation. Court, A. T. 1939. Hedonic Price Indexes with Automotive Examples. In The Dynamics of Automobile Demand, pp. 98–117. New York: General Motors Corporation.
go back to reference Davis, M.A., and J. Heathcote. 2007. The price and quantity of residential land in the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 54: 2595–2620.CrossRef Davis, M.A., and J. Heathcote. 2007. The price and quantity of residential land in the United States. Journal of Monetary Economics 54: 2595–2620.CrossRef
go back to reference de Haan, J., and F. Krsinich. 2014. Scanner Data and the Treatment of Quality Change in Rolling Year GEKS Price Indexes. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. forthcoming. de Haan, J., and F. Krsinich. 2014. Scanner Data and the Treatment of Quality Change in Rolling Year GEKS Price Indexes. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics. forthcoming.
go back to reference Deng, Y.D., and McMillen and T.F. Sing, 2012. Private residential price indices in Singapore: a matching approach. Regional Science and Urban Economics 42: 485–494.CrossRef Deng, Y.D., and McMillen and T.F. Sing, 2012. Private residential price indices in Singapore: a matching approach. Regional Science and Urban Economics 42: 485–494.CrossRef
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. 1976. Exact and superlative index numbers. Journal of Econometrics 4: 114–145.CrossRef Diewert, W.E. 1976. Exact and superlative index numbers. Journal of Econometrics 4: 114–145.CrossRef
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. 1992. Fisher ideal output, input and productivity indexes revisited. Journal of Productivity Analysis 3: 211–248.CrossRef Diewert, W.E. 1992. Fisher ideal output, input and productivity indexes revisited. Journal of Productivity Analysis 3: 211–248.CrossRef
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. 2003a. Hedonic Regressions: A Consumer Theory Approach. In Studies in Income and Wealth 64, ed. Scanner Data, R.C. Price Indexes, and Feenstra and M.D. Shapiro, 317–348. Chicago: University of Chicago. Diewert, W.E. 2003a. Hedonic Regressions: A Consumer Theory Approach. In Studies in Income and Wealth 64, ed. Scanner Data, R.C. Price Indexes, and Feenstra and M.D. Shapiro, 317–348. Chicago: University of Chicago.
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. 2003b. Hedonic Regressions: A Review of Some Unresolved Issues. In Paper Presented at the 7th Meeting of the Ottawa Group, Paris, May 27–29. Diewert, W.E. 2003b. Hedonic Regressions: A Review of Some Unresolved Issues. In Paper Presented at the 7th Meeting of the Ottawa Group, Paris, May 27–29.
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. 2010. Alternative Approaches to Measuring House Price Inflation. Discussion Paper 10-10, Department of Economics, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T 1Z1. Diewert, W.E. 2010. Alternative Approaches to Measuring House Price Inflation. Discussion Paper 10-10, Department of Economics, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T 1Z1.
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. 2011. The Paris OECD-IMF Workshop on Real Estate Price Indexes: Conclusions and Future Directions. In Price and Productivity Measurement, Vol. 1: Housing, W.E. Diewert, B.M. Balk, D. Fixler, K.J. Fox and A.O. Nakamura, eds., pp. 87–116. Trafford Press. Diewert, W.E. 2011. The Paris OECD-IMF Workshop on Real Estate Price Indexes: Conclusions and Future Directions. In Price and Productivity Measurement, Vol. 1: Housing, W.E. Diewert, B.M. Balk, D. Fixler, K.J. Fox and A.O. Nakamura, eds., pp. 87–116. Trafford Press.
go back to reference Diewert, W.E. and C. Shimizu 2013. Residential Property Price Indexes for Tokyo. Discussion Paper 13-07, School of Economics, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T 1Z1. Forthcoming in Macroeconomic Dynamics. Diewert, W.E. and C. Shimizu 2013. Residential Property Price Indexes for Tokyo. Discussion Paper 13-07, School of Economics, The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T 1Z1. Forthcoming in Macroeconomic Dynamics.
go back to reference Diewert, W.E., J. de Haan, and R. Hendriks. 2011a. The decomposition of a house price index into land and structures components: a hedonic regression approach. The Valuation Journal 6 (2011): 58–106. Diewert, W.E., J. de Haan, and R. Hendriks. 2011a. The decomposition of a house price index into land and structures components: a hedonic regression approach. The Valuation Journal 6 (2011): 58–106.
go back to reference Diewert, W.E., J. de Haan and R. Hendriks 2011b. Hedonic Regressions and the Decomposition of a House Price index into Land and Structure Components. Discussion Paper 11-01, Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T1Z1. Forthcoming in Econometric Reviews. Diewert, W.E., J. de Haan and R. Hendriks 2011b. Hedonic Regressions and the Decomposition of a House Price index into Land and Structure Components. Discussion Paper 11-01, Department of Economics, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada, V6T1Z1. Forthcoming in Econometric Reviews.
go back to reference Dorsey, R.E., H. Hua, W.J. Mayera, and H. Wanga. 2010. Hedonic versus repeat-sales housing price indexes for measuring the recent boom-bust cycle. Journal of Housing Economics 19: 75–93.CrossRef Dorsey, R.E., H. Hua, W.J. Mayera, and H. Wanga. 2010. Hedonic versus repeat-sales housing price indexes for measuring the recent boom-bust cycle. Journal of Housing Economics 19: 75–93.CrossRef
go back to reference Ekeland, I., J.J. Heckman, and L. Nesheim. 2004. Identification and estimation of hedonic models. Journal of Political Economy 112: 60–109.CrossRef Ekeland, I., J.J. Heckman, and L. Nesheim. 2004. Identification and estimation of hedonic models. Journal of Political Economy 112: 60–109.CrossRef
go back to reference Engelhardt, G.V. 2003. Nominal loss aversion, housing equity constraints and household mobility: evidence from the United States. Journal of Urban Economics 53: 171–195.CrossRef Engelhardt, G.V. 2003. Nominal loss aversion, housing equity constraints and household mobility: evidence from the United States. Journal of Urban Economics 53: 171–195.CrossRef
go back to reference Eurostat. 2011. Handbook on Residential Property Price Indices. Luxembourg: Eurostat. Eurostat. 2011. Handbook on Residential Property Price Indices. Luxembourg: Eurostat.
go back to reference Fisher, I. 1922. The Making of Index Numbers. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin. Fisher, I. 1922. The Making of Index Numbers. Boston: Houghton-Mifflin.
go back to reference Francke, M.K. 2008. The Hierarchical Trend Model. In Mass Appraisal Methods: An International Perspective for Property Valuers, T. Kauko and M. Damato, eds., pp. 164–180. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell. Francke, M.K. 2008. The Hierarchical Trend Model. In Mass Appraisal Methods: An International Perspective for Property Valuers, T. Kauko and M. Damato, eds., pp. 164–180. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell.
go back to reference Francke, M.K., and G.A. Vos. 2004. The hierarchical trend model for property valuation and local price indices. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 28 (2/3): 179–208.CrossRef Francke, M.K., and G.A. Vos. 2004. The hierarchical trend model for property valuation and local price indices. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 28 (2/3): 179–208.CrossRef
go back to reference Gatzlaff, D.H., and D.R. Haurin. 1998. Sample selection and biases in local house value indices. Journal of Urban Economics 43: 199–222.CrossRef Gatzlaff, D.H., and D.R. Haurin. 1998. Sample selection and biases in local house value indices. Journal of Urban Economics 43: 199–222.CrossRef
go back to reference Genesove, D., and C. Mayer. 1997. Equity and time to sale in the real estate market. American Economic Review 87: 255–269. Genesove, D., and C. Mayer. 1997. Equity and time to sale in the real estate market. American Economic Review 87: 255–269.
go back to reference Genesove, D., and C. Mayer. 2001. Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the housing market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116: 1233–1260.CrossRef Genesove, D., and C. Mayer. 2001. Loss aversion and seller behavior: evidence from the housing market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116: 1233–1260.CrossRef
go back to reference Goetzmann, W. and L. Peng 2006. Estimating house price indexes in the preference of seller reservation prices.CrossRef Goetzmann, W. and L. Peng 2006. Estimating house price indexes in the preference of seller reservation prices.CrossRef
go back to reference Goodman, A.C. and T.G. Thibodeau. 1998. Dwelling age heteroskedasticity in repeat sales house price equations. Goodman, A.C. and T.G. Thibodeau. 1998. Dwelling age heteroskedasticity in repeat sales house price equations.
go back to reference Griliches, Z. 1971. Introduction: hedonic price indexes revisited. In Price Indexes and Quality Change, Z. Griliches, ed., pp. 3–15. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press. Griliches, Z. 1971. Introduction: hedonic price indexes revisited. In Price Indexes and Quality Change, Z. Griliches, ed., pp. 3–15. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
go back to reference Gyourko, J., and A. Saiz. 2004. Reinvestment in the housing stock: the role of construction costs and the supply side. Journal of Urban Economics 55: 238–256.CrossRef Gyourko, J., and A. Saiz. 2004. Reinvestment in the housing stock: the role of construction costs and the supply side. Journal of Urban Economics 55: 238–256.CrossRef
go back to reference Hicks, J.R. 1946. Value and Capital, 2nd ed. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Hicks, J.R. 1946. Value and Capital, 2nd ed. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
go back to reference Haurin, D.R., J.L. Haurin, T. Nadauld, and A. Sanders. 2010. List prices, sale prices and marketing time: an application to U.S. housing markets. Real Estate Economics 38: 659–685.CrossRef Haurin, D.R., J.L. Haurin, T. Nadauld, and A. Sanders. 2010. List prices, sale prices and marketing time: an application to U.S. housing markets. Real Estate Economics 38: 659–685.CrossRef
go back to reference Ivancic, L., W.E. Diewert, and K.J. Fox. 2009. Scanner Data, Time Aggregation and the Construction of Price Indexes, Discussion Paper 09–09. Department of Economics: The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada. Ivancic, L., W.E. Diewert, and K.J. Fox. 2009. Scanner Data, Time Aggregation and the Construction of Price Indexes, Discussion Paper 09–09. Department of Economics: The University of British Columbia, Vancouver, Canada.
go back to reference Ivancic, L., W.E. Diewert, and K.J. Fox. 2011. Scanner data, time aggregation and the construction of price indexes. Journal of Econometrics 161: 24–35.CrossRef Ivancic, L., W.E. Diewert, and K.J. Fox. 2011. Scanner data, time aggregation and the construction of price indexes. Journal of Econometrics 161: 24–35.CrossRef
go back to reference Knight, J.R., C.F. Sirmans, and G.K. Turnbull. 1998. List price information in residential appraisal and underwriting. Journal of Real Estate Research 15: 59–76. Knight, J.R., C.F. Sirmans, and G.K. Turnbull. 1998. List price information in residential appraisal and underwriting. Journal of Real Estate Research 15: 59–76.
go back to reference Koev, E., and J.M.C. Santos Silva. 2008. Hedonic Methods for Decomposing House Price Indices into Land and Structure Components, unpublished paper. Department of Economics: University of Essex, England, October. Koev, E., and J.M.C. Santos Silva. 2008. Hedonic Methods for Decomposing House Price Indices into Land and Structure Components, unpublished paper. Department of Economics: University of Essex, England, October.
go back to reference Machado, J.A.F., and J. Mata. 2005. Counterfactual decomposition of changes in wage distributions using quantile regression. Journal of Applied Econometrics 20: 445–465.CrossRef Machado, J.A.F., and J. Mata. 2005. Counterfactual decomposition of changes in wage distributions using quantile regression. Journal of Applied Econometrics 20: 445–465.CrossRef
go back to reference McMillen, D.P. 2003. The return of centralization to Chicago: using repeat sales to identify changes in house price distance gradients. Regional Science and Urban Economics 33: 287–304.CrossRef McMillen, D.P. 2003. The return of centralization to Chicago: using repeat sales to identify changes in house price distance gradients. Regional Science and Urban Economics 33: 287–304.CrossRef
go back to reference McMillen, D.P. 2008. Changes in the distribution of house prices over time: structural characteristics, neighborhood or coefficients? Journal of Urban Economics 64: 573–589.CrossRef McMillen, D.P. 2008. Changes in the distribution of house prices over time: structural characteristics, neighborhood or coefficients? Journal of Urban Economics 64: 573–589.CrossRef
go back to reference McMillen, D.P. 2012. Repeat sales as a matching estimator. Real Estate Economics 40: 745–773.CrossRef McMillen, D.P. 2012. Repeat sales as a matching estimator. Real Estate Economics 40: 745–773.CrossRef
go back to reference McMillen, D.P., and P. Thorsnes. 2006. Housing renovations and the quantile repeat sales price index. Real Estate Economics 34: 567–587.CrossRef McMillen, D.P., and P. Thorsnes. 2006. Housing renovations and the quantile repeat sales price index. Real Estate Economics 34: 567–587.CrossRef
go back to reference Muth, R.F. 1971. The derived demand for Urban residential land. Urban Studies 8: 243–254.CrossRef Muth, R.F. 1971. The derived demand for Urban residential land. Urban Studies 8: 243–254.CrossRef
go back to reference Pollakowski, H.O. 1995. Data sources for measuring house price changes. Journal of Housing Research 6 (3): 377–387. Pollakowski, H.O. 1995. Data sources for measuring house price changes. Journal of Housing Research 6 (3): 377–387.
go back to reference Rambaldi, A.N., R.R.J. McAllister, K. Collins and C.S. Fletcher. 2010. Separating Land from Structure in Property Prices: A Case Study from Brisbane Australia. School of Economics, The University of Queensland, St. Lucia, Queensland 4072, Australia. Rambaldi, A.N., R.R.J. McAllister, K. Collins and C.S. Fletcher. 2010. Separating Land from Structure in Property Prices: A Case Study from Brisbane Australia. School of Economics, The University of Queensland, St. Lucia, Queensland 4072, Australia.
go back to reference Rosen, S. 1974. Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy 82: 34–55.CrossRef Rosen, S. 1974. Hedonic prices and implicit markets: product differentiation in pure competition. Journal of Political Economy 82: 34–55.CrossRef
go back to reference Schwann, G.M. 1998. A real estate price index for thin markets. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 16 (3): 269–287.CrossRef Schwann, G.M. 1998. A real estate price index for thin markets. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 16 (3): 269–287.CrossRef
go back to reference Shimizu, C., and K.G. Nishimura. 2006. Biases in appraisal land price information: the case of Japan. Journal of Property Investment and Finance 26: 150–175.CrossRef Shimizu, C., and K.G. Nishimura. 2006. Biases in appraisal land price information: the case of Japan. Journal of Property Investment and Finance 26: 150–175.CrossRef
go back to reference Shimizu, C., and K.G. Nishimura. 2007. Pricing structure in Tokyo metropolitan land markets and its structural changes: pre-bubble, bubble, and post-bubble periods. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 35: 475–496.CrossRef Shimizu, C., and K.G. Nishimura. 2007. Pricing structure in Tokyo metropolitan land markets and its structural changes: pre-bubble, bubble, and post-bubble periods. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 35: 475–496.CrossRef
go back to reference Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura, and Y. Asami. 2004. Search and vacancy costs in the Tokyo housing market: an attempt to measure social costs of imperfect information. Review of Urban and Regional Development Studies 16: 210–230.CrossRef Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura, and Y. Asami. 2004. Search and vacancy costs in the Tokyo housing market: an attempt to measure social costs of imperfect information. Review of Urban and Regional Development Studies 16: 210–230.CrossRef
go back to reference Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura, and T. Watanabe. 2010. Housing prices in Tokyo: a comparison of hedonic and repeat sales measures. Journal of Economics and Statistics 230 (6): 792–813. Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura, and T. Watanabe. 2010. Housing prices in Tokyo: a comparison of hedonic and repeat sales measures. Journal of Economics and Statistics 230 (6): 792–813.
go back to reference Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura and T. Watanabe. 2011. House Prices at Different Stages in Buying/Selling Process. Hitotsubashi University Research Center for Price Dynamics Working Paper Working Paper,No. 69. Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura and T. Watanabe. 2011. House Prices at Different Stages in Buying/Selling Process. Hitotsubashi University Research Center for Price Dynamics Working Paper Working Paper,No. 69.
go back to reference Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura and T. Watanabe. 2012. House Prices from Magazines, Realtors, and the Land Registry. Property Market and Financial Stability, BIS Papers No.64, Bank of International Settlements, March 2012, pp. 29-38. Shimizu, C., K.G. Nishimura and T. Watanabe. 2012. House Prices from Magazines, Realtors, and the Land Registry. Property Market and Financial Stability, BIS Papers No.64, Bank of International Settlements, March 2012, pp. 29-38.
go back to reference Shimizu, C., H. Takatsuji, H. Ono, and K.G. Nishimura. 2010. Structural and temporal changes in the housing market and hedonic housing price indices. International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis 3 (4): 351–368.CrossRef Shimizu, C., H. Takatsuji, H. Ono, and K.G. Nishimura. 2010. Structural and temporal changes in the housing market and hedonic housing price indices. International Journal of Housing Markets and Analysis 3 (4): 351–368.CrossRef
go back to reference Standard and Poor’s. 2008. S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price indexes: Index Methodology, March 2008. Standard and Poor’s. 2008. S&P/Case-Shiller Home Price indexes: Index Methodology, March 2008.
go back to reference Statistics Portugal (Instituto Nacional de Estatistica). 2009. Owner-Occupied Housing: Econometric Study and Model to Estimate Land Prices, Final Report, paper presented to the Eurostat Working Group on the Harmonization of Consumer Price Indices, March 26–27. Luxembourg: Eurostat. Statistics Portugal (Instituto Nacional de Estatistica). 2009. Owner-Occupied Housing: Econometric Study and Model to Estimate Land Prices, Final Report, paper presented to the Eurostat Working Group on the Harmonization of Consumer Price Indices, March 26–27. Luxembourg: Eurostat.
go back to reference Summers, R. 1973. International comparisons with incomplete data. Review of Income and Wealth 29 (1): 1–16.CrossRef Summers, R. 1973. International comparisons with incomplete data. Review of Income and Wealth 29 (1): 1–16.CrossRef
go back to reference Triplett, Jack. 2004. Handbook on Hedonic Indexes and Quality Adjustments in Price Indexes. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2004/9. Triplett, Jack. 2004. Handbook on Hedonic Indexes and Quality Adjustments in Price Indexes. OECD Science, Technology and Industry Working Papers 2004/9.
go back to reference Thorsnes, P. 1997. Consistent estimates of the elasticity of substitution between land and non-land inputs in the production of housing. Journal of Urban Economics 42: 98–108.CrossRef Thorsnes, P. 1997. Consistent estimates of the elasticity of substitution between land and non-land inputs in the production of housing. Journal of Urban Economics 42: 98–108.CrossRef
go back to reference White, K.J. 2004. Shazam: User’s Reference Manual, Version 10. Vancouver, Canada: Northwest Econometrics Ltd. White, K.J. 2004. Shazam: User’s Reference Manual, Version 10. Vancouver, Canada: Northwest Econometrics Ltd.
Metadata
Title
Estimation of Residential Property Price Index: Methodology and Data Sources
Authors
W. Erwin Diewert
Kiyohiko G. Nishimura
Chihiro Shimizu
Tsutomu Watanabe
Copyright Year
2020
Publisher
Springer Japan
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-4-431-55942-9_4