Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2014

01-04-2014

How a firm can induce legislators to adopt a bad policy

Authors: Matthias Dahm, Robert Dur, Amihai Glazer

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper shows why a majority of legislators may vote for a policy that benefits a firm but harms all legislators. The firm may induce legislators to support the policy by suggesting that it is more likely to invest in a district where voters or their representative support the policy. In equilibrium, no one vote may be decisive, so each legislator who seeks the firm’s investment votes for the policy, though all legislators would be better off if they all voted against the policy. And when votes reveal information about the district, the firm’s implicit promise or threat can be credible. Unlike influence mechanisms based on contributions or bribes, the behavior considered is time consistent and in line with the low campaign contributions by special interests.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Transcript, Lawrence F. O’Brien Oral History Interview XVII, 12/17/86, by Michael L. Gillette, Internet Copy, LBJ Library.
 
2
Danielle Kurtzleben, $4 billion in election spending a drop in the bucket, http://​www.​usnews.​com/​news/​articles/​2010/​11/​09/​4-billion-in-election-spending-a-drop-in-the-bucket.​html, downloaded December 29, 2010.
 
3
Nor is the size of illegal contributions large. Investigations following the Watergate scandal found that 21 companies made illegal contributions in 1972, totaling only $968,000; the largest one was made by Northrop for a mere $150,000 (Alexander 1980).
 
4
Models that combine both influence instruments are Bennedsen and Feldmann (2006), and Dahm and Porteiro (2008a, 2008b). In these models special interests choose between providing policy-relevant information or engaging in non-informational influence activities (such as by making campaign contributions).
 
5
Analyzing a game with two rent-seekers, Corchón and Dahm (2010) show that some contest success functions can be derived as a utility-maximizing choice from a setting in which rent-seekers are uncertain about the type of politician. Corchón and Dahm (2011) derive contest success functions without the commitment assumption. See also the literature reviewed in these papers.
 
6
For works arguing that special interests inform legislators about political consequences of legislative votes, see Smith (1984), Hansen (1991), Austen-Smith (1993), Austen-Smith and Wright (1992, 1994), Rasmussen (1993) and Lohmann (1995, 1998).
 
7
See Uhlaner (1989) and Schwartz (1987), who discuss a “local public benefit” to a group that increases with the number of votes the winner received from that group. Lapp (1999), however, testing the model, finds little empirical evidence that ethnic leaders can increase turnout among their followers.
 
8
For brevity, we take n to be an odd number.
 
9
The firm may invest with probability less than one. The values of g and b can then be taken as expected values.
 
10
In Sect. 6.1 we relax the assumptions that m≥1+(n+1)/2 and that the proportion of districts favoring the investment is common knowledge. We could also describe our setting as follows. First, nature assigns types to legislators (so that with probability γ a legislator favors the investment) and each legislator knows his type. This implies that m could be very small and our assumption on m just says that we focus on realizations in which m is larger. Then, each legislator gets a perfect signal concerning the other legislators’ types. The firm does not receive this signal. Under this interpretation Sect. 6.1 investigates robustness when neither legislators nor the firm receive a signal and m≥1+(n+1)/2 need not hold.
 
11
Faccio and Parsley (2009) show that the sudden death of a politician causes a 1.7 % decline in the value of companies headquartered in the politician’s home town. This decline is followed by a decline in the rate of growth in sales and a decline in access to credit.
 
12
Obviously, we do not require a legislator favoring the investment to use the same strategy as a legislator opposing the investment, with the labels ‘voting for’ and ‘voting against’ swapped.
 
13
Strictly speaking, we assume that a district that does not want the investment cannot prevent the firm from locating in the district. Incorporating such a veto power, Proposition 1 below still holds, although the strategy of the legislators from districts that oppose the investment is then weakly dominant.
 
14
Note that, by definition of n and k, nk−1 other legislators vote against the tariff, who constitute a majority if nk−1≥(n+1)/2, implying k≤(n−3)/2.
 
15
Besides the two voting profiles described above, two other symmetric strategy profiles are candidates for an equilibrium. Each, however, requires legislators who do not favor investment to use a strictly dominated strategy.
 
16
To see that an equilibrium with a dominant strategy is compatible with an inefficiency, consider the example in which g=F=1. It must hold that F/n<C and C/g<2/(n+1). These expressions define a non-empty interval for C described by 1/n<C<2/(n+1). But, of course, as the inefficiency becomes increasingly severe, the equilibrium is no longer in dominant strategies.
 
17
This argument can be made precise. Denote by F m the firm’s benefits from a successful match. In the unique equilibrium, social welfare is FnC+F m +g. Suppose the alternative has no vote on the tariff, with the firm deciding randomly where to invest. Then γ(F m +g)+(1−γ)(−b). If (1−γ)(F m +g+b) is smaller than −(FnC), the inefficiency is not reversed.
 
18
We see x 1 as a more appealing equilibrium than x 2, because it is plausible that as legislation becomes more inefficient it is less often approved. There are further reasons to focus on x 1. Consider n=3 and suppose that x 1 and x 2 exist. Denote by A(x) and B(x) the expected payoffs from voting for and against the tariff, respectively, when the two other legislators vote for the tariff with probability x. We have that A′(x)<0, A″(x)>0, B′(x)<0, B″(x)<0, and A(0)>B(0)>A(1)>B(1). Hence, A(x) and B(x) intersect twice (at x 1 and at x 2), and expected payoffs are strictly higher at x 1. Another reasoning could be based on a simultaneous version of Cournot’s tatonnement process, adapted to symmetric mixed-strategy equilibria. Consider an equilibrium \(\hat{x}\) to be (locally) stable if given a collective mistake in which everyone mixes with probability \(\hat{x}+m\), where m∈{−ϵ,ϵ} with ϵ>0, the following holds for all legislators: \(A(\hat{x}+\nobreak m)>B(\hat{x}+m)\) if m<0, and \(A(\hat{x}+m)<B(\hat{x}+m)\) if m>0. Similarly, consider an equilibrium \(\hat{x}\) to be (locally) unstable if for some legislator the opposite inequality holds. Given how A(x) and B(x) intersect, x 1 is stable, whereas x 2 is unstable.
 
19
Further simulations for larger n yield chaotic mixing probabilities, which could arise from rounding errors in the computer program Mathematica.
 
20
If all districts with priority offer no incentives, we assume that all districts have the same win probability 1/h, where h is the number of districts with priority.
 
21
Contrary to the benchmark, when u(−b,l)=0 it is now an equilibrium for all legislators to vote for the tariff. A legislator who opposes the investment might vote for the tariff because his district does not compete actively at the lobbying stage and, thus, will not attract the firm’s investment. Anticipating this, he is indifferent between voting for and against the tariff.
 
22
Notice that even if at the last stage competition is very fierce and the firm can appropriate all the rent from matching to a district favoring the investment, it is still an equilibrium for a legislator who favors the investment to vote for the tariff. If the lobbying stage is modeled as a first-price auction, in the undominated pure strategy Nash equilibrium a district that favors the investment obtains the expected payoff u(g,l)=0; see Alcalde and Dahm (2011). That is, any one legislator gains nothing from voting against the tariff when a majority of other legislators vote for it, and might as well vote for it.
 
Literature
go back to reference Alcalde, J., & Dahm, M. (2011). On the complete information first-price auction and its intuitive solution. International Game Theory Review, 13(3), 353–361. CrossRef Alcalde, J., & Dahm, M. (2011). On the complete information first-price auction and its intuitive solution. International Game Theory Review, 13(3), 353–361. CrossRef
go back to reference Alexander, H. (1980). Financing politics (2nd ed.). Washington: CQ Press. Alexander, H. (1980). Financing politics (2nd ed.). Washington: CQ Press.
go back to reference Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. Jr. (2003). Why is there so little money in U.S. politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 105–130. CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. Jr. (2003). Why is there so little money in U.S. politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 105–130. CrossRef
go back to reference Austen-Smith, D. (1993). Information and influence: lobbying for agendas and votes. American Journal of Political Science, 37(3), 799–833. CrossRef Austen-Smith, D. (1993). Information and influence: lobbying for agendas and votes. American Journal of Political Science, 37(3), 799–833. CrossRef
go back to reference Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1992). Competitive lobbying for a legislator’s vote. Social Choice and Welfare, 9, 229–257. CrossRef Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1992). Competitive lobbying for a legislator’s vote. Social Choice and Welfare, 9, 229–257. CrossRef
go back to reference Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1994). Counteractive lobbying. American Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 25–44. CrossRef Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1994). Counteractive lobbying. American Journal of Political Science, 38(1), 25–44. CrossRef
go back to reference Bennedsen, M., & Feldmann, S. (2006). Informational lobbying and political contributions. Journal of Public Economics, 90(4–5), 631–656. CrossRef Bennedsen, M., & Feldmann, S. (2006). Informational lobbying and political contributions. Journal of Public Economics, 90(4–5), 631–656. CrossRef
go back to reference Bernheim, B. D., Rangel, A., & Rayo, L. (2006). The power of the last word in legislative policy making. Econometrica, 74(5), 1161–1190. CrossRef Bernheim, B. D., Rangel, A., & Rayo, L. (2006). The power of the last word in legislative policy making. Econometrica, 74(5), 1161–1190. CrossRef
go back to reference Corchón, L., & Dahm, M. (2010). Foundations for contest success functions. Economic Theory, 43, 81–98. CrossRef Corchón, L., & Dahm, M. (2010). Foundations for contest success functions. Economic Theory, 43, 81–98. CrossRef
go back to reference Corchón, L., & Dahm, M. (2011). Welfare maximizing contest success functions when the planner cannot commit. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 47, 309–317. CrossRef Corchón, L., & Dahm, M. (2011). Welfare maximizing contest success functions when the planner cannot commit. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 47, 309–317. CrossRef
go back to reference Crawford, V. P., & Sobel, J. (1982). Strategic information transmission. Econometrica, 50(6), 1431–1451. CrossRef Crawford, V. P., & Sobel, J. (1982). Strategic information transmission. Econometrica, 50(6), 1431–1451. CrossRef
go back to reference Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008a). Informational lobbying under the shadow of political pressure. Social Choice and Welfare, 30(4), 531–559. CrossRef Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008a). Informational lobbying under the shadow of political pressure. Social Choice and Welfare, 30(4), 531–559. CrossRef
go back to reference Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008b). Side effects of campaign finance reform. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(5), 1057–1077. CrossRef Dahm, M., & Porteiro, N. (2008b). Side effects of campaign finance reform. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(5), 1057–1077. CrossRef
go back to reference Dal Bó, E. (2007). Bribing voters. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 789–803. CrossRef Dal Bó, E. (2007). Bribing voters. American Journal of Political Science, 51(4), 789–803. CrossRef
go back to reference Evans, C. L. (2009). A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics: an empirical investigation. Economics & Politics, 21(2), 278–307. CrossRef Evans, C. L. (2009). A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics: an empirical investigation. Economics & Politics, 21(2), 278–307. CrossRef
go back to reference Evans, C. L., & Obradovich, N. (2009). Agricultural protection and electoral systems: an empirical investigation. Working paper. Department of Economics, Santa Clara University. Evans, C. L., & Obradovich, N. (2009). Agricultural protection and electoral systems: an empirical investigation. Working paper. Department of Economics, Santa Clara University.
go back to reference Faccio, M., & Parsley, D. C. (2009). Sudden deaths: taking stock of geographic ties. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44, 683–718. CrossRef Faccio, M., & Parsley, D. C. (2009). Sudden deaths: taking stock of geographic ties. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 44, 683–718. CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.
go back to reference Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2005). A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1239–1282. CrossRef Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2005). A protectionist bias in majoritarian politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1239–1282. CrossRef
go back to reference Hall, R. L. (2000). Lobbying as legislative subsidy. Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington. Hall, R. L. (2000). Lobbying as legislative subsidy. Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington.
go back to reference Hansen, J. M. (1991). Gaining access: congress and the farm lobby 1919–81. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Hansen, J. M. (1991). Gaining access: congress and the farm lobby 1919–81. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
go back to reference Hatfield, J. W., & Hauk, W. R. Jr. (2010). Electoral regime and trade policy. Mimeo. Graduate School of Business, Stanford University. Hatfield, J. W., & Hauk, W. R. Jr. (2010). Electoral regime and trade policy. Mimeo. Graduate School of Business, Stanford University.
go back to reference Kingdon, J. W. (1984). Agendas, alternatives, and public policy. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company. Kingdon, J. W. (1984). Agendas, alternatives, and public policy. Boston: Little, Brown, and Company.
go back to reference Krehbiel, K. (1991). Information and legislative organization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Krehbiel, K. (1991). Information and legislative organization. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
go back to reference Lapp, M. (1999). Incorporating groups into rational choice explanations of turnout: an empirical test. Public Choice, 98(1–2), 171–185. CrossRef Lapp, M. (1999). Incorporating groups into rational choice explanations of turnout: an empirical test. Public Choice, 98(1–2), 171–185. CrossRef
go back to reference Lohmann, S. (1995). Information, access, and contributions: a signaling model of lobbying. Public Choice, 85(3–4), 267–284. CrossRef Lohmann, S. (1995). Information, access, and contributions: a signaling model of lobbying. Public Choice, 85(3–4), 267–284. CrossRef
go back to reference Lohmann, S. (1998). An information rationale for the power of special interests. American Political Science Review, 92(4), 809–827. CrossRef Lohmann, S. (1998). An information rationale for the power of special interests. American Political Science Review, 92(4), 809–827. CrossRef
go back to reference McCarty, N., & Rothenberg, L. S. (1996). Commitment and the campaign contribution contract. American Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 872–904. CrossRef McCarty, N., & Rothenberg, L. S. (1996). Commitment and the campaign contribution contract. American Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 872–904. CrossRef
go back to reference McChesney, F. S. (1987). Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation. Journal of Legal Studies, 16(1), 101–118. CrossRef McChesney, F. S. (1987). Rent extraction and rent creation in the economic theory of regulation. Journal of Legal Studies, 16(1), 101–118. CrossRef
go back to reference Milyo, J., Primo, D., & Groseclose, T. (2000). Corporate PAC campaign contributions in perspective. Business and Politics, 2(1), 75–88. CrossRef Milyo, J., Primo, D., & Groseclose, T. (2000). Corporate PAC campaign contributions in perspective. Business and Politics, 2(1), 75–88. CrossRef
go back to reference Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Mueller, D. C. (1989). Public choice II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Raff, H., & Srinivasan, K. (1998). Tax incentives for import-substituting foreign investment: does signaling play a role? Journal of Public Economics, 67(2), 167–193. CrossRef Raff, H., & Srinivasan, K. (1998). Tax incentives for import-substituting foreign investment: does signaling play a role? Journal of Public Economics, 67(2), 167–193. CrossRef
go back to reference Rasmussen, E. (1993). Lobbying when the decisionmaker can acquire independent information. Public Choice, 77(4), 899–913. CrossRef Rasmussen, E. (1993). Lobbying when the decisionmaker can acquire independent information. Public Choice, 77(4), 899–913. CrossRef
go back to reference Schwartz, T. (1987). Your vote counts on account of the way it is counted: an institutional solution to the paradox of not voting. Public Choice, 54(2), 101–121. CrossRef Schwartz, T. (1987). Your vote counts on account of the way it is counted: an institutional solution to the paradox of not voting. Public Choice, 54(2), 101–121. CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, R. A. (1984). Advocacy, interpretation, and influence in the U.S. Congress. American Political Science Review, 78(1), 44–63. CrossRef Smith, R. A. (1984). Advocacy, interpretation, and influence in the U.S. Congress. American Political Science Review, 78(1), 44–63. CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, R. A. (1995). Interest group influence in the U.S. Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 20(1), 89–139. CrossRef Smith, R. A. (1995). Interest group influence in the U.S. Congress. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 20(1), 89–139. CrossRef
go back to reference Stratmann, T. (1998). The market for congressional votes: is timing of contributions everything? Journal of Law and Economics, 41(1), 85–113. CrossRef Stratmann, T. (1998). The market for congressional votes: is timing of contributions everything? Journal of Law and Economics, 41(1), 85–113. CrossRef
go back to reference Stratmann, T. (2005). Some talk: money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. Public Choice, 124(1), 135–156. CrossRef Stratmann, T. (2005). Some talk: money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. Public Choice, 124(1), 135–156. CrossRef
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1972). The purchase of politicians. Western Economic Journal, 10, 354–355. Tullock, G. (1972). The purchase of politicians. Western Economic Journal, 10, 354–355.
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press. Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J. Buchanan, R. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.
go back to reference Uhlaner, C. J. (1989). Rational turnout: the neglected role of groups. American Journal of Political Science, 33(2), 390–422. CrossRef Uhlaner, C. J. (1989). Rational turnout: the neglected role of groups. American Journal of Political Science, 33(2), 390–422. CrossRef
go back to reference Wright, J. R. (1996). Interest groups and Congress: lobbying, contributions, and influence. Boston: Allyn and Bacon. Wright, J. R. (1996). Interest groups and Congress: lobbying, contributions, and influence. Boston: Allyn and Bacon.
go back to reference Yates, A. J. (2011). Winner-pay contests. Public Choice, 147(1–2), 93–106. CrossRef Yates, A. J. (2011). Winner-pay contests. Public Choice, 147(1–2), 93–106. CrossRef
Metadata
Title
How a firm can induce legislators to adopt a bad policy
Authors
Matthias Dahm
Robert Dur
Amihai Glazer
Publication date
01-04-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0016-z

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2014

Public Choice 1-2/2014 Go to the issue