Skip to main content
Top
Published in:
Cover of the book

2018 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

1. Facts, Figures and Theory

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This chapter provides some data on the geographical and historical importance of the phenomenon and compares it with the Initial Public Offering (IPO) market in order to show how it has increased and fluctuated over time and across different stock exchanges in response to market-wide factors. It then explains the most common techniques used to delist a firm and the US regulation that disciplines the procedure for implementing them. It also provides the reader with a wide and systematic description of the theoretical approaches that are proposed in order to explain the choice, such as information-based theories, access to capital, stock liquidity, corporate governance, listing requirements, short-termism, the use of derivatives, takeover defense, and agency problems.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
The market timing argument is mainly developed within the IPO (Initial Public Offering) market (Ibbotson and Jaffe 1975; Ritter 1984; Lucas and McDonald 1990; Loughran et al. 1994; Pagano et al. 1998; Lowry 2003; Ritter and Welch 2002), but some empirical studies (Mitchell and Mulherin 1996; Brau et al. 2003) develop and find a similar regularity within takeovers that are one of the most important ways to delist a publicly traded firm. They find an increase in takeover activity during industry and economic downturns, and therefore, when information asymmetries peak. In other words, intense periods of IPO activity tend to occur when the takeover activity is relatively low and vice versa. This could help explain why IPO and going private may occur in negatively correlated waves.
 
2
Private equity investors are typically funds structured as limited partnerships with outside investors who act as passive limited partners and the private equity firm that acts as the controlling general partner (Metrick and Yasuda 2010).
 
3
In the US, the squeeze-out thresholds are regulated by State laws. For example, in Delaware, if the acquirer purchases at least 90% of the target’s shares in the tender offer, it may then squeeze out the remaining shares with a short form merger, a merger that requires no further involvement by the target’s board or stockholders. In other countries there are similar squeeze-out regulations. For example, in Germany and Italy, the squeeze-out threshold is 95% and in the UK it is 90%.
 
4
In the US, we need to distinguish shareholders of record from beneficial shareholders. The difference between the two concepts is a consequence of the fast dematerialization of shares pursued by the major stock exchanges in order to increase the efficiency of stock trading, brokerage, and clearing services (Marosi and Massoud 2007). The effect of this dematerialization process is that shareholders no longer hold paper share certificates. They hold their claims in electronic form with street names such as Goldman Sachs, Morgan Stanley, and other brokerage firms. Consequently, the number of shareholders listed in corporate records as having been issued a paper stock certificate has significantly reduced. This has also created a significant deviation between the number of beneficial shareholders, who are the actual shareholders, and the number of shareholders of record, who are the brokerage firms in which the beneficial shareholders hold their shares electronically. This means that Goldman Sachs, as the holder of the claims of thousands of beneficial shareholders, will be counted as one certificate holder (one shareholder of record). The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) only considers the number of shareholders of record in order to define the threshold below which a firm can delist and terminate the registration of securities under Section 12(g) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 that leads to the end of reporting obligations for listed firms. A formal definition of securities “held of record” is provided by the Rule 12g5-1 “Definition of securities ‘held of record’” of the Code of Federal Regulations (Title 17, Chapter II, Part 240—General Rules and Regulations, Securities Exchange Act of 1934).
 
5
Form 10 is the type of document that should be submitted to the SEC in order to make the registration statement.
 
6
Accredited investors are mainly institutional investors, high-net-worth individuals, and directors-executive officers of the issuer. For a formal definition, see Rule 501 of the Code of Federal Regulations (Title 17, Chapter II, Part 230, General Rules and Regulations, Securities Act of 1933).
 
7
Form 15 is the type of document that the firm eligible to be delisted should submit to the SEC in order to certify and notify the termination of registration of a class of securities under Section 12(g) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934.
 
8
Small firms tend to be more opaque in providing information on their business as a result of costs related to disclosure requirements, investor relations, and potential loss of competitive advantage (Pettit and Singer 1985). Moreover, they also tend to be followed by few analysts and their shares are often neglected by large institutional investors (Freeman 1987; Draper and Paudyal 2008).
 
9
For an analytical formalization of the model, see Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999).
 
10
The issue of the effect of a modification of the listing requirements on the going private decision is directly analyzed by Engel et al. (2007) who investigate how the enactment of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 affected the decision to go private. They find that higher disclosure requirements imposed by the new regulation induced many small and poorly liquid firms to leave the stock market because the benefits of greater transparency, lower information acquisition costs, and higher liquidity were surpassed by the costs of compliance that each firm had to bear. The model proposed by Chemmanur and Fulghieri (1999) takes into consideration this aspect with a focus on the upper bound on the investors’ information production costs resulting from the introduction of such a regulation. We will come back both to the relationship between going private and listing requirements and to the trade-off between the costs of disclosure requirements and their benefits to investors in terms of lower information acquisition costs, lower adverse selection problems, and higher liquidity, later on in the text.
 
11
For a rigorous analytical demonstration of these results, see Subrahmanyam and Titman (1999).
 
12
For an analytical formalization of the model, see Yosha (1995).
 
13
The intuition is that, in this case, the private information is publicly disclosed but the reaction of the competitor is not strong because the quality of the innovator’s project is not high. The innovator therefore prefers to bear the higher costs of public financing rather than being perceived as being of high quality, therefore triggering a strong reaction from the competitor.
 
14
In this case, the innovator prefers private financing because a public disclosure of private information on the project may trigger a stronger reaction from the competitor.
 
15
For an analytical demonstration of these results, see Merton (1987).
 
16
Despite the fact that rights offerings have lower direct costs (i.e., fees) than public ones (Slovin et al. 2000), parallel research streams found that this method can be more expensive than a public offering due to indirect costs: (1) costs borne by shareholders to trade the rights (Hansen 1988); (2) lower market liquidity resulting from a rights offer due to the preserved higher ownership concentration (Kothare 1997); (3) wealth transfers from shareholders to convertible securities holders connected with non-neutral anti-dilution clauses (Myhal 1990); (4) possible agency costs induced by collusion between managers and underwriters (Smith 1977; Herman 1981); (5) stock price declining during the offering period, due to arbitrage activity frequently carried out by the underwriter (Singh 1997).
 
17
The debate on how to measure a firm’s financial constraint was very lively, starting with the pioneering study by Fazzari et al. (1988) and continuing with Kaplan and Zingales (1997), Fazzari et al. (2000) and Kaplan and Zingales (2000) who responded to each other.
 
18
Empirical evidence on this matter was found by Botosan (1997) and Barth et al. (2013).
 
19
Bhide (1993) has a different opinion. Most efforts to increase corporate liquidity involve an increase in the number and turnover of shareholders and, in the process, a reduction in the stability and, perhaps most importantly, the concentration of ownership. Bhide (1993) argues that increases in liquidity can weaken corporate governance in underperforming companies by making it easier for dissatisfied investors to sell their shares instead of attempting to bring about constructive change by engaging managements and boards. Coffee (1991) offers a similar thesis and argues that public ownership incurs the high shareholder dispersion that weakens the control on managers that can be carried out better by the private ownership.
 
20
The tension between liquidity and corporate control and its effect on the choice between public and private financing will be discussed in greater detail later on in the text.
 
21
Bear in mind that the bargaining phase has to start if the incumbent, after selling the shares to outside shareholders, still retains control. In contrast, if, after the IPO, he no longer has the majority of votes, the control transfer may occur independently of the incumbent agreement. The buyer, faced with the incumbent rejection of its offer, may launch a tender offer directly to dispersed shareholders. However, Zingales (1995) shows that for the initial owner, relinquishing control is never optimal.
 
22
The fact that a company is better sold in stages for considerations related to corporate control is also analyzed in Mello and Parsons (1998) and Stoughton and Zechner (1998).
 
23
θl and θh can be seen as, respectively, “low” prior beliefs (a sort of worst-case scenario) and “high” prior beliefs (a sort of best-case scenario), conditional on the appearance of a G-type project.
 
24
Bear in mind that without preparation effort, the project will not affect the firm’s cash flows which will remain at level S.
 
25
In this case, the project has a positive NPV of Xh − S.
 
26
In this case, for investors, the project has a negative NPV of θlXG − S.
 
27
This implies that the higher the level of agreement with managers, the higher the value of the company for investors will be. This point will be demonstrated later on. However, intuitively, this result arises from the fact that when there is agreement, the value that investors attach to the project will be Xh = θhXG (if the prior belief is θh) or θlS (if the prior belief is θl). Vice versa, in case of disagreement, the value for investors will be θhS (if the prior belief is θh for investors and θl for managers) or θlXG = Xl (if the prior belief is θl for investors and θh for managers). In the event of agreement, managers and investors always agree in making the project or not and there is one scenario in which the project has a positive NPV for investors. In case of disagreement, the project has always a negative NPV for investors and in one scenario (when the managers’ prior belief is θh), the managers, according to their managerial autonomy, may decide to implement it despite investors not wanting it. This means that, ceteris paribus, the value of the company for investors is increasing in the level of agreement ρ.
 
28
The positive relationship between managerial autonomy and the perceived value of the ownership stake held by managers will be demonstrated later on.
 
29
See also the discussion in section “Investor participation, agreement and firm value” for the motivations behind this result.
 
30
Pagni, L., 2012. “Edison e le altre cinquanta. La grande fuga da Piazza Affari. Così la crisi ha rivoluzionato il listino della Borsa”, La Repubblica, August 18. Monti, M., 2012. “Ex quotate. La bufera sui mercati ha incrementato il numero di uscite dalla Borsa negli ultimi quattro anni. La crisi e quei 50 “addii” a Piazza Affari”, Il Sole 24 Ore, February 2.
 
31
Stothard, M., 2012. “Economic woes lead to AIM delistings”, Financial Times, January 3.
 
32
The inequality \( \widehat{\rho}>\overline{\rho} \) holds because of L, the liquidity cost under private ownership. In fact L reduces the private investors’ valuation of the company under private ownership (\( {V}_{pr}^I \)). This implies that for the private ownership to be preferred, the cutoff value of ρpr should be greater than \( \overline{\rho}, \) the expected level of agreement in the public market, and, in turn, the inequality \( {\rho}_{pr}>\widehat{\rho}>\overline{\rho} \) should hold.
 
33
Bear in mind that \( {\rho}_{pr}>\overline{\rho} \) leads to higher managerial autonomy and greater level of managerial effort which, in turn, give rise to higher probability of project implementation under private ownership.
 
34
Bear in mind that the managers’ total payoff under private ownership (\( {V}_{pr}^M \)) increases in managerial search effort, e, which, in turn, increases in the degree of agreement under private ownership, ρpr.
 
35
See also Lehn and Poulsen (1989), Denis (1992), Opler and Titman (1993) and Mehran and Peristiani (2010) for evidence that is consistent with the free cash flow hypothesis. Vice versa, Maupin et al. (1984), Kieschnick (1989, 1998) and Servaes (1994) show different results.
 
36
For example, Bebchuk et al. (2009) propose five clauses (i.e., staggered boards, limits to amend by-laws, supermajority requirements for mergers and charter amendments, poison pills, and golden parachutes) which should provide a measure of the degree of managerial entrenchment. Consequently, firms that meet these provisions are less likely to go private according to Boot et al. (2008).
 
37
In fact, for private ownership to be desirable, it has to be \( {\rho}_{pr}>\widehat{\rho}>\overline{\rho}. \) Given that managerial autonomy is increasing in ρ and managerial search effort is increasing in ρ and η, it follows that managerial search effort under public ownership will be lower than that under private ownership.
 
38
Voting shares are generally held by managers and the largest shareholders. They should therefore be less affected by trading activity. This, in turn, could further be limited by transfer restrictions that often accompany voting shares held by insiders.
 
39
Coates (2007) documents a dramatic fall, after the enactment of SOX, of the number of securities frauds alleged in significant class action lawsuits against US public companies.
 
40
Coates (2007) documents that earnings management fell after SOX. The correlation that existed before the SOX between abnormal accounting accruals—that is, accruals not predicted by standard empirical models of accruals—and the importance of an audit client to its auditor vanished after the law was passed. Investor confidence also increased after the passage of SOX. Bid-ask spreads and market depth, which were widening and falling, respectively, during 2001–2002, reflecting falling investor confidence, began to tighten and rise again in both the month and in the nine months after the legislation was passed.
 
41
Some firms, in order to escape the increased regulatory burden of SOX, go dark instead of going private. The difference is that when going dark, the firm’s shares continue to be traded on the Pink Sheets but the firm legally ceases to file SEC disclosures because the number of its shareholders has fallen below the trigger level for SEC registration, while when going private, the firm’s shares cease trading. In both cases, companies will no longer be subject to the requirements of SOX. We will go back to this difference later on.
 
42
Zingales (2007) and Halling et al. (2008) empirically show that US stock markets have been facing increased competition for trading volume from domestic markets, but the trend does not seem to be linked to SOX enactment.
 
43
According to Demirag (2015), short-termism includes those factors acting upon (or within) an organization which tend to cause decision-makers (a) to raise the discount rate above the cost of capital; and/or (b) to contract the forecast horizon beyond which future revenues are ignored altogether. Such pressures will tend to reduce the rate of investment and/or bias it toward short-term projects.
 
44
However, Shleifer and Vishny (1997) in their review of corporate governance conclude that the theories and arguments in favor of the view that US companies are relatively short sighted are remarkably short of empirical support. Anecdotal evidence comes from corporate executives who increasingly often state the excessive level of public market pressure to be the main reason for their choice to take the firm private. For example, in 2010, Burger King agreed to a $3.3 billion sale to 3G Capital. 3G Capital took the firm private and its executives and analysts said going private would free Burger King to make major changes without the distraction of pleasing Wall Street (Baertlein, L., 2010. “Burger King agrees to $3.3 billion sale to 3G Capital”, Reuters, September 2). Likewise, in 2010, Burlington Northern Santa Fe (BNSF) prepared to delist from the public markets following its takeover by Warren Buffet’s Berkshire Hathaway in a deal valued at $44 billion. Matthew Rose, chief executive of Burlington Northern Santa Fe, said it could be frustrating dealing with quarterly earnings announcements when the company’s investments were far longer term and criticized the market’s excessive focus on short-term results and the lack of a long-term perspective (Wright, R., 2010. “BNSF chief hits at short-termism”, Financial Times, February 12). Market pressure is advanced as motivation to go private also outside the US. For example, Ferretti spa, world leader in the production of luxury yachts, chose to leave the Italian stock market in 2003. Ferretti’s CEO, Norberto Ferretti, said that the company had to invest €250 million in plants and acquisitions and needed to raise capital. The firm would not have been able to pursue that strategy effectively if the market had been short sighted, not very patient, and excessively punitive toward those firms performing long-term expansion plans (Puato, A., 2002. “Quei titoli perduti”, Il Corriere della Sera, October 7).
 
Literature
go back to reference Acharya, V. V., & Pedersen, L. H. (2005). Asset pricing with liquidity risk. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(2), 375–410.CrossRef Acharya, V. V., & Pedersen, L. H. (2005). Asset pricing with liquidity risk. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(2), 375–410.CrossRef
go back to reference Acharya, V. V., Franks, J., & Servaes, H. (2007). Private equity: Boom and bust? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 19(4), 1–10.CrossRef Acharya, V. V., Franks, J., & Servaes, H. (2007). Private equity: Boom and bust? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 19(4), 1–10.CrossRef
go back to reference Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for lemons. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.CrossRef Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for lemons. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.CrossRef
go back to reference Amihud, Y., & Li, K. (2006). The declining information content of dividend announcements and the effects of institutional holdings. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 41(3), 637–660.CrossRef Amihud, Y., & Li, K. (2006). The declining information content of dividend announcements and the effects of institutional holdings. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 41(3), 637–660.CrossRef
go back to reference Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1986). Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of Financial Economics, 17(2), 223–249.CrossRef Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1986). Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. Journal of Financial Economics, 17(2), 223–249.CrossRef
go back to reference Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1988). Liquidity and asset prices: Financial management implications. Financial Management, 17(1), 5–15.CrossRef Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1988). Liquidity and asset prices: Financial management implications. Financial Management, 17(1), 5–15.CrossRef
go back to reference Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1991). Liquidity, asset prices and financial policy. Financial Analysts Journal, 47(6), 56–66.CrossRef Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (1991). Liquidity, asset prices and financial policy. Financial Analysts Journal, 47(6), 56–66.CrossRef
go back to reference Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (2012). Liquidity, the value of the firm, and corporate finance. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 24(1), 17–32.CrossRef Amihud, Y., & Mendelson, H. (2012). Liquidity, the value of the firm, and corporate finance. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 24(1), 17–32.CrossRef
go back to reference Arbel, A., Carvell, S., & Strebel, P. (1983). Giraffes, institutions and neglected firms. Financial Analysts Journal, 39(3), 57–63.CrossRef Arbel, A., Carvell, S., & Strebel, P. (1983). Giraffes, institutions and neglected firms. Financial Analysts Journal, 39(3), 57–63.CrossRef
go back to reference Aslan, H., & Kumar, P. (2011). Lemons or cherries? Growth opportunities and market temptations in going public and private. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46(2), 489–526.CrossRef Aslan, H., & Kumar, P. (2011). Lemons or cherries? Growth opportunities and market temptations in going public and private. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 46(2), 489–526.CrossRef
go back to reference Bajo, E., Barbi, M., Bigelli, M., & Hillier, D. (2013). The role of institutional investors in public-to-private transactions. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(11), 4327–4336.CrossRef Bajo, E., Barbi, M., Bigelli, M., & Hillier, D. (2013). The role of institutional investors in public-to-private transactions. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(11), 4327–4336.CrossRef
go back to reference Baker, M., & Stein, J. C. (2004). Market liquidity as a sentiment indicator. Journal of Financial Markets, 7(3), 271–299.CrossRef Baker, M., & Stein, J. C. (2004). Market liquidity as a sentiment indicator. Journal of Financial Markets, 7(3), 271–299.CrossRef
go back to reference Bancel, F., & Mittoo, U. R. (2009). Why do European firms go public? European Financial Management, 15(4), 844–884.CrossRef Bancel, F., & Mittoo, U. R. (2009). Why do European firms go public? European Financial Management, 15(4), 844–884.CrossRef
go back to reference Banerjee, S., Gatchev, V. A., & Spindt, P. A. (2007). Stock market liquidity and firm dividend policy. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(2), 369–397.CrossRef Banerjee, S., Gatchev, V. A., & Spindt, P. A. (2007). Stock market liquidity and firm dividend policy. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(2), 369–397.CrossRef
go back to reference Barth, M. E., Konchitchki, Y., & Landsman, W. R. (2013). Cost of capital and earnings transparency. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 55(2–3), 206–224.CrossRef Barth, M. E., Konchitchki, Y., & Landsman, W. R. (2013). Cost of capital and earnings transparency. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 55(2–3), 206–224.CrossRef
go back to reference Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., & Ferrell, A. (2009). What matters in corporate governance? Review of Financial Studies, 22(2), 783–827.CrossRef Bebchuk, L., Cohen, A., & Ferrell, A. (2009). What matters in corporate governance? Review of Financial Studies, 22(2), 783–827.CrossRef
go back to reference Bharath, S. T., & Dittmar, A. K. (2010). Why do firms use private equity to opt out of public markets? The Review of Financial Studies, 23(5), 1771–1818.CrossRef Bharath, S. T., & Dittmar, A. K. (2010). Why do firms use private equity to opt out of public markets? The Review of Financial Studies, 23(5), 1771–1818.CrossRef
go back to reference Bharath, S. T., Pasquariello, P., & Wu, G. (2009). Does asymmetric information drive capital structure decisions? Review of Financial Studies, 22(8), 3211–3243.CrossRef Bharath, S. T., Pasquariello, P., & Wu, G. (2009). Does asymmetric information drive capital structure decisions? Review of Financial Studies, 22(8), 3211–3243.CrossRef
go back to reference Bharath, S. T., Dittmar, A. K., & Sivadasan, J. (2014). Do going-private transactions affect plant efficiency and investment? The Review of Financial Studies, 27(7), 1929–1976.CrossRef Bharath, S. T., Dittmar, A. K., & Sivadasan, J. (2014). Do going-private transactions affect plant efficiency and investment? The Review of Financial Studies, 27(7), 1929–1976.CrossRef
go back to reference Bhide, A. (1990). Reversing corporate diversification. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 3(2), 70–81.CrossRef Bhide, A. (1990). Reversing corporate diversification. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 3(2), 70–81.CrossRef
go back to reference Bhide, A. (1993). The hidden costs of stock market liquidity. Journal of Financial Economics, 34(1), 31–51.CrossRef Bhide, A. (1993). The hidden costs of stock market liquidity. Journal of Financial Economics, 34(1), 31–51.CrossRef
go back to reference Black, F. (1976). Studies of stock price volatility changes. Proceedings of the 1976 meetings of the American Statistical Association, business and economics statistics section, pp. 177–181. Black, F. (1976). Studies of stock price volatility changes. Proceedings of the 1976 meetings of the American Statistical Association, business and economics statistics section, pp. 177–181.
go back to reference Bolton, P., & Von Thadden, E. L. (1998). Blocks, liquidity, and corporate control. The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 1–25.CrossRef Bolton, P., & Von Thadden, E. L. (1998). Blocks, liquidity, and corporate control. The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 1–25.CrossRef
go back to reference Boot, A. W., Gopalan, R., & Thakor, A. V. (2006). The entrepreneur’s choice between private and public ownership. The Journal of Finance, 61(2), 803–836.CrossRef Boot, A. W., Gopalan, R., & Thakor, A. V. (2006). The entrepreneur’s choice between private and public ownership. The Journal of Finance, 61(2), 803–836.CrossRef
go back to reference Boot, A. W., Gopalan, R., & Thakor, A. V. (2008). Market liquidity, investor participation, and managerial autonomy: Why do firms go private? The Journal of Finance, 63(4), 2013–2059.CrossRef Boot, A. W., Gopalan, R., & Thakor, A. V. (2008). Market liquidity, investor participation, and managerial autonomy: Why do firms go private? The Journal of Finance, 63(4), 2013–2059.CrossRef
go back to reference Botosan, C. A. (1997). Disclosure level and the cost of equity capital. The Accounting Review, 72(3), 323–349. Botosan, C. A. (1997). Disclosure level and the cost of equity capital. The Accounting Review, 72(3), 323–349.
go back to reference Brau, J. C., & Fawcett, S. E. (2006). Initial public offerings: An analysis of theory and practice. The Journal of Finance, 61(1), 399–436.CrossRef Brau, J. C., & Fawcett, S. E. (2006). Initial public offerings: An analysis of theory and practice. The Journal of Finance, 61(1), 399–436.CrossRef
go back to reference Brau, J. C., Francis, B., & Kohers, N. (2003). The choice of IPO versus takeover: Empirical evidence. Journal of Business, 76(4), 583–612.CrossRef Brau, J. C., Francis, B., & Kohers, N. (2003). The choice of IPO versus takeover: Empirical evidence. Journal of Business, 76(4), 583–612.CrossRef
go back to reference Brav, A., Jiang, W., Partnoy, F., & Thomas, R. (2008). Hedge fund activism, corporate governance, and firm performance. The Journal of Finance, 63(4), 1729–1775.CrossRef Brav, A., Jiang, W., Partnoy, F., & Thomas, R. (2008). Hedge fund activism, corporate governance, and firm performance. The Journal of Finance, 63(4), 1729–1775.CrossRef
go back to reference Brennan, M. J., & Subrahmanyam, A. (1995). Investment analysis and price formation in securities markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 38(3), 361–381.CrossRef Brennan, M. J., & Subrahmanyam, A. (1995). Investment analysis and price formation in securities markets. Journal of Financial Economics, 38(3), 361–381.CrossRef
go back to reference Brockman, P., Howe, J. S., & Mortal, S. (2008). Stock market liquidity and the decision to repurchase. Journal of Corporate Finance, 14(4), 446–459.CrossRef Brockman, P., Howe, J. S., & Mortal, S. (2008). Stock market liquidity and the decision to repurchase. Journal of Corporate Finance, 14(4), 446–459.CrossRef
go back to reference Bushee, B. J., & Leuz, C. (2005). Economic consequences of SEC disclosure regulation: Evidence from the OTC bulletin board. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39(2), 233–264.CrossRef Bushee, B. J., & Leuz, C. (2005). Economic consequences of SEC disclosure regulation: Evidence from the OTC bulletin board. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 39(2), 233–264.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, T. S. (1979). Optimal investment financing decisions and the value of confidentiality. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14(5), 913–924.CrossRef Campbell, T. S. (1979). Optimal investment financing decisions and the value of confidentiality. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 14(5), 913–924.CrossRef
go back to reference Chemmanur, T. J., & Fulghieri, P. (1999). A theory of the going-public decision. The Review of Financial Studies, 12(2), 249–279.CrossRef Chemmanur, T. J., & Fulghieri, P. (1999). A theory of the going-public decision. The Review of Financial Studies, 12(2), 249–279.CrossRef
go back to reference Coates IV., J. C. (2007). The goals and promise of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(1), 91–116.CrossRef Coates IV., J. C. (2007). The goals and promise of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21(1), 91–116.CrossRef
go back to reference Coffee, J. C. (1991). Liquidity versus control: The institutional investor as corporate monitor. Columbia Law Review, 91(6), 1277–1368.CrossRef Coffee, J. C. (1991). Liquidity versus control: The institutional investor as corporate monitor. Columbia Law Review, 91(6), 1277–1368.CrossRef
go back to reference Coller, M., & Yohn, T. L. (1997). Management forecasts and information asymmetry: An examination of bid-ask spreads. Journal of Accounting Research, 35(2), 181–191.CrossRef Coller, M., & Yohn, T. L. (1997). Management forecasts and information asymmetry: An examination of bid-ask spreads. Journal of Accounting Research, 35(2), 181–191.CrossRef
go back to reference Comment, R., & Jarrell, G. A. (1995). Corporate focus and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 37(1), 67–87.CrossRef Comment, R., & Jarrell, G. A. (1995). Corporate focus and stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics, 37(1), 67–87.CrossRef
go back to reference Croci, E., & Del Giudice, A. (2014). Delistings, controlling shareholders and firm performance in Europe. European Financial Management, 20(2), 374–405.CrossRef Croci, E., & Del Giudice, A. (2014). Delistings, controlling shareholders and firm performance in Europe. European Financial Management, 20(2), 374–405.CrossRef
go back to reference DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Rice, E. M. (1984). Going private: Minority freezeouts and stockholder wealth. The Journal of Law and Economics, 27(2), 367–401.CrossRef DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Rice, E. M. (1984). Going private: Minority freezeouts and stockholder wealth. The Journal of Law and Economics, 27(2), 367–401.CrossRef
go back to reference Demirag, I. S. (2015). Short-termism. Wiley Encyclopedia of Management. Demirag, I. S. (2015). Short-termism. Wiley Encyclopedia of Management.
go back to reference Denis, D. J. (1992). Corporate investment decisions and corporate control: Evidence from going-private transactions. Financial Management, 21(3), 80–94.CrossRef Denis, D. J. (1992). Corporate investment decisions and corporate control: Evidence from going-private transactions. Financial Management, 21(3), 80–94.CrossRef
go back to reference Diamond, D. W., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1991). Disclosure, liquidity, and the cost of capital. Journal of Finance, 46(4), 1325–1359.CrossRef Diamond, D. W., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1991). Disclosure, liquidity, and the cost of capital. Journal of Finance, 46(4), 1325–1359.CrossRef
go back to reference Draper, P., & Paudyal, K. (2008). Information asymmetry and bidders’ gains. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 35(3–4), 376–405.CrossRef Draper, P., & Paudyal, K. (2008). Information asymmetry and bidders’ gains. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 35(3–4), 376–405.CrossRef
go back to reference Eckbo, B. E., & Masulis, R. W. (1992). Adverse selection and the rights offer paradox. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(3), 293–332.CrossRef Eckbo, B. E., & Masulis, R. W. (1992). Adverse selection and the rights offer paradox. Journal of Financial Economics, 32(3), 293–332.CrossRef
go back to reference Eckbo, B. E., & Masulis, R. W. (1995). Seasoned equity offerings: A survey, In R. A. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic, & W. T. Ziemba (Ed.), Handbooks in operations research and management science (Vol. 9, Chap. 31, pp. 1017–1072). Amsterdam: North-Holland/Elsevier. Eckbo, B. E., & Masulis, R. W. (1995). Seasoned equity offerings: A survey, In R. A. Jarrow, V. Maksimovic, & W. T. Ziemba (Ed.), Handbooks in operations research and management science (Vol. 9, Chap. 31, pp. 1017–1072). Amsterdam: North-Holland/Elsevier.
go back to reference Edmans, A., Fang, V. W., & Zur, E. (2013). The effect of liquidity on governance. The Review of Financial Studies, 26(6), 1443–1482.CrossRef Edmans, A., Fang, V. W., & Zur, E. (2013). The effect of liquidity on governance. The Review of Financial Studies, 26(6), 1443–1482.CrossRef
go back to reference Engel, E., Hayes, R. M., & Wang, X. (2007). The Sarbanes–Oxley Act and firms’ going-private decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44(1–2), 116–145.CrossRef Engel, E., Hayes, R. M., & Wang, X. (2007). The Sarbanes–Oxley Act and firms’ going-private decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44(1–2), 116–145.CrossRef
go back to reference Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1995). Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal of Finance, 50(1), 131–155.CrossRef Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (1995). Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal of Finance, 50(1), 131–155.CrossRef
go back to reference Fang, V. W., Noe, T. H., & Tice, S. (2009). Stock market liquidity and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 94(1), 150–169.CrossRef Fang, V. W., Noe, T. H., & Tice, S. (2009). Stock market liquidity and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 94(1), 150–169.CrossRef
go back to reference Fazzari, S. M., Hubbard, R. G., Petersen, B. C., Blinder, A. S., & Poterba, J. M. (1988). Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1988(1), 141–206.CrossRef Fazzari, S. M., Hubbard, R. G., Petersen, B. C., Blinder, A. S., & Poterba, J. M. (1988). Financing constraints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1988(1), 141–206.CrossRef
go back to reference Fazzari, S. M., Hubbard, R. G., & Petersen, B. C. (2000). Investment-cash flow sensitivities are useful: A comment on Kaplan and Zingales. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2), 695–705.CrossRef Fazzari, S. M., Hubbard, R. G., & Petersen, B. C. (2000). Investment-cash flow sensitivities are useful: A comment on Kaplan and Zingales. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2), 695–705.CrossRef
go back to reference Fink, J., Fink, K. E., Grullon, G., & Weston, J. P. (2010). What drove the increase in idiosyncratic volatility during the internet boom? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(5), 1253–1278.CrossRef Fink, J., Fink, K. E., Grullon, G., & Weston, J. P. (2010). What drove the increase in idiosyncratic volatility during the internet boom? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45(5), 1253–1278.CrossRef
go back to reference Freeman, R. N. (1987). The association between accounting earnings and security returns for large and small firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 9(2), 195–228.CrossRef Freeman, R. N. (1987). The association between accounting earnings and security returns for large and small firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 9(2), 195–228.CrossRef
go back to reference Gompers, P. A. (1996). Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial Economics, 42(1), 133–156.CrossRef Gompers, P. A. (1996). Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial Economics, 42(1), 133–156.CrossRef
go back to reference Gompers, P. A., Ishii, J., & Metrick, A. (2003). Corporate governance and equity prices. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 107–156.CrossRef Gompers, P. A., Ishii, J., & Metrick, A. (2003). Corporate governance and equity prices. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 107–156.CrossRef
go back to reference Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., & Rajgopal, S. (2005). The economic implications of corporate financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40(1–3), 3–73.CrossRef Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., & Rajgopal, S. (2005). The economic implications of corporate financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40(1–3), 3–73.CrossRef
go back to reference Guo, S., Hotchkiss, E. S., & Song, W. (2011). Do buyouts (still) create value? Journal of Finance, 66(2), 479–517.CrossRef Guo, S., Hotchkiss, E. S., & Song, W. (2011). Do buyouts (still) create value? Journal of Finance, 66(2), 479–517.CrossRef
go back to reference Halling, M., Pagano, M., Randl, O., & Zechner, J. (2008). Where is the market? Evidence from cross-listings in the United States. The Review of Financial Studies, 21(2), 725–761.CrossRef Halling, M., Pagano, M., Randl, O., & Zechner, J. (2008). Where is the market? Evidence from cross-listings in the United States. The Review of Financial Studies, 21(2), 725–761.CrossRef
go back to reference Hansen, R. S. (1988). The demise of the rights issue. The Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 289–309.CrossRef Hansen, R. S. (1988). The demise of the rights issue. The Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 289–309.CrossRef
go back to reference Herman, E. S. (1981). Corporate control, corporate power. New York: Cambridge University Press. Herman, E. S. (1981). Corporate control, corporate power. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Holmstrom, B., & Kaplan, S. N. (2003). The state of US corporate governance: What’s right and what’s wrong? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15(3), 8–20.CrossRef Holmstrom, B., & Kaplan, S. N. (2003). The state of US corporate governance: What’s right and what’s wrong? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15(3), 8–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Ibbotson, R. G., & Jaffe, J. F. (1975). “Hot issue” markets. The Journal of Finance, 30(4), 1027–1042. Ibbotson, R. G., & Jaffe, J. F. (1975). “Hot issue” markets. The Journal of Finance, 30(4), 1027–1042.
go back to reference Jayaraman, S., & Milbourn, T. T. (2011). The role of stock liquidity in executive compensation. The Accounting Review, 87(2), 537–563.CrossRef Jayaraman, S., & Milbourn, T. T. (2011). The role of stock liquidity in executive compensation. The Accounting Review, 87(2), 537–563.CrossRef
go back to reference Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76(2), 323–329. Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76(2), 323–329.
go back to reference Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.CrossRef Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.CrossRef
go back to reference Kamar, E., Karaca-Mandic, P., & Talley, E. (2009). Going-private decisions and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002: A cross-country analysis. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 25(1), 107–133.CrossRef Kamar, E., Karaca-Mandic, P., & Talley, E. (2009). Going-private decisions and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002: A cross-country analysis. The Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 25(1), 107–133.CrossRef
go back to reference Kaplan, S. N. (1989a). The effects of management buyouts on operating performance and value. Journal of Financial Economics, 24(2), 217–254.CrossRef Kaplan, S. N. (1989a). The effects of management buyouts on operating performance and value. Journal of Financial Economics, 24(2), 217–254.CrossRef
go back to reference Kaplan, S. N. (1989b). Management buyouts: Evidence on taxes as a source of value. The Journal of Finance, 44(3), 611–632.CrossRef Kaplan, S. N. (1989b). Management buyouts: Evidence on taxes as a source of value. The Journal of Finance, 44(3), 611–632.CrossRef
go back to reference Kaplan, S. N., & Zingales, L. (1997). Do investment-cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 169–215.CrossRef Kaplan, S. N., & Zingales, L. (1997). Do investment-cash flow sensitivities provide useful measures of financing constraints? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(1), 169–215.CrossRef
go back to reference Kaplan, S. N., & Zingales, L. (2000). Investment-cash flow sensitivities are not valid measures of financing constraints. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2), 707–712.CrossRef Kaplan, S. N., & Zingales, L. (2000). Investment-cash flow sensitivities are not valid measures of financing constraints. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(2), 707–712.CrossRef
go back to reference Kashefi Pour, E., & Lasfer, M. (2013). Why do companies delist voluntarily from the stock market? Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(12), 4850–4860.CrossRef Kashefi Pour, E., & Lasfer, M. (2013). Why do companies delist voluntarily from the stock market? Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(12), 4850–4860.CrossRef
go back to reference Kieschnick, R. L. (1989). Management buyouts of public corporations: An analysis of prior characteristics. In Y. Amihud (Ed.), Leveraged Management Buyouts: Causes and Consequences (pp. 35–59). Homewood: Dow Jones-Irwin. Kieschnick, R. L. (1989). Management buyouts of public corporations: An analysis of prior characteristics. In Y. Amihud (Ed.), Leveraged Management Buyouts: Causes and Consequences (pp. 35–59). Homewood: Dow Jones-Irwin.
go back to reference Kieschnick, R. L. (1998). Free cash flow and stockholder gains in going private transactions revisited. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 25(1–2), 187–202.CrossRef Kieschnick, R. L. (1998). Free cash flow and stockholder gains in going private transactions revisited. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 25(1–2), 187–202.CrossRef
go back to reference Kim, W., & Weisbach, M. S. (2008). Motivations for public equity offers: An international perspective. Journal of Financial Economics, 87(2), 281–307.CrossRef Kim, W., & Weisbach, M. S. (2008). Motivations for public equity offers: An international perspective. Journal of Financial Economics, 87(2), 281–307.CrossRef
go back to reference Kothare, M. (1997). The effects of equity issues on ownership structure and stock liquidity: A comparison of rights and public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 43(1), 131–148.CrossRef Kothare, M. (1997). The effects of equity issues on ownership structure and stock liquidity: A comparison of rights and public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 43(1), 131–148.CrossRef
go back to reference Lehn, K., & Poulsen, A. (1989). Free cash flow and stockholder gains in going private transactions. The Journal of Finance, 44(3), 771–787.CrossRef Lehn, K., & Poulsen, A. (1989). Free cash flow and stockholder gains in going private transactions. The Journal of Finance, 44(3), 771–787.CrossRef
go back to reference Leland, H. E., & Pyle, D. H. (1977). Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation. The Journal of Finance, 32(2), 371–387.CrossRef Leland, H. E., & Pyle, D. H. (1977). Informational asymmetries, financial structure, and financial intermediation. The Journal of Finance, 32(2), 371–387.CrossRef
go back to reference Lerner, J. (1994). Venture capitalists and the decision to go public. Journal of Financial Economics, 35(3), 293–316.CrossRef Lerner, J. (1994). Venture capitalists and the decision to go public. Journal of Financial Economics, 35(3), 293–316.CrossRef
go back to reference Leuz, C. (2007). Was the Sarbanes–Oxley Act of 2002 really this costly? A discussion of evidence from event returns and going-private decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44(1–2), 146–165.CrossRef Leuz, C. (2007). Was the Sarbanes–Oxley Act of 2002 really this costly? A discussion of evidence from event returns and going-private decisions. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 44(1–2), 146–165.CrossRef
go back to reference Leuz, C., Nanda, D., & Wysocki, P. D. (2003). Earnings management and investor protection: An international comparison. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(3), 505–527.CrossRef Leuz, C., Nanda, D., & Wysocki, P. D. (2003). Earnings management and investor protection: An international comparison. Journal of Financial Economics, 69(3), 505–527.CrossRef
go back to reference Loughran, T., Ritter, J. R., & Rydqvist, K. (1994). Initial public offerings: International insights. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 2(2–3), 165–199.CrossRef Loughran, T., Ritter, J. R., & Rydqvist, K. (1994). Initial public offerings: International insights. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 2(2–3), 165–199.CrossRef
go back to reference Lowenstein, L. (1985). Management buyouts. Columbia Law Review, 85(4), 730–784.CrossRef Lowenstein, L. (1985). Management buyouts. Columbia Law Review, 85(4), 730–784.CrossRef
go back to reference Lowry, M. (2003). Why does IPO volume fluctuate so much? Journal of Financial Economics, 67(1), 3–40.CrossRef Lowry, M. (2003). Why does IPO volume fluctuate so much? Journal of Financial Economics, 67(1), 3–40.CrossRef
go back to reference Lucas, D. J., & McDonald, R. L. (1990). Equity issues and stock price dynamics. The Journal of Finance, 45(4), 1019–1043.CrossRef Lucas, D. J., & McDonald, R. L. (1990). Equity issues and stock price dynamics. The Journal of Finance, 45(4), 1019–1043.CrossRef
go back to reference Marosi, A., & Massoud, N. (2007). Why do firms go dark? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(2), 421–442.CrossRef Marosi, A., & Massoud, N. (2007). Why do firms go dark? Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 42(2), 421–442.CrossRef
go back to reference Masulis, R. W., & Thomas, R. S. (2009). Does private equity create wealth? The effects of private equity and derivatives on corporate governance. The University of Chicago Law Review, 76(1), 219–259. Masulis, R. W., & Thomas, R. S. (2009). Does private equity create wealth? The effects of private equity and derivatives on corporate governance. The University of Chicago Law Review, 76(1), 219–259.
go back to reference Maug, E. (1998). Large shareholders as monitors: Is there a trade-off between liquidity and control? The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 65–98.CrossRef Maug, E. (1998). Large shareholders as monitors: Is there a trade-off between liquidity and control? The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 65–98.CrossRef
go back to reference Maupin, R. J., Bidwell, C. M., & Ortegren, A. K. (1984). An empirical investigation of the characteristics of publicly-quoted corporations which change to closely-held ownership through management buyouts. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 11(4), 435–450.CrossRef Maupin, R. J., Bidwell, C. M., & Ortegren, A. K. (1984). An empirical investigation of the characteristics of publicly-quoted corporations which change to closely-held ownership through management buyouts. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 11(4), 435–450.CrossRef
go back to reference Mehran, H., & Peristiani, S. (2010). Financial visibility and the decision to go private. The Review of Financial Studies, 23(2), 519–547.CrossRef Mehran, H., & Peristiani, S. (2010). Financial visibility and the decision to go private. The Review of Financial Studies, 23(2), 519–547.CrossRef
go back to reference Mello, A. S., & Parsons, J. E. (1998). Going public and the ownership structure of the firm. Journal of Financial Economics, 49(1), 79–109.CrossRef Mello, A. S., & Parsons, J. E. (1998). Going public and the ownership structure of the firm. Journal of Financial Economics, 49(1), 79–109.CrossRef
go back to reference Merton, R. C. (1987). A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. The Journal of Finance, 42(3), 483–510.CrossRef Merton, R. C. (1987). A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. The Journal of Finance, 42(3), 483–510.CrossRef
go back to reference Merton, R. C. (1995). Financial innovation and the management and regulation of financial institutions. Journal of Banking & Finance, 19(3–4), 461–481.CrossRef Merton, R. C. (1995). Financial innovation and the management and regulation of financial institutions. Journal of Banking & Finance, 19(3–4), 461–481.CrossRef
go back to reference Metrick, A., & Yasuda, A. (2010). The economics of private equity funds. The Review of Financial Studies, 23(6), 2303–2341.CrossRef Metrick, A., & Yasuda, A. (2010). The economics of private equity funds. The Review of Financial Studies, 23(6), 2303–2341.CrossRef
go back to reference Miller, M. H., & Modigliani, F. (1961). Dividend policy, growth, and the valuation of shares. Journal of Business, 34(4), 411–433.CrossRef Miller, M. H., & Modigliani, F. (1961). Dividend policy, growth, and the valuation of shares. Journal of Business, 34(4), 411–433.CrossRef
go back to reference Mitchell, M. L., & Mulherin, J. H. (1996). The impact of industry shocks on takeover and restructuring activity. Journal of Financial Economics, 41(2), 193–229.CrossRef Mitchell, M. L., & Mulherin, J. H. (1996). The impact of industry shocks on takeover and restructuring activity. Journal of Financial Economics, 41(2), 193–229.CrossRef
go back to reference Muscarella, C. J., & Vetsuypens, M. R. (1990). Efficiency and organizational structure: A study of reverse LBOs. The Journal of Finance, 45(5), 1389–1413.CrossRef Muscarella, C. J., & Vetsuypens, M. R. (1990). Efficiency and organizational structure: A study of reverse LBOs. The Journal of Finance, 45(5), 1389–1413.CrossRef
go back to reference Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(2), 147–175.CrossRef Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(2), 147–175.CrossRef
go back to reference Myhal, P. J. (1990). Some observations on the usual anti-dilution provisions. Canadian Business Law Journal, 17(2), 283–302. Myhal, P. J. (1990). Some observations on the usual anti-dilution provisions. Canadian Business Law Journal, 17(2), 283–302.
go back to reference Opler, T., & Titman, S. (1993). The determinants of leveraged buyout activity: Free cash flow vs. financial distress costs. The Journal of Finance, 48(5), 1985–1999.CrossRef Opler, T., & Titman, S. (1993). The determinants of leveraged buyout activity: Free cash flow vs. financial distress costs. The Journal of Finance, 48(5), 1985–1999.CrossRef
go back to reference Pagano, M., & Röell, A. (1998). The choice of stock ownership structure: Agency costs, monitoring, and the decision to go public. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1), 187–225.CrossRef Pagano, M., & Röell, A. (1998). The choice of stock ownership structure: Agency costs, monitoring, and the decision to go public. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1), 187–225.CrossRef
go back to reference Pagano, M., Panetta, F., & Zingales, L. (1998). Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 27–64.CrossRef Pagano, M., Panetta, F., & Zingales, L. (1998). Why do companies go public? An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance, 53(1), 27–64.CrossRef
go back to reference Pástor, Ľ., & Stambaugh, R. F. (2003). Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. Journal of Political Economy, 111(3), 642–685.CrossRef Pástor, Ľ., & Stambaugh, R. F. (2003). Liquidity risk and expected stock returns. Journal of Political Economy, 111(3), 642–685.CrossRef
go back to reference Perotti, E. C., & Van Oijen, P. (2001). Privatization, political risk and stock market development in emerging economies. Journal of International Money and Finance, 20(1), 43–69.CrossRef Perotti, E. C., & Van Oijen, P. (2001). Privatization, political risk and stock market development in emerging economies. Journal of International Money and Finance, 20(1), 43–69.CrossRef
go back to reference Pettit, R. R., & Singer, R. F. (1985). Small business finance: A research agenda. Financial Management, 14(3), 47–60.CrossRef Pettit, R. R., & Singer, R. F. (1985). Small business finance: A research agenda. Financial Management, 14(3), 47–60.CrossRef
go back to reference Ritter, J. R. (1984). The “hot issue” market of 1980. Journal of Business, 57(2), 215–240.CrossRef Ritter, J. R. (1984). The “hot issue” market of 1980. Journal of Business, 57(2), 215–240.CrossRef
go back to reference Ritter, J. R., & Welch, I. (2002). A review of IPO activity, pricing, and allocations. The Journal of Finance, 57(4), 1795–1828.CrossRef Ritter, J. R., & Welch, I. (2002). A review of IPO activity, pricing, and allocations. The Journal of Finance, 57(4), 1795–1828.CrossRef
go back to reference Roulstone, D. T. (2003). Analyst following and market liquidity. Contemporary Accounting Research, 20(3), 552–578.CrossRef Roulstone, D. T. (2003). Analyst following and market liquidity. Contemporary Accounting Research, 20(3), 552–578.CrossRef
go back to reference Rydqvist, K., & Högholm, K. (1995). Going public in the 1980s: Evidence from Sweden. European Financial Management, 1(3), 287–315.CrossRef Rydqvist, K., & Högholm, K. (1995). Going public in the 1980s: Evidence from Sweden. European Financial Management, 1(3), 287–315.CrossRef
go back to reference Servaes, H. (1994). Do takeover targets overinvest? The Review of Financial Studies, 7(2), 253–277.CrossRef Servaes, H. (1994). Do takeover targets overinvest? The Review of Financial Studies, 7(2), 253–277.CrossRef
go back to reference Shah, S., & Thakor, A. V. (1988). Private versus public ownership: Investment, ownership distribution, and optimality. The Journal of Finance, 43(1), 41–59.CrossRef Shah, S., & Thakor, A. V. (1988). Private versus public ownership: Investment, ownership distribution, and optimality. The Journal of Finance, 43(1), 41–59.CrossRef
go back to reference Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management’s buyouts as a response to market pressure. In A. Auerbach (Ed.), Mergers and acquisitions (pp. 87–103). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management’s buyouts as a response to market pressure. In A. Auerbach (Ed.), Mergers and acquisitions (pp. 87–103). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783.CrossRef Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. The Journal of Finance, 52(2), 737–783.CrossRef
go back to reference Singh, A. K. (1997). Layoffs and underwritten rights offers. Journal of Financial Economics, 43(1), 105–130.CrossRef Singh, A. K. (1997). Layoffs and underwritten rights offers. Journal of Financial Economics, 43(1), 105–130.CrossRef
go back to reference Slovin, M. B., Sushka, M. E., & Lai, K. W. (2000). Alternative flotation methods, adverse selection, and ownership structure: Evidence from seasoned equity issuance in the UK. Journal of Financial Economics, 57(2), 157–190.CrossRef Slovin, M. B., Sushka, M. E., & Lai, K. W. (2000). Alternative flotation methods, adverse selection, and ownership structure: Evidence from seasoned equity issuance in the UK. Journal of Financial Economics, 57(2), 157–190.CrossRef
go back to reference Smith Jr., C. W. (1977). Alternative methods for raising capital: Rights versus underwritten offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(3), 273–307.CrossRef Smith Jr., C. W. (1977). Alternative methods for raising capital: Rights versus underwritten offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 5(3), 273–307.CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, A. J. (1990). Corporate ownership structure and performance: The case of management buyouts. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(1), 143–164.CrossRef Smith, A. J. (1990). Corporate ownership structure and performance: The case of management buyouts. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(1), 143–164.CrossRef
go back to reference Stein, J. C. (1989). Efficient capital markets, inefficient firms: A model of myopic corporate behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4), 655–669.CrossRef Stein, J. C. (1989). Efficient capital markets, inefficient firms: A model of myopic corporate behavior. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(4), 655–669.CrossRef
go back to reference Stoughton, N. M., & Zechner, J. (1998). IPO-mechanisms, monitoring and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 49(1), 45–77.CrossRef Stoughton, N. M., & Zechner, J. (1998). IPO-mechanisms, monitoring and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 49(1), 45–77.CrossRef
go back to reference Strömberg, P. (2007). The new demography of private equity. Swedish Institute for Financial Research, Stockholm School of Economics, CEPR and NBER, working paper. Strömberg, P. (2007). The new demography of private equity. Swedish Institute for Financial Research, Stockholm School of Economics, CEPR and NBER, working paper.
go back to reference Subrahmanyam, A., & Titman, S. (1999). The going-public decision and the development of financial markets. The Journal of Finance, 54(3), 1045–1082.CrossRef Subrahmanyam, A., & Titman, S. (1999). The going-public decision and the development of financial markets. The Journal of Finance, 54(3), 1045–1082.CrossRef
go back to reference Verrecchia, R. E. (1983). Discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 5, 179–194.CrossRef Verrecchia, R. E. (1983). Discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 5, 179–194.CrossRef
go back to reference Verrecchia, R. E. (1990). Information quality and discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 12(4), 365–380.CrossRef Verrecchia, R. E. (1990). Information quality and discretionary disclosure. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 12(4), 365–380.CrossRef
go back to reference Weston, J. F., Mitchell, M. L., & Mulherin, J. H. (2004). Takeovers, restructuring, and corporate governance (4th ed.). Upper Saddle River: Pearson-Prentice Hall. Weston, J. F., Mitchell, M. L., & Mulherin, J. H. (2004). Takeovers, restructuring, and corporate governance (4th ed.). Upper Saddle River: Pearson-Prentice Hall.
go back to reference Yosha, O. (1995). Information disclosure costs and the choice of financing source. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 4(1), 3–20.CrossRef Yosha, O. (1995). Information disclosure costs and the choice of financing source. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 4(1), 3–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Zingales, L. (1994). The value of the voting right: A study of the Milan stock exchange experience. The Review of Financial Studies, 7(1), 125–148.CrossRef Zingales, L. (1994). The value of the voting right: A study of the Milan stock exchange experience. The Review of Financial Studies, 7(1), 125–148.CrossRef
go back to reference Zingales, L. (1995). Insider ownership and the decision to go public. The Review of Economic Studies, 62(3), 425–448.CrossRef Zingales, L. (1995). Insider ownership and the decision to go public. The Review of Economic Studies, 62(3), 425–448.CrossRef
go back to reference Zingales, L. (2007). Is the US capital market losing its competitive edge? European Corporate Governance Institute. Finance Working Paper n. 192. Zingales, L. (2007). Is the US capital market losing its competitive edge? European Corporate Governance Institute. Finance Working Paper n. 192.
Metadata
Title
Facts, Figures and Theory
Author
Ottorino Morresi
Copyright Year
2018
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-95049-5_1