Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Annals of Finance 1/2021

09-11-2020 | Research Article

Heterogeneous beliefs, monetary policy, and stock price volatility

Author: Katsuhiro Oshima

Published in: Annals of Finance | Issue 1/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper, I build a two-agent New Keynesian model in which households with subjective and objective beliefs about capital gains from stock prices exist. The former type of households constructs their beliefs about expected capital gains by Bayesian learning from observed growth rates of stock prices. In a homogenous agent model with only subjective beliefs, the effect of the interest rate on stock prices tends to be unrealistically strong. I show how the presence of heterogeneity improves second moments of stock prices with realistic moments of business cycle properties. This quantitative improvement in stock price behaviors allows me to conduct a realistic analysis of how the stance of monetary policy affects stock price volatilities. Strong inertia of monetary policy provides the stability of stock prices. This is because the near-term real interest rate has dominant effects on stock prices under the presence of subjective beliefs since the presence limits the forward-looking nature in pricing stocks. However, because output depends on the expected path of the real interest rate in the forward-looking manner, strong monetary policy inertia does not necessarily provide stabilities of stock prices and output at the same time.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See Challe and Giannitsarou (2014) for a summary of empirical studies about the effect of monetary policy shock on stock prices including Bernanke and Kuttner (2005).
 
2
Srour (2001) lists an argument that the large surprises in short-term interest rates can cause volatility in financial markets as one reason for smoothing interest rates. Rudebusch (2006) examines a discussion about a rationale for policy gradualism, which is a desire to reduce the volatility in asset prices. González-Páramo (2006) argues that a gradual monetary policy could reduce the likelihood of financial market disruptions. In actual policymaking, FOMC Secretariat (1994) records that there were discussions led by chairman Alan Greenspan on whether a 25 basis point policy tightening was preferable to a 50 basis point tightening because some members considered the larger move to have a higher probability of cracking financial markets. To this question, Bernanke (2004) gives no decisive conclusion on whether gradualism of monetary policy provides stability of financial market or asset prices.
 
3
De Paoli et al. (2010) and Challe and Giannitsarou (2014) assume 5 for relative risk aversion rate. The prominent work by Jermann (1998), which is a real model, also assumes 5.
 
4
Caines and Winkler (2018) study housing prices in a New Keynesian model with learning about housing price capital gains. Because housing stock quantity is directly included in households’ utility, housing price has wealth effects on business cycles.
 
5
The belief structure in Winkler (2019) is also similar. However, Winkler (2019) assumes that agents have “conditionally model-consistent expectations”. Conditionally model-consistent expectations are consistent with all equilibrium conditions of the model, except those that would convey knowledge of the price that clears the asset market, when agents solve for the perceived law of motion. On the other hand, this study follows Adam and Merkel (2018) in which market clearing conditions are known by agents.
 
6
On the other hand, external rationality postulates that agents’ subjective probability belief equals the objective probability density of external variables as they emerge in equilibrium.
 
7
Both adjustment costs have positive values when the stock and bond holdings deviate from steady state levels. I assume these costs to incorporate demand for stock and bond from the two types of households.
 
8
These representations of stock and bond adjustment costs are parsimonious ways to aggregate two types of agents by having a mathematical representation similar to that obtained by the mean-variance optimization under constant absolute risk aversion utility. For example, see Brock and Hommes (1998) and Hanson and Stein (2015). Intuitively speaking, \(\zeta ^S\) and \(\zeta ^B\) represent the variance of expected returns of stocks and bonds, respectively.
 
9
The reason why a small value is necessary for the optimal Kalman gain g is that when g is not small enough, the Blanchard-Kahn condition is not satisfied in general equilibrium, as mentioned later. From (15) and (16) shown shortly, g becomes large if I do not assume (13). The calibrated value for g in this model is \(\frac{1}{150}\).
 
10
The linearized equation of (50) is given by \(\hat{\pi }_t = \delta E_t \hat{\pi }_{t+1} + \frac{1}{\zeta ^{P}(\mu -1)} \hat{\varOmega }_t + \frac{1}{\zeta ^{P}(\mu -1)} \kappa u_t\).
 
11
Winkler (2019) uses the second-order perturbation method to solve his New Keynesian model. I use the first-order perturbation method because the excess return of the stock is out of my interest.
 
12
This quarterly value implies 0.5 at an annual rate.
 
13
The effect on consumption of the sizes of two parameters does not appear in the homogenous cases with subjective beliefs, \(\alpha =1\). This is because \(S_{s,t}\) is always equal to 1 (or \(S_{ss}\)) in Eq. (18) and \(B_{s,t}\) is always equal to 0 (or \(B_{ss}\)) in Eq. (8) from the market clearing conditions of stock and bond markets, (27), (28), and (30). The same observation applies to the homogenous cases with objective beliefs, \(\alpha =0\).
 
14
The sample period almost corresponds to the periods during which the U.S. central bank targeted the interest rate rather than money growth.
 
15
In Smets and Wouters (2007), the productivity shock is estimated as 0.45%, monetary policy shock is estimated as 0.24%, preference shock is estimated as 0.24%, and investment-specific shock is estimated as 0.45% in standard deviation on a quarterly basis. The sample period in their study is 1966–2004. Smets and Wouters (2007) use an ARMA(1,1) process for the markup shock process which is different from this study. Levin et al. (2005) estimate that standard deviation of markup shock is 0.2%. The sample period in their study is 1955–2001.
 
16
The definition of dividend in the model shown in (53) is not the same as that in the statistics of U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis because of my model structure. The data are constructed here to be consistent with the definition of dividend in the model.
 
17
Due to data accessibility to subjective stock price growth expectations to cover the same data periods with other variables, I did not show \(Corr[\log P^s/d, \log (\alpha m_t + (1-\alpha )E_t[p^s_{t+1}/p^s_{t}])]\) in Table 3.
 
18
Castelnuovo and Nistico (2010) claim that incorporating sticky wages helps generate the procyclicality of dividends and their study shows positive responses of stock prices to preference shocks. However, their model does not include investment and capital, which could be crowded out under positive preference shocks and reduce the long-run production capacity. I examined how sticky wages change properties of responses to preference shocks in the model. However, it does not change responses of stock prices qualitatively from what the model without sticky wages presents in this study.
 
19
I experimented lower values for g than \(\frac{1}{1000}\). However, results are similar to what I discuss here.
 
20
I set \(\alpha =0.95\) instead of 0.94 in this study to match the moments.
 
21
In addition, in “Appendix A.2”, I investigate the effects on stock price volatilities under the habit formation parameter \(\phi \) with different values.
 
Literature
go back to reference Adam, K., Marcet, A.: Internal rationality, imperfect market knowledge and asset prices. J Econ Theory 146(3), 1224–1252 (2011)CrossRef Adam, K., Marcet, A.: Internal rationality, imperfect market knowledge and asset prices. J Econ Theory 146(3), 1224–1252 (2011)CrossRef
go back to reference Adam, K., Merkel, S.: Stock price cycles and business cycles. Working Paper (2018) Adam, K., Merkel, S.: Stock price cycles and business cycles. Working Paper (2018)
go back to reference Adam, K., Marcet, A., Nicolini, J.P.: Stock market volatility and learning. J Finance 71(1), 33–82 (2016)CrossRef Adam, K., Marcet, A., Nicolini, J.P.: Stock market volatility and learning. J Finance 71(1), 33–82 (2016)CrossRef
go back to reference Adam, K., Marcet, A., Beutel, J.: Stock price booms and expected capital gains. Am Econ Rev 107(8), 2352–2408 (2017)CrossRef Adam, K., Marcet, A., Beutel, J.: Stock price booms and expected capital gains. Am Econ Rev 107(8), 2352–2408 (2017)CrossRef
go back to reference Bansal, R., Yaron, A.: Risks for the long run: a potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. J Finance 59(4), 1481–1509 (2004)CrossRef Bansal, R., Yaron, A.: Risks for the long run: a potential resolution of asset pricing puzzles. J Finance 59(4), 1481–1509 (2004)CrossRef
go back to reference Barberis, N., Greenwood, R., Jin, L., Shleifer, A.: X-capm: an extrapolative capital asset pricing model. J Financ Econ 115(1), 1–24 (2015)CrossRef Barberis, N., Greenwood, R., Jin, L., Shleifer, A.: X-capm: an extrapolative capital asset pricing model. J Financ Econ 115(1), 1–24 (2015)CrossRef
go back to reference Bernanke, B.S., Kuttner, K.N.: What explains the stock market’s reaction to federal reserve policy? J Finance 60(3), 1221–1257 (2005)CrossRef Bernanke, B.S., Kuttner, K.N.: What explains the stock market’s reaction to federal reserve policy? J Finance 60(3), 1221–1257 (2005)CrossRef
go back to reference Bilbiie, F.O.: Limited asset markets participation, monetary policy and (inverted) aggregate demand logic. J Econ Theory 140(1), 162–196 (2008)CrossRef Bilbiie, F.O.: Limited asset markets participation, monetary policy and (inverted) aggregate demand logic. J Econ Theory 140(1), 162–196 (2008)CrossRef
go back to reference Brock, W.A., Hommes, C.H.: Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. J Econ Dyn Control 22(8–9), 1235–1274 (1998)CrossRef Brock, W.A., Hommes, C.H.: Heterogeneous beliefs and routes to chaos in a simple asset pricing model. J Econ Dyn Control 22(8–9), 1235–1274 (1998)CrossRef
go back to reference Caines, C., Winkler, F.: Asset price learning and optimal monetary policy. Working Paper (2018) Caines, C., Winkler, F.: Asset price learning and optimal monetary policy. Working Paper (2018)
go back to reference Campbell, J.Y., Cochrane, J.H.: By force of habit: a consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. J Polit Econ 107(2), 205–251 (1999)CrossRef Campbell, J.Y., Cochrane, J.H.: By force of habit: a consumption-based explanation of aggregate stock market behavior. J Polit Econ 107(2), 205–251 (1999)CrossRef
go back to reference Campbell, J.Y., Mankiw, N.G.: Permanent income, current income, and consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 8(3), 265–279 (1990) Campbell, J.Y., Mankiw, N.G.: Permanent income, current income, and consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 8(3), 265–279 (1990)
go back to reference Castelnuovo, E., Nistico, S.: Stock market conditions and monetary policy in a dsge model for the us. J Econ Dyn Control 34(9), 1700–1731 (2010)CrossRef Castelnuovo, E., Nistico, S.: Stock market conditions and monetary policy in a dsge model for the us. J Econ Dyn Control 34(9), 1700–1731 (2010)CrossRef
go back to reference Challe, E., Giannitsarou, C.: Stock prices and monetary policy shocks: a general equilibrium approach. J Econ Dyn Control 40, 46–66 (2014)CrossRef Challe, E., Giannitsarou, C.: Stock prices and monetary policy shocks: a general equilibrium approach. J Econ Dyn Control 40, 46–66 (2014)CrossRef
go back to reference Choi, J.J., Mertens, T.: Extrapolative expectations and the equity premium. Working Paper (2013) Choi, J.J., Mertens, T.: Extrapolative expectations and the equity premium. Working Paper (2013)
go back to reference Christiano, L.J., Fisher, J.D.M.: Stock market and investment goods prices: implications for macroeconomics. NBER Working Paper, No. 10031 (2003) Christiano, L.J., Fisher, J.D.M.: Stock market and investment goods prices: implications for macroeconomics. NBER Working Paper, No. 10031 (2003)
go back to reference Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C.L.: Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J Polit Econ 113(1), 1–45 (2005)CrossRef Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M., Evans, C.L.: Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J Polit Econ 113(1), 1–45 (2005)CrossRef
go back to reference Collin-Dufresne, P., Johannes, M., Lochstoer, L.A.: Parameter learning in general equilibrium: the asset pricing implications. Am Econ Rev 106(3), 664–98 (2016)CrossRef Collin-Dufresne, P., Johannes, M., Lochstoer, L.A.: Parameter learning in general equilibrium: the asset pricing implications. Am Econ Rev 106(3), 664–98 (2016)CrossRef
go back to reference Debortoli, D., Galí, J.: Monetary policy with heterogeneous agents: insights from tank models. Working Paper (2017) Debortoli, D., Galí, J.: Monetary policy with heterogeneous agents: insights from tank models. Working Paper (2017)
go back to reference De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H., Waldmann, R.J.: Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation. J Finance 45(2), 379–395 (1990)CrossRef De Long, J.B., Shleifer, A., Summers, L.H., Waldmann, R.J.: Positive feedback investment strategies and destabilizing rational speculation. J Finance 45(2), 379–395 (1990)CrossRef
go back to reference De Paoli, B., Scott, A., Weeken, O.: Asset pricing implications of a new keynesian model. J Econ Dyn Control 34(10), 2056–2073 (2010)CrossRef De Paoli, B., Scott, A., Weeken, O.: Asset pricing implications of a new keynesian model. J Econ Dyn Control 34(10), 2056–2073 (2010)CrossRef
go back to reference Eusepi, S., Preston, B.: Expectations, learning, and business cycle fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 101(6), 2844–72 (2011)CrossRef Eusepi, S., Preston, B.: Expectations, learning, and business cycle fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 101(6), 2844–72 (2011)CrossRef
go back to reference Evans, G.W, Honkapohja, S.: Learning and expectations in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2001) Evans, G.W, Honkapohja, S.: Learning and expectations in macroeconomics. Princeton University Press, Princeton (2001)
go back to reference Galí, J., López-Salido, J.D., Vallés, J.: Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 5(1), 227–270 (2007)CrossRef Galí, J., López-Salido, J.D., Vallés, J.: Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 5(1), 227–270 (2007)CrossRef
go back to reference Hanson, S.G., Stein, J.C.: Monetary policy and long-term real rates. J Financ Econ 115(3), 429–448 (2015)CrossRef Hanson, S.G., Stein, J.C.: Monetary policy and long-term real rates. J Financ Econ 115(3), 429–448 (2015)CrossRef
go back to reference Harrison, J.M., Kreps, D.M.: Speculative investor behavior in a stock market with heterogeneous expectations. Q J Econ 92(2), 323–336 (1978)CrossRef Harrison, J.M., Kreps, D.M.: Speculative investor behavior in a stock market with heterogeneous expectations. Q J Econ 92(2), 323–336 (1978)CrossRef
go back to reference Hirshleifer, D., Li, J., Jianfeng, Yu.: Asset pricing in production economies with extrapolative expectations. J Monet Econ 76, 87–106 (2015)CrossRef Hirshleifer, D., Li, J., Jianfeng, Yu.: Asset pricing in production economies with extrapolative expectations. J Monet Econ 76, 87–106 (2015)CrossRef
go back to reference Ireland, P.N.: Sticky-price models of the business cycle: specification and stability. J Monet Econ 47(1), 3–18 (2001)CrossRef Ireland, P.N.: Sticky-price models of the business cycle: specification and stability. J Monet Econ 47(1), 3–18 (2001)CrossRef
go back to reference Jermann, U.J.: Asset pricing in production economies. J Monet Econ 41(2), 257–275 (1998)CrossRef Jermann, U.J.: Asset pricing in production economies. J Monet Econ 41(2), 257–275 (1998)CrossRef
go back to reference Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G.E., Tambalotti, A.: Investment shocks and business cycles. J Monet Econ 57(2), 132–145 (2010)CrossRef Justiniano, A., Primiceri, G.E., Tambalotti, A.: Investment shocks and business cycles. J Monet Econ 57(2), 132–145 (2010)CrossRef
go back to reference Kaplan, G., Moll, B., Violante, G.L.: Monetary policy according to hank. Am Econ Rev 108(3), 697–743 (2018)CrossRef Kaplan, G., Moll, B., Violante, G.L.: Monetary policy according to hank. Am Econ Rev 108(3), 697–743 (2018)CrossRef
go back to reference Lansing, K.J.: Rational and near-rational bubbles without drift. Econ J 120(549), 1149–1174 (2010)CrossRef Lansing, K.J.: Rational and near-rational bubbles without drift. Econ J 120(549), 1149–1174 (2010)CrossRef
go back to reference Laopodis, N.T.: Monetary policy and stock market dynamics across monetary regimes. J Int Money Finance 33, 381–406 (2013)CrossRef Laopodis, N.T.: Monetary policy and stock market dynamics across monetary regimes. J Int Money Finance 33, 381–406 (2013)CrossRef
go back to reference Levin, A.T., Onatski, A., Williams, J.C., Williams, N.: Monetary policy under uncertainty in micro-founded macroeconometric models. NBER Macroecon Ann 20, 229–287 (2005)CrossRef Levin, A.T., Onatski, A., Williams, J.C., Williams, N.: Monetary policy under uncertainty in micro-founded macroeconometric models. NBER Macroecon Ann 20, 229–287 (2005)CrossRef
go back to reference Nisticò, S.: Monetary policy and stock-price dynamics in a dsge framework. J Macroecon 34(1), 126–146 (2012)CrossRef Nisticò, S.: Monetary policy and stock-price dynamics in a dsge framework. J Macroecon 34(1), 126–146 (2012)CrossRef
go back to reference Oshima, K.: Subjective beliefs, monetary policy, and stock price volatility. Working Paper (2019) Oshima, K.: Subjective beliefs, monetary policy, and stock price volatility. Working Paper (2019)
go back to reference Paul, P.: The time-varying effect of monetary policy on asset prices. Rev Econ Stat forthcoming (2019) Paul, P.: The time-varying effect of monetary policy on asset prices. Rev Econ Stat forthcoming (2019)
go back to reference Rotemberg, J.J.: Sticky prices in the united states. J Polit Econ 90(6), 1187–1211 (1982)CrossRef Rotemberg, J.J.: Sticky prices in the united states. J Polit Econ 90(6), 1187–1211 (1982)CrossRef
go back to reference Rudebusch, G.D.: Monetary policy inertia: fact or fiction? Int J Central Bank 2(4), 85–135 (2006) Rudebusch, G.D.: Monetary policy inertia: fact or fiction? Int J Central Bank 2(4), 85–135 (2006)
go back to reference Scheinkman, J.A., Xiong, W.: Overconfidence and speculative bubbles. J Polit Econ 111(6), 1183–1220 (2003)CrossRef Scheinkman, J.A., Xiong, W.: Overconfidence and speculative bubbles. J Polit Econ 111(6), 1183–1220 (2003)CrossRef
go back to reference Shiller, R.J., Fischer, S., Friedman, B.M.: Stock prices and social dynamics. Brook Pap Econ Act 1984(2), 457–510 (1984)CrossRef Shiller, R.J., Fischer, S., Friedman, B.M.: Stock prices and social dynamics. Brook Pap Econ Act 1984(2), 457–510 (1984)CrossRef
go back to reference Smets, F., Wouters, R.: Shocks and frictions in us business cycles: a bayesian dsge approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3), 586–606 (2007)CrossRef Smets, F., Wouters, R.: Shocks and frictions in us business cycles: a bayesian dsge approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3), 586–606 (2007)CrossRef
go back to reference Srour, G.: Why do central banks smooth interest rates? Working Paper (2001) Srour, G.: Why do central banks smooth interest rates? Working Paper (2001)
go back to reference Timmermann, A.G.: How learning in financial markets generates excess volatility and predictability in stock prices. Q. J. Econ 108(4), 1135–1145 (1993) Timmermann, A.G.: How learning in financial markets generates excess volatility and predictability in stock prices. Q. J. Econ 108(4), 1135–1145 (1993)
go back to reference Wei, C.: A quartet of asset pricing models in nominal and real economies. J Econ Dyn Control 33(1), 154–165 (2009) Wei, C.: A quartet of asset pricing models in nominal and real economies. J Econ Dyn Control 33(1), 154–165 (2009)
go back to reference Winkler, F.: The role of learning for asset prices and business cycles. J Monetary Econ forthcoming (2019) Winkler, F.: The role of learning for asset prices and business cycles. J Monetary Econ forthcoming (2019)
Metadata
Title
Heterogeneous beliefs, monetary policy, and stock price volatility
Author
Katsuhiro Oshima
Publication date
09-11-2020
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Annals of Finance / Issue 1/2021
Print ISSN: 1614-2446
Electronic ISSN: 1614-2454
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10436-020-00379-9

Other articles of this Issue 1/2021

Annals of Finance 1/2021 Go to the issue