Skip to main content
Top
Published in: The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 4/2021

06-06-2020

Geographic Heterogeneity in Housing Market Risk and Portfolio Choice

Author: Tong-yob Nam

Published in: The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics | Issue 4/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The U.S. housing market is heterogeneous in that house price dynamics vary greatly across regions. Depending on the location of the main residence, households are exposed to completely different housing market risk. This paper examines how geographic heterogeneity in housing market risk affects household portfolio allocations. Housing supply elasticity largely explains variation in housing market risk across regions. Where housing supply elasticity is low, households face higher housing market risk since house price growth rates are more volatile and more positively correlated with stock returns and labor income growth rates. Using the restricted version of the Health and Retirement Study (HRS) data with detailed geographic information, I find that households in areas with low housing supply elasticity tend to hold less stock in their portfolios. This tendency, however, weakens after retirement when labor income risk disappears.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The stock price of a company whose operations are closely related to the strength of the local economy can be affected by region-specific shocks. If stock investors prefer to hold stocks of locally specialized companies, their portfolios are vulnerable to region-specific shocks (Coval and Moskowitz 1999). However, in this paper, I assume that households hold an aggregate-level stock index; as a result, their portfolios are free of region-specific shocks.
 
2
Poterba (2000) briefly summarizes the evidence on the link between stock prices and real estate.
 
3
Among various elasticities, only the price elasticity of the housing supply is assumed to vary across regions, as indicated by subscript i in Eq. 2.
 
4
Glaeser et al. (2008) show that house prices are more volatile in areas where housing supply elasticity is low. Harter-Dreiman (2004) studies how housing supply elasticity explains the relationship between local house prices and local labor income dynamics.
 
5
Assuming the house price at t is 1, then the log house price at t + 1, pt+ 1, can be interpreted as the house price growth rate.
 
6
Chetty et al. (2017) also assume no moving cost, but in their paper, households move only with an exogenous moving shock at a probability of 𝜃. Probability 1 − 𝜃 is interpreted as a commitment to the current house.
 
7
From this linear relationship, the correlation between the house price and labor income can be represented as follows: \(\rho _{py}=Corr(p_{t+1},y_{t+1})=\frac {Cov(\upbeta y_{t+1}+\psi _{t+1},y_{t+1})}{\sigma _{p}\sigma _{y}}=\upbeta \frac {\sigma _{y}}{\sigma _{p}}.\) Therefore, a high β means a high correlation between the house price and labor income ρpy (\(\frac {\partial \rho _{py}}{\partial \upbeta }>0\)).
 
8
By contrast, the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID), another longitudinal survey, tracks individuals in all age groups on an annual or biennial basis.
 
9
Prior to 1998, the HRS collected data in 1992, 1994, and 1996, while the AHEAD collected data in 1993 and 1995.
 
10
Although the HRS has surveyed more than 26,000 individuals, not all of them are relevant to this study. For example, the main focus of this paper being household portfolio allocation in the liquid financial wealth, households with little liquid assets are irrelevant to this study. Including irrelevant households in the sample impedes examination of the real effect of household portfolio allocation.
 
11
Although I include both married and single households, I exclude any household that experiences a change in marital status during the sample period. The reason I exclude this sample is that marital status change by itself causes a significant change in household portfolios that may affect the identification of the effect of other factors on portfolio choices.
 
12
The HRS does not provide a definition for household head. In this study, I define household head as the member of a household whose earnings are the highest among that household’s members across the survey period.
 
13
Since this paper studies the effect of housing assets on portfolio choices, I focus on homeowners in the main analyses. In a robustness test, I also consider the risky investment behavior of households that rent their residence.
 
14
In addition to the sample selection criteria listed here, I also exclude any households that have negative total wealth, zero total household income, a stock share greater than 1, or missing demographic information. The exclusion of these samples reduces total sample size from 16,751 to 16,231.
 
15
Because the size of MSAs varies greatly, the sample size for each MSA also varies. However, there is no significant variation over survey years within the same MSA.
 
16
Note that households can invest in the stock market through an IRA account. The portion of stock held in an IRA account may affect the household’s portfolio choice in their financial wealth. However, due to the limited information on IRA holdings in the HRS data, I am unable to analyze the effect of IRA holdings.
 
17
In the HRS, the value of a household’s housing assets is estimated based on the question: “What is its present value? I mean, what would it bring if it were sold today?” Since this question captures a self-estimation of an individual’s house value, the reported value may differ from the house’s market value. However, since the focus of this study is on the impact of perceptions of housing assets on a household’s portfolio decisions, the self-reported value represents an appropriate characterization of the housing assets’ value.
 
18
While the measure of housing supply elasticity developed by Saiz (2010) is often used as an instrument for local house prices, it does carry some limitations, as discussed in Davidoff (2016).
 
19
Here, home equity share is the portion of home equity (house value - remaining mortgage balance - home equity loan) in total wealth, while stock share is the portion of stock assets in total liquid assets. Although stock share is not directly related to home equity share in this set up, there could be a concern about a systemic relationship between home equity share and stock share. To address this concern, I use the home equity to income ratio to measure the relative importance of the housing asset in household finance. Even using this alternative measure as a control variable, the effect of housing supply elasticity on stock share remains significant.
 
20
As alternative specifications, I use home equity (dollar value) or home equity as a share of liquid assets, and obtain similar results.
 
21
For this grouping, I consider households with a home equity share between 0 and 1. Since home equity is the value of the house minus the mortgage amount, the home equity share cannot exceed 1 unless the household’s total non-housing wealth is negative. Similarly, the home equity share cannot be less than 0 unless the household’s home equity is negative. After grouping, each home equity share quartile group has home equity share 0 to 0.25, 0.25 to 0.5, 0.5 to 0.75, and 0.75 to 1, respectively. Samples used for this analysis are relatively well distributed across the four home equity share groups. There are 4,756, 6,045, 4,191, and 1,695 samples in groups with home equity shares of 0 to 0.25, 0.25 to 0.5, 0.5 to 0.75, and 0.75 to 1, respectively.
 
22
Flavin and Yamashita (2002) estimate the household mortgage holdings using the PSID data. The average LTV ratio for households whose head is aged between 18 and 30 is around 80 percent.
 
23
Since self-employment status is not available for retirees, I draw the subsample for this analysis from households in the labor force.
 
24
Since this paper defines the head of a household as the member whose labor income is higher than any other member throughout the survey period, the labor income of the household head, by definition, is always higher than that of the spouse. Working status of household head is thus more important to household portfolio choice. For some households, however, the difference in labor income between the household head and the spouse is insignificant, in which case, the spouse’s labor income may represent a considerable portion of the total household income.
 
25
For single households, head retirement status is the same as household retirement status.
 
Literature
go back to reference Benzoni, L., Collin-Dufresne, P., & Goldstein, R.S. (2007). Portfolio choice over the life-cycle when the stock and labor markets are cointegrated. Journal of Finance, 62(5), 3.CrossRef Benzoni, L., Collin-Dufresne, P., & Goldstein, R.S. (2007). Portfolio choice over the life-cycle when the stock and labor markets are cointegrated. Journal of Finance, 62(5), 3.CrossRef
go back to reference Bodie, Z., Merton, R.C., & Samuelson, W.F. (1992). Labor supply flexibility and portfolio choice in a life cycle model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16(3), 427–449.CrossRef Bodie, Z., Merton, R.C., & Samuelson, W.F. (1992). Labor supply flexibility and portfolio choice in a life cycle model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 16(3), 427–449.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, J.Y. (1993). Intertemporal asset pricing without consumption data. American Economic Review, 83(3), 487–512. Campbell, J.Y. (1993). Intertemporal asset pricing without consumption data. American Economic Review, 83(3), 487–512.
go back to reference Campbell, J.Y., & Viceira, L.M. (1999). Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (2), 433–495. Campbell, J.Y., & Viceira, L.M. (1999). Consumption and Portfolio Decisions When Expected Returns Are Time Varying. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114 (2), 433–495.
go back to reference Campbell, J.Y., & Viceira, L.M. (2001). Who should buy Long-Term bonds?. American Economic Review, 91(1), pp 99–127.CrossRef Campbell, J.Y., & Viceira, L.M. (2001). Who should buy Long-Term bonds?. American Economic Review, 91(1), pp 99–127.CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, J.Y., & Viceira, L.M. (2002). Strategic Asset allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-term Investors. Oxford University Press. Campbell, J.Y., & Viceira, L.M. (2002). Strategic Asset allocation: Portfolio Choice for Long-term Investors. Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Chetty, R., Sándor, L., & Szeidl, A. (2017). The effect of housing on portfolio choice. The Journal of Finance, 72(3), 1171–1212.CrossRef Chetty, R., Sándor, L., & Szeidl, A. (2017). The effect of housing on portfolio choice. The Journal of Finance, 72(3), 1171–1212.CrossRef
go back to reference Cocco, J.F. (2005). Portfolio choice in the presence of housing. Review of Financial Studies, 18(2), 535–567.CrossRef Cocco, J.F. (2005). Portfolio choice in the presence of housing. Review of Financial Studies, 18(2), 535–567.CrossRef
go back to reference Coval, J.D., & Moskowitz, T.J. (1999). Home bias at home: local equity preference in domestic portfolios. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2045–2073.CrossRef Coval, J.D., & Moskowitz, T.J. (1999). Home bias at home: local equity preference in domestic portfolios. Journal of Finance, 54(6), 2045–2073.CrossRef
go back to reference Davidoff, T. (2016). Supply constraints are not valid instrumental variables for home prices because they are correlated with many demand factors. Critical Finance Review, 5(2), 177–206.CrossRef Davidoff, T. (2016). Supply constraints are not valid instrumental variables for home prices because they are correlated with many demand factors. Critical Finance Review, 5(2), 177–206.CrossRef
go back to reference Dimson, E. (1979). Risk Measurement when Shares are subject to Infrequent Trading. Journal of Financial Economics, 7(2), 197–226.CrossRef Dimson, E. (1979). Risk Measurement when Shares are subject to Infrequent Trading. Journal of Financial Economics, 7(2), 197–226.CrossRef
go back to reference Flavin, M., & Yamashita, T. (2002). Owner-occupied housing and the composition of the household portfolio. American Economic Review, 92(1), pp. 345–362.CrossRef Flavin, M., & Yamashita, T. (2002). Owner-occupied housing and the composition of the household portfolio. American Economic Review, 92(1), pp. 345–362.CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., & Saiz, A. (2008). Housing supply and housing bubbles. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(2), 198–217.CrossRef Glaeser, E.L., Gyourko, J., & Saiz, A. (2008). Housing supply and housing bubbles. Journal of Urban Economics, 64(2), 198–217.CrossRef
go back to reference Gomes, F., & Michaelides, A. (2003). Portfolio choice with internal habit formation: a life-cycle model with uninsurable labor income risk. Review of Economic Dynamics, 6(4), 729–766.CrossRef Gomes, F., & Michaelides, A. (2003). Portfolio choice with internal habit formation: a life-cycle model with uninsurable labor income risk. Review of Economic Dynamics, 6(4), 729–766.CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, S.J., & Laroque, G. (1990). Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica, 58(1), 25–52.CrossRef Grossman, S.J., & Laroque, G. (1990). Asset pricing and optimal portfolio choice in the presence of illiquid durable consumption goods. Econometrica, 58(1), 25–52.CrossRef
go back to reference Guiso, L., Jappelli, T., & Terlizzese, D. (1996). Income risk, borrowing constraints, and portfolio choice. American Economic Review, 86(1), pp 158–172. Guiso, L., Jappelli, T., & Terlizzese, D. (1996). Income risk, borrowing constraints, and portfolio choice. American Economic Review, 86(1), pp 158–172.
go back to reference Harter-Dreiman, M. (2004). Drawing inferences about housing supply elasticity from house price responses to income shocks. Journal of Urban Economics, 55(2), 316–337.CrossRef Harter-Dreiman, M. (2004). Drawing inferences about housing supply elasticity from house price responses to income shocks. Journal of Urban Economics, 55(2), 316–337.CrossRef
go back to reference Heaton, J., & Lucas, D. (2000). Portfolio choice and asset prices: the importance of entrepreneurial risk. Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1163–1198.CrossRef Heaton, J., & Lucas, D. (2000). Portfolio choice and asset prices: the importance of entrepreneurial risk. Journal of Finance, 55(3), 1163–1198.CrossRef
go back to reference Kimball, M.S. (1993). Standard risk aversion. Econometrica, pp. 589–611. Kimball, M.S. (1993). Standard risk aversion. Econometrica, pp. 589–611.
go back to reference Lynch, A.W., & Tan, S. (2011). Labor income dynamics at business-cycle frequencies: implications for portfolio choice. Journal of Financial Economics, 101 (2), 333–359.CrossRef Lynch, A.W., & Tan, S. (2011). Labor income dynamics at business-cycle frequencies: implications for portfolio choice. Journal of Financial Economics, 101 (2), 333–359.CrossRef
go back to reference Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2010). Household leverage and the recession of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58(1), 74–117.CrossRef Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2010). Household leverage and the recession of 2007–09. IMF Economic Review, 58(1), 74–117.CrossRef
go back to reference Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2011). House prices, home Equity-Based borrowing, and the US household leverage crisis. American Economic Review, 101(5), 2132–56.CrossRef Mian, A., & Sufi, A. (2011). House prices, home Equity-Based borrowing, and the US household leverage crisis. American Economic Review, 101(5), 2132–56.CrossRef
go back to reference Mian, A., Rao, K., & Sufi, A. (2013). Household balance sheets, consumption, and the economic slump. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(4), 1687–1726.CrossRef Mian, A., Rao, K., & Sufi, A. (2013). Household balance sheets, consumption, and the economic slump. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(4), 1687–1726.CrossRef
go back to reference Mian, A.R., & Sufi, A. (2009). The consequences of mortgage credit expansion: evidence from the US mortgage default crisis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124 (4), 1449–1496.CrossRef Mian, A.R., & Sufi, A. (2009). The consequences of mortgage credit expansion: evidence from the US mortgage default crisis. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124 (4), 1449–1496.CrossRef
go back to reference Paciorek, A., & Sinai, T. (2012). Does home owning smooth the variability of future housing consumption?. Journal of Urban Economics, 71(2), 244–257.CrossRef Paciorek, A., & Sinai, T. (2012). Does home owning smooth the variability of future housing consumption?. Journal of Urban Economics, 71(2), 244–257.CrossRef
go back to reference Polkovnichenko, V. (2007). Life-cycle portfolio choice with additive habit formation preferences and uninsurable labor income risk. Review of Financial Studies, 20(1), 83–124.CrossRef Polkovnichenko, V. (2007). Life-cycle portfolio choice with additive habit formation preferences and uninsurable labor income risk. Review of Financial Studies, 20(1), 83–124.CrossRef
go back to reference Poterba, J.M. (2000). Stock market wealth and consumption. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(2), 99–118.CrossRef Poterba, J.M. (2000). Stock market wealth and consumption. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(2), 99–118.CrossRef
go back to reference Saiz, A. (2010). The geographic determinants of housing supply. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(3), 1253–1296.CrossRef Saiz, A. (2010). The geographic determinants of housing supply. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(3), 1253–1296.CrossRef
go back to reference Sinai, T., & Souleles, N.S. (2005). Owner-Occupied Housing as a Hedge Against Rent Risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 763–789. Sinai, T., & Souleles, N.S. (2005). Owner-Occupied Housing as a Hedge Against Rent Risk. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 763–789.
go back to reference Viceira, L.M. (2001). Optimal portfolio choice for Long-Horizon investors with nontradable labor income. Journal of Finance, 56(2), 433–470.CrossRef Viceira, L.M. (2001). Optimal portfolio choice for Long-Horizon investors with nontradable labor income. Journal of Finance, 56(2), 433–470.CrossRef
go back to reference Yao, R., & Zhang, H.H. (2005). Optimal consumption and portfolio choices with risky housing and borrowing constraints. Review of Financial Studies, 18(1), 197–239.CrossRef Yao, R., & Zhang, H.H. (2005). Optimal consumption and portfolio choices with risky housing and borrowing constraints. Review of Financial Studies, 18(1), 197–239.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Geographic Heterogeneity in Housing Market Risk and Portfolio Choice
Author
Tong-yob Nam
Publication date
06-06-2020
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics / Issue 4/2021
Print ISSN: 0895-5638
Electronic ISSN: 1573-045X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-020-09762-9

Other articles of this Issue 4/2021

The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 4/2021 Go to the issue