Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2018

05-07-2018

Fast, frugal and correct? An experimental study on the influence of time scarcity and quantity of information on the voter decision making process

Authors: Michal Tóth, Roman Chytilek

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2018

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Classical theories of political representation claim that high levels of political knowledge and awareness across the electorate are crucial for a well-functioning democracy. In real life, though, the actual amount of political information possessed by voters is small and unevenly distributed. In addition, electoral decision making is complex and often characterized by severe time pressure. This study therefore experimentally tests the theoretical framework of “fast and frugal” voters and the “less-is-more effect” (Gigerenzer and Goldstein in Psychol Rev 103(4):650–669, 1996), which expects that in some instances low levels of political knowledge may actually result in equally good or even better outcomes than in the case of well-informed decisions. It is hence assumed that employing specific cognitive shortcuts can help voters make good and quick decisions, even with a lack of information. We have used a laboratory experiment to create an environment characterized by severe time pressure that allowed for only shallow information search and limited comparisons across alternatives. Subjects were able to base their decisions only on a small number of criteria operationalized by candidates’ positions on current political issues with various levels of perceived salience. Voters appear to simplify decision making by focusing mainly on those policy attitudes they consider important. Consequently, it seems that shifting the decision-making strategy from accuracy to efficiency has no effect on the final outcome.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
According to a survey made by the agency STEM/MARK, one-quarter of voters participating in elections to the Czech Republic’s Chamber of Deputies in 2013 decided at the last minute. Seventy-eight percent of them, who decided to participate in the election only a week beforehand, chose their candidates during that week or in the voting booth (STEM/MARK 2013).
 
2
Kuklinski and Quirk (2000b), nevertheless, argue that such a decision-making mechanism can sufficiently operate in various domains of life, but that it is unsuited for politics.
 
3
“Correct vote” is not the only way of evaluating whether a decision fits that definition or not. For example, Bartels (1996) and Delli Carpini and Keeter (1996) also focused on the differences between decisions made by more and less informed voters. They, however, did not use the term “correct decision”.
 
4
Baum and Jamison (2016) employed the term “consistent” voting because they strive to avoid the normative connotations ascribed to the term “correct vote”.
 
5
Our assumptions are based on a classical spatial model claiming that the relationships between political actors can be represented by proximity and distance. The basis for political success in this model is the smallest possible distance of the candidate from the voters (Downs 1957). However, it is important to note that it’s not the only way to model spatial political preferences. Another approach is represented by so-called directional models, which work not only with positions of voters and candidates, but they include also the status quo referential point. Such models suggest that voters’ utility of choice is not given by the absolute distance between voters’ and candidates’ positions, but by their directions, determined by the referential point (whether both voter and candidate are on the same side of the simple, dichotomous, policy space) (Claasen 2007). The most prominent type of directional models was introduced by Rabinowitz and Macdonald (1989). They propose that the utility associated with a choice depends on the intensity of a voter’s and a candidate’s relationship to the referential point (the further they both are in the same direction to the referential point, the larger is the voter’s utility).
 
6
All texts in the experiment were originally in Czech. For the purposes of this article they were translated into English.
 
7
See “Appendix” for the sample of possible candidate positions on the issue of involvement of the Czech Republic in the fight against ISIS. Full texts of other issues are available as electronic supplementary material (Online Appendix).
 
8
The experiment did not follow what would happen if even greater distances between the voter and the candidate were possible. We assume that such a treatment probably would raise the likelihood of casting a correct vote, since the greater attitudinal distance between the candidates would make it easier for the voter to do so. When designing the experiment, however, we had to take into consideration several aspects. First, we had to make sure that the selection of the correct candidate was not the result of chance, so we worked with up to three candidates. At the same time, we were not able to extend the range of the scale to more than five possible positions because the differences between the verbal expressions of the positions would be too small, which could cause an unclear decision-making situation and also jeopardize the reliability of the measurement. Since we wanted to ensure the same pattern of candidate placement on each issue and use a five-degree scale, we could not work with more extreme positions.
 
9
Differences in average salience of each issue between experimental groups were not statistically significant (the only exception was the “pensions” issue).
 
10
We also checked the assumption that on the most salient issues (the top two), voters take the most extreme positions (1 or 5). We found that for the time-constrained group the assumption holds true in 80% of the cases, and in 74.3% of the cases for the group without a time constraint. The positions of the candidates were then modeled according to the predesigned pattern described in Sect. 7 above.
 
11
We also checked for multicollinearity. Tests shows that multicollinearity is not present in our data (tolerance = 0.258, VIF = 3.874). In addition, we checked group characteristics in different dimensions (sex, age, sophistication) to ensure that random assignment of participants to each experimental condition worked. The results indicate that the two groups do not differ significantly along those dimensions.
 
Literature
go back to reference Baldassarri, D. (2013). The simple art of voting: The cognitive shortcuts of Italian voters. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Baldassarri, D. (2013). The simple art of voting: The cognitive shortcuts of Italian voters. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Bartels, L. (1996). Uninformed votes: Information effects in presidential elections. American Journal of Political Science, 40(14), 194–230.CrossRef Bartels, L. (1996). Uninformed votes: Information effects in presidential elections. American Journal of Political Science, 40(14), 194–230.CrossRef
go back to reference Baum, M., & Jamison, A. (2016). The Oprah effect: How soft news helps inattentive citizens vote consistently. The Journal of Politics, 68(4), 946–959.CrossRef Baum, M., & Jamison, A. (2016). The Oprah effect: How soft news helps inattentive citizens vote consistently. The Journal of Politics, 68(4), 946–959.CrossRef
go back to reference Berelson, B., Lazarsfeld, P. F., & McPhee, W. N. (1954). Voting: A study of opinion formation in a presidential campaign (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Berelson, B., Lazarsfeld, P. F., & McPhee, W. N. (1954). Voting: A study of opinion formation in a presidential campaign (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Chytilek, R., & Eibl, O. (2011). České politické strany v politickém prostoru. Sociologický časopis, 47(1), 61–88. Chytilek, R., & Eibl, O. (2011). České politické strany v politickém prostoru. Sociologický časopis, 47(1), 61–88.
go back to reference Claasen, R. L. (2007). Ideology and evaluation in an experimental setting: Comparing the proximity and the directional models. Political Research Quarterly, 60(2), 263–273.CrossRef Claasen, R. L. (2007). Ideology and evaluation in an experimental setting: Comparing the proximity and the directional models. Political Research Quarterly, 60(2), 263–273.CrossRef
go back to reference Converse, P. (1964). The nature of belief systems in mass publics. In D. Apter (Ed.), Ideology and discontent. New York: Free Press. Converse, P. (1964). The nature of belief systems in mass publics. In D. Apter (Ed.), Ideology and discontent. New York: Free Press.
go back to reference Czerlinski, J., Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. (1999). How good are simple heuristics? In G. Gigerenzer & P. Todd (Eds.), Simple heuristics that make us smart. New York: Oxford University Press. Czerlinski, J., Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. (1999). How good are simple heuristics? In G. Gigerenzer & P. Todd (Eds.), Simple heuristics that make us smart. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Dahl, R. A. (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press. Dahl, R. A. (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and opposition. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Delli Carpini, M. X., & Keeter, S. (1996). What Americans know about politics and why it matters. New Haven: Yale University Press. Delli Carpini, M. X., & Keeter, S. (1996). What Americans know about politics and why it matters. New Haven: Yale University Press.
go back to reference Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Boston: Addison-Wesley. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Boston: Addison-Wesley.
go back to reference Druckman, J. N. (2005). Does political information matter? Political Communication, 22(4), 515–519.CrossRef Druckman, J. N. (2005). Does political information matter? Political Communication, 22(4), 515–519.CrossRef
go back to reference Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef
go back to reference Fiske, S., & Taylor, S. (2013). Social cognition: From brains to culture (1st ed.). Los Angeles: Sage.CrossRef Fiske, S., & Taylor, S. (2013). Social cognition: From brains to culture (1st ed.). Los Angeles: Sage.CrossRef
go back to reference Fournier, P., Blais, A., Nadeau, R., Gidengil, E., & Nevitte, N. (2003). Issue importance and performance voting. Political Behavior, 25(1), 51–67.CrossRef Fournier, P., Blais, A., Nadeau, R., Gidengil, E., & Nevitte, N. (2003). Issue importance and performance voting. Political Behavior, 25(1), 51–67.CrossRef
go back to reference Gigerenzer, G. (2001). The adaptive toolbox. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Gigerenzer, G. (2001). The adaptive toolbox. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality. Psychological Review, 103(4), 650–669.CrossRef Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality. Psychological Review, 103(4), 650–669.CrossRef
go back to reference Graefe, A., & Armstrong, S. (2010). Predicting elections from the most important issue: A test of the take-the-best heuristic. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 25(1), 41–48.CrossRef Graefe, A., & Armstrong, S. (2010). Predicting elections from the most important issue: A test of the take-the-best heuristic. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 25(1), 41–48.CrossRef
go back to reference Graefe, A., & Armstrong, S. (2014). Forecasts of the 2012 US presidential election based on candidates’ perceived competence in handling the most important issue. Political Science Research and Methods, 2(1), 141–149.CrossRef Graefe, A., & Armstrong, S. (2014). Forecasts of the 2012 US presidential election based on candidates’ perceived competence in handling the most important issue. Political Science Research and Methods, 2(1), 141–149.CrossRef
go back to reference Holbrook, A. L., Berent, M. K., Krosnick, J. A., Visser, P. S., & Boninger, D. S. (2005). Attitude importance and the accumulation of attitude-relevant knowledge in memory. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 88(5), 749–769.CrossRef Holbrook, A. L., Berent, M. K., Krosnick, J. A., Visser, P. S., & Boninger, D. S. (2005). Attitude importance and the accumulation of attitude-relevant knowledge in memory. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 88(5), 749–769.CrossRef
go back to reference Iyengar, S., Hahn, K. S., Krosnick, J. A., & Walker, J. (2008). Selective exposure to campaign communication: The role of anticipated agreement and issue public membership. The Journal of Politics, 70(1), 186–200.CrossRef Iyengar, S., Hahn, K. S., Krosnick, J. A., & Walker, J. (2008). Selective exposure to campaign communication: The role of anticipated agreement and issue public membership. The Journal of Politics, 70(1), 186–200.CrossRef
go back to reference Junn, J. (1991). Participation and political knowledge. In W. Crotty (Ed.), Political participation and American democracy. New York: Greenwood Press. Junn, J. (1991). Participation and political knowledge. In W. Crotty (Ed.), Political participation and American democracy. New York: Greenwood Press.
go back to reference Knight, K. (1985). Ideology in the 1980 election: Ideological sophistication does matter. The Journal of Politics, 47(3), 828–853.CrossRef Knight, K. (1985). Ideology in the 1980 election: Ideological sophistication does matter. The Journal of Politics, 47(3), 828–853.CrossRef
go back to reference Krosnick, J. A. (1990). Government policy and citizen passion: A study of issue publics in contemporary America. Political Behavior, 12(1), 59–92.CrossRef Krosnick, J. A. (1990). Government policy and citizen passion: A study of issue publics in contemporary America. Political Behavior, 12(1), 59–92.CrossRef
go back to reference Krosnick, J. A., & Milburn, M. A. (1990). Psychological determinants of political opinionation. Social Cognition, 8(1), 49–72.CrossRef Krosnick, J. A., & Milburn, M. A. (1990). Psychological determinants of political opinionation. Social Cognition, 8(1), 49–72.CrossRef
go back to reference Kuklinski, J., & Quirk, P. (2000a). A cognitive-sciences perspective: Hard wiring, evolution, and the tasks of citizenship. In A. Lupia, M. Mccubbins, & S. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason. New York: Cambridge University Press. Kuklinski, J., & Quirk, P. (2000a). A cognitive-sciences perspective: Hard wiring, evolution, and the tasks of citizenship. In A. Lupia, M. Mccubbins, & S. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Kuklinski, J., & Quirk, P. (2000b). Reconsidering the rational public: Cognition, heuristics and mass opinion. In A. Lupia, M. Mccubbins, & S. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason. New York: Cambridge University Press. Kuklinski, J., & Quirk, P. (2000b). Reconsidering the rational public: Cognition, heuristics and mass opinion. In A. Lupia, M. Mccubbins, & S. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Lanoue, D. (1992). One that made a difference: Cognitive consistency, political knowledge, and the 1980 presidential debate. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 56(2), 168–184.CrossRef Lanoue, D. (1992). One that made a difference: Cognitive consistency, political knowledge, and the 1980 presidential debate. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 56(2), 168–184.CrossRef
go back to reference Lau, R., & Redlawsk, D. (1997). Voting correctly. The American Political Science Review, 91(3), 585–598.CrossRef Lau, R., & Redlawsk, D. (1997). Voting correctly. The American Political Science Review, 91(3), 585–598.CrossRef
go back to reference Lau, R., & Redlawsk, D. (2006). How voters decide: Information processing during election campaigns. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Lau, R., & Redlawsk, D. (2006). How voters decide: Information processing during election campaigns. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Laver, M. (2001). Position and salience in the policies of political actors. In M. Laver (Ed.), Estimating the policy positions of political actors. London: Routledge. Laver, M. (2001). Position and salience in the policies of political actors. In M. Laver (Ed.), Estimating the policy positions of political actors. London: Routledge.
go back to reference Lupia, A., & Mccubbins, M. (1998). The democratic dilemma: Can citizens learn what they need to know? (1st ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lupia, A., & Mccubbins, M. (1998). The democratic dilemma: Can citizens learn what they need to know? (1st ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Martignon, L. (2001). Comparing fast and frugal heuristics and optimal models. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Martignon, L. (2001). Comparing fast and frugal heuristics and optimal models. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference McGregor, R. M. (2013). Measuring “correct voting” using comparative manifestos project data. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion, 23(1), 1–26.CrossRef McGregor, R. M. (2013). Measuring “correct voting” using comparative manifestos project data. Journal of Elections, Public Opinion, 23(1), 1–26.CrossRef
go back to reference Page, B. I., & Shapiro, R. Y. (1992). The rational public: fifty years of trends in Americans’ policy preferences (p. 1992). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef Page, B. I., & Shapiro, R. Y. (1992). The rational public: fifty years of trends in Americans’ policy preferences (p. 1992). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Payne, J., & Bettman, J. (2001). Preferential choice and adaptive strategy use. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Payne, J., & Bettman, J. (2001). Preferential choice and adaptive strategy use. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Payne, J., Bettman, J., & Johnson, E. (1993). The adaptive decision maker. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Payne, J., Bettman, J., & Johnson, E. (1993). The adaptive decision maker. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Popkin, S. (1994). The reasoning voter: Communication and persuasion in presidential campaigns (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Popkin, S. (1994). The reasoning voter: Communication and persuasion in presidential campaigns (2nd ed.). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Rabinowitz, G., & Macdonald, S. (1989). A directional theory of issue voting. American Political Science Review, 83(1), 93–121.CrossRef Rabinowitz, G., & Macdonald, S. (1989). A directional theory of issue voting. American Political Science Review, 83(1), 93–121.CrossRef
go back to reference Redlawsk, D. (2004). What voters do: Information search during election campaigns. Political Psychology, 25(4), 595–610.CrossRef Redlawsk, D. (2004). What voters do: Information search during election campaigns. Political Psychology, 25(4), 595–610.CrossRef
go back to reference Rieskamp, J., & Hoffrage, U. (1999). When do people use simple heuristics, and how can we tell? In G. Gigerenzer & P. Todd (Eds.), Simple heuristics that make us smart. New York: Oxford University Press. Rieskamp, J., & Hoffrage, U. (1999). When do people use simple heuristics, and how can we tell? In G. Gigerenzer & P. Todd (Eds.), Simple heuristics that make us smart. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Simon, H. (1957). Rational choice and the structure of environments. Psychological Review, 63(2), 129–138.CrossRef Simon, H. (1957). Rational choice and the structure of environments. Psychological Review, 63(2), 129–138.CrossRef
go back to reference Todd, P. (2001). Fast and frugal heuristics for environmentally bounded minds. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Todd, P. (2001). Fast and frugal heuristics for environmentally bounded minds. In G. Gigerenzer & R. Selten (Eds.), Bounded rationality: The adaptive toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
go back to reference Tomz, M., & Van Houweling, R. P. (2008). Candidate positioning and voter choice. American Political Science Review, 102(03), 303–318.CrossRef Tomz, M., & Van Houweling, R. P. (2008). Candidate positioning and voter choice. American Political Science Review, 102(03), 303–318.CrossRef
go back to reference Zaller, J. (1992). The nature and origins of mass opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Zaller, J. (1992). The nature and origins of mass opinion. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Fast, frugal and correct? An experimental study on the influence of time scarcity and quantity of information on the voter decision making process
Authors
Michal Tóth
Roman Chytilek
Publication date
05-07-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2018
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-018-0587-4

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2018

Public Choice 1-2/2018 Go to the issue