Skip to main content
Top
Published in:
Cover of the book

Open Access 2017 | Supplement | Chapter

2. GDP and GDP Per Head

Author : Leandro Prados de la Escosura

Published in: Spanish Economic Growth, 1850–2015

Publisher: Springer International Publishing

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
download
DOWNLOAD
print
PRINT
insite
SEARCH
loading …

Abstract

Modern economic growth is defined by the sustained improvement in GDP per head. From 1850 to 2015 while population trebled, real GDP per head in Spain experienced nearly
Modern economic growth is defined by the sustained improvement in GDP per head. From 1850 to 2015 while population trebled, real GDP per head in Spain experienced nearly a 16-fold increase, growing at an annual rate of 1.7% (Fig. 2.1 and Table 2.1). GDP growth was intensive, that is, driven by the advance in GDP per person, but for exceptional periods of Civil War, Depression, and Recession (Fig. 2.2). Such an improvement took place at an uneven pace. Per capita GDP grew at 0.7% over 1850–1950, doubling its initial level. During the next quarter of a century, the Golden Age, its pace accelerated more than sevenfold so, by 1974, per capita income was 3.6 times higher than in 1950. Although the economy decelerated from 1974 onwards, and its rate of growth per head shrank to one-half that of the Golden Age, per capita GDP more than doubled between 1974 and 2007. The Great Recession (2008–2013) shrank per capita income by 11%, but, by 2015, its level was still 83% higher than at the time of Spain’s EU accession (1985).
Table 2.1
Growth of GDP and its components, 1850–2015 (%) (average yearly logarithmic rates)
 
GDP
Per Capita GDP
Population
1850–2015
2.4
1.7
0.7
Panel A
1850–1950
1.3
0.7
0.6
1950–1974
6.3
5.3
1.0
1974–2007
3.3
2.5
0.7
2007–2015
–0.5
–0.8
0.3
Panel B
1850–1883
1.7
1.3
0.5
1883–1920
1.2
0.6
0.6
1920–1929
3.8
2.8
1.0
1929–1950
0.0
–0.9
0.9
1950–1958
5.8
5.0
0.8
1958–1974
6.5
5.5
1.1
1974–1984
2.2
1.4
0.8
1984–1992
4.5
4.2
0.3
1992–2007
3.3
2.4
1.0
2007–2013
–1.4
–1.9
0.5
2013–2015
2.4
2.6
–0.2
Panel C
1850–1855
2.6
2.1
0.6
1855–1866
1.0
0.4
0.6
1866–1873
3.2
2.9
0.2
1873–1883
1.1
0.6
0.5
1883–1892
0.8
0.6
0.3
1892–1901
1.3
0.7
0.6
1901–1913
1.2
0.5
0.7
1913–1918
0.3
–0.6
0.9
1918–1929
3.9
3.1
0.9
1929–1935
0.0
–1.5
1.5
1935–1939
–6.6
–6.9
0.4
1939–1944
4.9
4.8
0.1
1944–1950
0.2
–1.0
1.2
Different long swings can be distinguished in which growth rates deviate from the long-run trend as a result of economic policies, access to international markets, and technological change. Growth rates, measured as average annual logarithmic rates of variation, are provided in Table 2.1 for main phases of economic performance (Panel A) and long swings (Panel B). A further breakdown into short cycles is presented for 1850–1950 (Panel C).
During the first long swing, 1850–1883, the rate of growth of product per person was well above the 1850–1950 average. Institutional reforms that brought higher economic freedom seem to lie beneath the significant growth experienced during these three decades (Prados de la Escosura 2016). Opening up to international trade and foreign capital made it possible to break the close connection between investment and savings and contributed to the economic growth (Prados de la Escosura 2010). It is worth stressing that, contrary to common economic wisdom, robust economic performance took place in a context of persistent political instability which included the 1854 liberal uprising and the 1868 Glorious Revolution. This suggests that an improved definition and enforcement of property rights and openness to goods and ideas contributed to offset political turmoil and social unrest.
Growth slowed down between the early 1880s and 1920s. Restrictions on both domestic and external competition help explain sluggish growth during the Restauración (1875–1923), despite the fact that institutional stability should have provided a favourable environment for investment and growth (Fraile Balbín 1991, 1998). Increasing tariff protection (Tena Junguito 1999), together with exclusion from the prevailing international monetary system, the gold standard, may have represented a major obstacle to Spain’s integration in the international economy (Martín-Aceña 1993; Bordo and Rockoff 1996). The Cuban War of Independence, despite the already weakened economic links between the metropolis and its colony, caused significant macroeconomic instability that brought forward the fall of the peseta and increased Spain’s economic isolation (Prados de la Escosura 2010). Macroeconomic instability, together with a ‘sudden stop’, reduced capital inflows leading to the depreciation of the peseta (Martín-Aceña 1993; Prados de la Escosura 2010) that, in turn, increased migration costs and reduced the outward flow of labour (Sánchez-Alonso 2000). Cuban independence had little direct economic impact on Spain’s economy but a deep indirect one, as the intensification of protectionist and isolationist tendencies in the early twentieth century seem to be its political outcome (Fraile Balbín and Escribano 1998). World War I hardly brought any economic progress and GDP per head shrank, a result in stark contradiction with the conventional stress on the war stimulating effects on growth. 1
The 1920s represented the period of most intense growth prior to 1950. The hypothesis that Government intervention, through trade protectionism, regulation, and investment in infrastructure, was a driver of growth has been widely accepted (Velarde 1969). The emphasis on tariff protectionism tends to neglect, however, that Spain opened up to international capital during the 1920s, which allowed the purchase of capital goods and raw materialsraw materials and, hence, contributed to growth acceleration.
A fourth long swing took place between 1929 and 1950, which includes the Great Depression, the Civil War, and post-war autarkic policies, is defined by economic stagnation and shrinking GDP per head. The impact of the Depression, measured by the contraction in real GDP per head, extended in Spain, as in the USA, until 1933, with a 12% fall (against 31% in the USA), lasting longer than in the UK (where it ended in 1931 and real per capita GDP per head shrank by 7%) and Germany (1932 and 17% decline, respectively), but less than in Italy (1934 and 9% contraction) and France (1935 and 13% fall). Thus, the Depression, with GDP per head falling at −3.1% annually (−1.5% for absolute GDP), was milder than in the USA but similar in intensity to Western Europe’s average (Maddison Project 2013), a finding that challenges the view of a weaker impact due to Spain’s relative international isolation and backwardness. The Civil War (1936–1939) prevented Spain from joining the postpost-Depression recovery and resulted in a severe contraction of economic activity (31% drop in real per capita income between levels in 1935 and the 1938 trough) that, nonetheless, did not reach the magnitude of World War II impact on main belligerent countries of continental Western Europe (in Austria, the Netherlands, France, and Italy per capita income shrank by half and in Germany by two-thirds) (Maddison Project 2013). 2
The weak recovery of the post-World War years stands out in the international context. Spain’s economy did not reach its pre-war GDP per head peak level (1929) until 1954 (1950 in absolute terms) and that of private consumption per head until 1956. In contrast, it only took an average of 6 years to return to the pre-war levels in Western Europe (1951). 3 It is true that warring countries surrounded post-Civil War Spain (Velarde 1993), but the fact that its economy only grew at a rate of 0.2% yearly between 1944 and 1950 suggests a sluggish recovery after a comparatively mild contraction.
In the search for explanations, the destruction of physical capital does not appear to be a convincing one as it was about the Western European average during World War II (around 8% of the existing stock of capital in 1935), although its concentration on productive capital (especially transport equipment) meant that levels of destruction caused by the conflict in Spain were far from negligible (Prados de la Escosura and Rosés 2010). However, exile after the Civil War and, possibly to a larger extent, internal exile resulting from political repression of Franco’s dictatorship, meant the loss of a considerable amount of Spain’s limited human capital (Núñez 2003; Ortega and Silvestre 2006). 4 Thus, it can be put forward the hypothesis that the larger loss of human capital vis-à-vis physical capital contributed to the delayed reconstruction (Prados de la Escosura 2007).
The change in trend that began after 1950 ushered in an exceptional phase of rapid growth lasting until 1974. During the 1950s, though, industrialization in Spain was largely dependent on internal demand. Import volatility rendered investment risky and tended to penalize capital accumulation, while inflows of foreign capital and new technology were restricted. However, increasing confidence in the viability of Franco’s dictatorship after the US—Spain military and technological cooperation agreements (1953), together with the regime’s moderate economic reforms, favoured investment and innovation contributing to accelerated economic growth (Calvo-González 2007; Prados de la Escosura et al. 2012).
An institutional reform initiated with the 1959 Stabilization and Liberalization Plan, a response to the exhaustion of the inward-looking development strategy, set policies that favoured the allocation of resources along comparative advantage and allowed sustained and faster growth during the 1960s and early 1970s. 5 Without the Stabilization and Liberalization Plan, per capita GDP would have been significantly lower at the time of Franco’s death, in 1975. However, without the moderate reforms of the 1950s and the subsequent economic growth, it seems unlikely the Stabilization Plan would have succeeded (Prados de la Escosura et al. 2012). This view challenges the widespread perception of the first two decades of Franco’s dictatorship as a homogeneous autarchic era and the 1959 Stabilization and Liberalization Plan as a major discontinuity between autarky and the market economy.
The oil shocks of the 1970s happened at the time of Spain’s transition from dictatorship to democracy that brought with it further opening up and economic liberalization. During the transition decade (1974–1984), GDP growth rate fell to one-third of that achieved over 1958–1974, and to one-fourth when measured in per capita terms. Was the slowdown exogenous, a result of the international crisis? Did it derive from the Francoism legacy of an economy still sheltered from international competition? Or was the outcome of the new democratic authorities’ policies? Answering these questions represents a challenge to researchers. Accession to the European Union heralded more than three decades of absolute and per capita growth that came to a halt with the Great Recession. Again, the deeper contraction and weaker recovery calls for investigation on the underlying foundations of the 1985–2007 expansion.
Notes
1.
Cf. Roldán and García Delgado (1973) for the established view on the impact of the Great War on Spain.
 
2.
Actually, at the trough during the Civil War (1938) Spain’s GDP per head was equal to that of 1905, while the World War II trough brought Italy, Germany, and France’s back to 1880, 1886, and 1891, respectively (Maddison Project, 2013. See Bolt and van Zanden 2014, for a presentation of this collaborative project).
 
3.
Belgium, the Netherlands, and France did so in 1949, Austria and Italy in 1950, with Germany (1954) and Greece (1956), the exceptions.
 
4.
Regarding interior and exterior exile cf. López (1991, 1996) and Plá Brugat (1994, 1999).
 
5.
It is worth pointing out interesting similarities between the 1959 Stabilization Plan and the Washington Consensus, including measures conducive to trade and capital account liberalization, macroeconomic policies to reduce inflation and the size of the fiscal imbalances, and other reforms to protect private property rights and to reduce the activity of the government (Williamson 1990; Fischer 2003; Schleifer 2009; Edwards 2009).
 
Open Access This chapter is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​), which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license and indicate if changes were made.
The images or other third party material in this chapter are included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the chapter’s Creative Commons license and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.
Literature
go back to reference Bolt, J., and J.L. Van Zanden. 2014. The Maddison Project: Collaborative Research on Historical National Accounts. Economic History Review 67 (3): 627–651. Bolt, J., and J.L. Van Zanden. 2014. The Maddison Project: Collaborative Research on Historical National Accounts. Economic History Review 67 (3): 627–651.
go back to reference Bordo, M.D., and H. Rockoff 1996. The Gold Standard as a ‘Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval’. Journal of Economic History 56: 389–428. Bordo, M.D., and H. Rockoff 1996. The Gold Standard as a ‘Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval’. Journal of Economic History 56: 389–428.
go back to reference Calvo González, O. 2007. American Military Interests and Economic Confidence in Spain under the Franco Dictatorship. Journal of Economic History 67 (3): 740–767. Calvo González, O. 2007. American Military Interests and Economic Confidence in Spain under the Franco Dictatorship. Journal of Economic History 67 (3): 740–767.
go back to reference Edwards, S. 2009. Forty Years of Latin Americas Economic Development: From the Alliance for Progress to the Washington Consensus. NBER Working Papers 15190. Edwards, S. 2009. Forty Years of Latin Americas Economic Development: From the Alliance for Progress to the Washington Consensus. NBER Working Papers 15190.
go back to reference Fischer, S. 2003. Globalization and its Challenges: The Richard T. Ely Lecture. American Economic Review 93 (2): 1–30. Fischer, S. 2003. Globalization and its Challenges: The Richard T. Ely Lecture. American Economic Review 93 (2): 1–30.
go back to reference Fraile Balbín, P. 1998. La retórica contra la competencia en España (1875–1975). Madrid: Fundación Argentaria/Visor. Fraile Balbín, P. 1998. La retórica contra la competencia en España (1875–1975). Madrid: Fundación Argentaria/Visor.
go back to reference Fraile Balbín, P., and A. Escribano. 1998. The Spanish 1898 Disaster: The Drift Toward, National-Protectionism. In The Costs and Benefits of European Imperialism from the Conquest of Ceuta, 1415, to the Treaty of Lusaka, 1974, Revista de Historia Económica, ed. P.K. O’Brien and L. Prados de la Escosura, 265–290. (special issue) 16. Fraile Balbín, P., and A. Escribano. 1998. The Spanish 1898 Disaster: The Drift Toward, National-Protectionism. In The Costs and Benefits of European Imperialism from the Conquest of Ceuta, 1415, to the Treaty of Lusaka, 1974, Revista de Historia Económica, ed. P.K. O’Brien and L. Prados de la Escosura, 265–290. (special issue) 16.
go back to reference Fraile, P. 1991. Industrialización y grupos de presión. La economía política de la protección en España, 1900–1950, Madrid: Alianza. Fraile, P. 1991. Industrialización y grupos de presión. La economía política de la protección en España, 1900–1950, Madrid: Alianza.
go back to reference López García, S.M. 1991. La organización de la investigación científica y técnica tras la Guerra Civil: contrastes y similitudes con los logros de las primeras décadas del siglo XX. Actas del Encuentro de Historia Económica. Valencia, UIMP. López García, S.M. 1991. La organización de la investigación científica y técnica tras la Guerra Civil: contrastes y similitudes con los logros de las primeras décadas del siglo XX. Actas del Encuentro de Historia Económica. Valencia, UIMP.
go back to reference López García, S.M. 1996. La investigación científica y técnica antes y después de la Guerra Civil. In Economía y sociedad en la España contemporánea, ed. A. Gómez Mendoza, 265–275. Madrid: Síntesis. López García, S.M. 1996. La investigación científica y técnica antes y después de la Guerra Civil. In Economía y sociedad en la España contemporánea, ed. A. Gómez Mendoza, 265–275. Madrid: Síntesis.
go back to reference Martin Aceña, P. 1993. Spain during the Classical Gold Standard Years, 1880–1914. In Monetary Régimes in Transition, ed. M.D. Bordo and F. Capie, 135–172. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. Martin Aceña, P. 1993. Spain during the Classical Gold Standard Years, 1880–1914. In Monetary Régimes in Transition, ed. M.D. Bordo and F. Capie, 135–172. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Núñez, C.E. 2003. El capital humano en el primer franquismo. In Autarquía y mercado negro: El fracaso económico del primer franquismo, ed. C. Barciela, 27–53. Crítica: Barcelona. Núñez, C.E. 2003. El capital humano en el primer franquismo. In Autarquía y mercado negro: El fracaso económico del primer franquismo, ed. C. Barciela, 27–53. Crítica: Barcelona.
go back to reference Ortega, J.A. and J. Silvestre. 2006. Las consecuencias demográficas. In La economía de la Guerra Civil, eds. P. Martín Aceña and E. Martínez Ruiz, 53–105. Madrid: Marcial Pons. Ortega, J.A. and J. Silvestre. 2006. Las consecuencias demográficas. In La economía de la Guerra Civil, eds. P. Martín Aceña and E. Martínez Ruiz, 53–105. Madrid: Marcial Pons.
go back to reference Plá Brugat, D. 1994. Características del exilio en México en 1939, Una inmigración privilegiada. In Comerciantes, empresarios y profesionales españoles en México en los siglos XIX y XX, ed. C.E. Lida, 218–231. Madrid: Alianza. Plá Brugat, D. 1994. Características del exilio en México en 1939, Una inmigración privilegiada. In Comerciantes, empresarios y profesionales españoles en México en los siglos XIX y XX, ed. C.E. Lida, 218–231. Madrid: Alianza.
go back to reference Plá Brugat, D. 1999. Els exiliats catalans. Un estudio de la emigración republicana en México. México D.F.: INAH. Plá Brugat, D. 1999. Els exiliats catalans. Un estudio de la emigración republicana en México. México D.F.: INAH.
go back to reference Prados de la Escosura, L. 2007. Growth and Structural Change in Spain, 1850–2000: A European Perspective. Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 25 (1): 147–181. Prados de la Escosura, L. 2007. Growth and Structural Change in Spain, 1850–2000: A European Perspective. Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 25 (1): 147–181.
go back to reference Prados de la Escosura, L. 2010. Spain’s International Position, 1850–1913. Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 28(1): 1–43. Prados de la Escosura, L. 2010. Spain’s International Position, 1850–1913. Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 28(1): 1–43.
go back to reference Prados de la Escosura, L. 2016. Economic Freedom in the Long Run: Evidence from OECD Countries (1850–2007). Economic History Review 69 (2): 435–468. Prados de la Escosura, L. 2016. Economic Freedom in the Long Run: Evidence from OECD Countries (1850–2007). Economic History Review 69 (2): 435–468.
go back to reference Prados de la Escosura, L., and J.R. Rosés. 2010. Capital Accumulation in the Long-Run: The Case of Spain, 1850–2000. Research in Economic History 27: 93–152. Prados de la Escosura, L., and J.R. Rosés. 2010. Capital Accumulation in the Long-Run: The Case of Spain, 1850–2000. Research in Economic History 27: 93–152.
go back to reference Prados de la Escosura, L., J.R. Rosés, and I. Sanz-Villarroya. 2012. Economic Reforms and Growth in Franco’s Spain. Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 30 (1): 45–89. Prados de la Escosura, L., J.R. Rosés, and I. Sanz-Villarroya. 2012. Economic Reforms and Growth in Franco’s Spain. Revista de Historia Económica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 30 (1): 45–89.
go back to reference Roldán, S. and J.L. Garcïa Delgado. 1973. La formación de la sociedad capitalista en España, 1914–1920, vol. 2. Madrid: Cajas de Ahorro Confederadas. Roldán, S. and J.L. Garcïa Delgado. 1973. La formación de la sociedad capitalista en España, 1914–1920, vol. 2. Madrid: Cajas de Ahorro Confederadas.
go back to reference Sánchez Alonso, B. 2000. European Emigration in the Late Nineteenth Century: The Paradoxical Case of Spain. Economic History Review 53: 309–330. Sánchez Alonso, B. 2000. European Emigration in the Late Nineteenth Century: The Paradoxical Case of Spain. Economic History Review 53: 309–330.
go back to reference Shleifer, A. 2009. The Age of Milton Friedman. Journal of Economic Literature 47 (1): 123–135. Shleifer, A. 2009. The Age of Milton Friedman. Journal of Economic Literature 47 (1): 123–135.
go back to reference Tena Junguito, A. 1999. Un nuevo perfil del proteccionismo español Velarde Fuertes, J. 1969. Política económica de la Dictadura. Madrid: Guadiana. Tena Junguito, A. 1999. Un nuevo perfil del proteccionismo español Velarde Fuertes, J. 1969. Política económica de la Dictadura. Madrid: Guadiana.
go back to reference Velarde Fuertes, J. 1969. Política económica de la Dictadura. Madrid: Guadiana. Velarde Fuertes, J. 1969. Política económica de la Dictadura. Madrid: Guadiana.
go back to reference Velarde Fuertes, J. 1993. Convergencias y divergencias de la economía española: comentario a una intervención del profesor Comín. Papeles de Economía Española 57: 57–72. Velarde Fuertes, J. 1993. Convergencias y divergencias de la economía española: comentario a una intervención del profesor Comín. Papeles de Economía Española 57: 57–72.
go back to reference Williamson, O. 1990. What Washington Means by Policy Reform. In Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened?, ed. J. Williamson. Washington: Institute for International Economics. Williamson, O. 1990. What Washington Means by Policy Reform. In Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened?, ed. J. Williamson. Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Metadata
Title
GDP and GDP Per Head
Author
Leandro Prados de la Escosura
Copyright Year
2017
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-58042-5_2