Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Small Business Economics 4/2019

Open Access 19-12-2018

Informality and poverty in Ecuador

Author: Carla Canelas

Published in: Small Business Economics | Issue 4/2019

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper uses national representative data from the Ecuadorian Family Expenditure survey to study the determinants of poverty and informality in the country, taking into account the two-way relationship between these two phenomena. The main contribution of this paper is to present new empirical evidence on this relationship for a developing country where more than 60% of workers are in the informal sector. The results support the view of a heterogeneous informal market, in which informal work is both a demand-led phenomenon and a voluntary and primarily supply-led form of employment.

1 Introduction

For the vast majority of households in the developing world, labor income accounts for the main, if not the only, source of income. In 2013, the estimates of the World Development Report from the World Bank (2013) revealed that self-employment and farming represent almost half of the jobs in the developing world. They also revealed that the important decline in poverty rates between 1981 and 2008 was achieved, to a large extent, through jobs. If non-wage employment represents such a large share of total employment in these countries, understanding the links between informal jobs (whether defined on the basis of self-employment, social security coverage or written employment contract) and poverty becomes critical from a policy perspective.
Indeed, labor informality is a common characteristic of developing countries, which are also characterized by high levels of poverty. In this context, it is easy to think that a link between poverty and informal employment exists. In particular, one may think that being poor affects the probability of working informally, but also that having informal employment is a determinant of poverty. The question then becomes whether informality is both a cause and a result of poverty. That is, are informal employment and poverty interrelated? While there is some agreement about this idea in the literature, there is still limited evidence about the interactions between the two phenomena. Most articles on informality or poverty consider this only as a one-way relationship and do not take into account the simultaneous causality that may exist between these two phenomena—thus, estimates may be biased. This article adds to the limited number of empirical studies that address this problem.
The case of Ecuador is of particular interest since little evidence exists for this country even though its poverty and informality rates are among the highest in Latin America. In Ecuador, the share of employees who do not have social security coverage is the highest among the poorest, at 84% versus 65% for the not poor. Also, households headed by informal workers have higher poverty rates (34%) than those headed by formal workers (13%).1 There is thus a strong association between informality and poverty in the country.
This paper contributes to the literature in several ways. First, it controls for the simultaneity of poverty and informality by using a simultaneous equation model that allows for error correlation across equations. While the methodology is not new in the literature, the article adds to the limited number of studies that address the double causality between the two phenomena. Second, it provides evidence for a country for which no other stu- dies link poverty and informality. Third, it presents the results for both salaried and self-employed workers. These results, so far unavailable in the literature, contri- bute to a better understanding of the heterogeneity of informal sector employment in a developing country.
The structure of the paper is as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature and the main theories of informality. Section 3 describes the data and presents some descriptive statistics. Section 4 presents the empirical specification, Section 5 the results, and Section 6 the robustness checks. This is followed by a discussion and conclusion in Sections 7 and 8.

2 Conceptual framework and literature review

The relationship between informal employment and po- verty is a very complex one that is not yet well understood. In the theoretical literature on the informal sector, three contrasting views prevail regarding the origins of informal employment—namely the dualistic labor market approach, the alternative or neoliberal approach, and the structural articulation approach.
In the first approach, informal employment is seen as an involuntary solution to unemployment—it is the second-best strategy that substitutes for the lack of formal employment. As such, the informal sector absorbs the surplus labor in the economy. In this view, informal employment is involuntary, requires little capital investment and only provides a subsistence wage. This approach originated with the works of Lewis (1954) and Harris and Todaro (1970), and was later extended by Fields (1975).
The alternative (or neoliberal) approach sees informal employment as a voluntary choice. In this view, informal employment represents a cost-minimizing strategy for entrepreneurs trying to avoid the costs of labor regulations. Basically, the informal sector is viewed as the optimal and coherent response of economic units to government-induced distortions like minimum wages and excessive taxes (Chaudhuri and Mukhopadhyay 2010).
The third theory of informal employment sees the informal sector as heterogeneous and comprising at least two distinct sub-sectors: informal activities with direct subsistence goals and dynamic activities with decreasing labor costs and capital accumulation goals (see Chaudhuri and Mukhopadhyay (2010)). I argue that informal employment in Ecuador exhibits the characteristics of a heterogeneous informal market, where informal work is both a demand-led phenomenon and a voluntary and primarily supply-led form of employment. See Cunningham and Maloney (2001), Paulson and Townsend (2005), Günther and Launov (2012), and Harati (2013) for studies in developing countries that exhibit similar characteristics.
Literature relating poverty and informal employment is scarce, mostly based on studying a one-way relationship, and usually being descriptive. For instan- ce, Gasparini and Tornarolli (2009) study the trends of labor informality in the Latin America region during the period 1989–2005. While the cross-section evidence seems to be consistent with the idea of voluntary self- employment, the authors found that, on average, being informal implies lower wages, even when controlling for observable factors. Informally employed male wor- kers without a secondary education earn, on average, 30% less than their formally employed counterparts. Accordingly, in all countries the difference in the po- verty headcount ratio between informal and formal workers is sizeable. Loayza et al. (2009) study, among other things, the connection between poverty and in- formality in Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC). Using country-level data, the authors use the share of informal employment as one of the determinants of poverty and use instrumental variables to control for the endogeneity of informality on poverty. The results suggest that the share of the informal sector has a significant positive impact on the incidence of poverty across LAC countries. Maurizio (2012) studies to what extent the income segmentation associated with informality is a relevant factor in the poverty situation of households in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and Peru. She finds a positive relationship between informality and poverty. However, she also finds that the elimination of informality does not eliminate poverty. A more recent study (Webster et al. 2016) looks at the relationship between informality, property rights, and poverty in three Chinese cities. Among the various definitions of informality used by the authors, the results show a strong association between labor contract types and poverty. While these results are fundamental for the understanding of informal employment and poverty, either no casual relationship between the two phenomena was established, or only a one-way relationship was considered in the analysis, usually with informality as a determinant of poverty.
To the best of this author’s knowledge, only three stu- dies have used a simultaneous equations framework to study the relationship between poverty and informa- lity: Amuedo-Dorantes (2004), who studies the determinants of poverty and its implications for the informal sector in Chile; Devicienti et al. (2009), who study the same process using panel data for Argentina; and Nazier and Ramadan (2015), who study the inverse causality between informality and poverty in Egypt. Both studies in Latin America found a strong correlation between poverty and informality in the countries. In the absence of panel data, I follow the methodology employed by Amuedo-Dorantes (2004) and study the determinants of poverty and informality in Ecuador. In addition to the results already provided for salaried workers in Chile, I also provide estimations for self-employed workers. These results, to date unavailable in the literature, contribute to a better understanding of the heterogeneity of informal sector employment in a developing country, where usually more than 50% of the working population is categorized as self-employed.

3 Data and descriptive analysis

The data used in this paper are drawn from the Ecuadorian National Living Standards Survey (ECV) 2014, conducted by the Ecuadorian National Institute of Statistics (INEC). The ECV is a cross-sectional survey representative of the Ecuadorian population. The survey collects detailed information on household demographics, health, education, occupations and labor force participation, housing and asset ownership, household food, and non-food expenditures and income.
Affiliation to the national social security system is mandatory for all salaried workers. A registered worker has access to health care services and retirement benefits. A salaried worker also has the right to earn at least the minimum wage, be paid for extra hours of work and to receive mandated benefits (teen salaries and profit sharing at the end of the fiscal year) (Canelas 2014). Since the social security card constitutes a sufficient proof of labor dependence, it assures employers’ compliance with all these benefits. On the other hand, it also reduces the chances of employees under-declaring their income as the information is cross-validated between the National Revenue Tax Institute, employers and employees. Hence, the definition of informality used in this paper is based on the lack of social security coverage. Since this definition applies only to salaried workers, I run separate regressions using self-employment status as an alternative definition of informality. These results are interpreted in Section 5.
Studying the relationship between informality and poverty is a difficult task since poverty is measured at the household level while informality and other human capital variables are based on individual status. In order to deal with this problem, I follow the standard practice in the literature (Amuedo-Dorantes 2004; Devicienti et al. 2009), and I base the definition of informality on the formal/informal status of the household head. Thus, I work with a sample of working household heads.
The poverty status of the household is assessed using the index of unsatisfied basic needs (UBN) (Necesidades Basicas Insatisfechas; NBI) proposed by the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) and used as an official measure of poverty in many countries in Latin America, including Ecuador.2 Most UBN indices include indicators such as access to clean water, quality of housing, crowding, education level of household head, school attendance, nutrition, and others. In the case of Ecuador, a household is considered poor if one of the following holds:
  • The house is made of irregular/inadequate materials (housing).
  • The house does not have adequate services such as a flush toilet and piped water (sanitation).
  • There is a high dependency ratio, with three or more persons per person working and a household head with two or fewer years of primary school education (subsistence capacity).
  • There is at least one child between 6 and 12 years old who is not attending school (school attendance).
  • There are more than three persons per room for sleeping (crowding).
The use of a composite index to measure poverty is not free of criticisms. The most obvious problem with the UBN is that the greater the number of indicators used to create the index, the greater the likelihood of being categorized as poor—the probability of being categorized as poor would be higher if one uses five indicators instead of three.
In order to measure the robustness of the estimates, I also present the results using a consumption poverty line. This measure is one of the official poverty lines used by the Ecuadorian government.3
Table 1 presents the percentage of poor households for different sub-samples and two measures of poverty. As mentioned before, working individuals are divided into salaried and self-employed workers. Salaried workers represent, on average, 40% of all working individuals, while the other 60% are self-employed. The first row of Table 1 gives the percentage of poor households with respect to each sub-sample, while the second row presents the same results with respect to the entire sample of workers. For instance, using the UBN indicator, around 45% of self-employed workers and 28% of salaried workers are poor (row 1, columns 2 and 3). With respect to the whole sample, poor self-employed workers represent 27% of the sample and poor salaried workers represent 11% (row 2, columns 2 and 3). Together, poor self-employed and salaried workers comprise 38% of the sample. Columns 4 and 5 decompose the results of salaried workers into formal and informal workers. The interpretation of the results is similar to columns 2 and 3.4 Finally, the interpretation for row 3 (4), is similar to row 1 (2).
Table 1
Poverty measures
 
All
Self-employed
Salaried
Salaried formal
Salaried informal
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
Unsatisfied Basic Needs (%)
37.90
44.77
27.88
22.10
40.46
UBN (% sample)
37.90
26.57
11.33
6.15
5.18
Consumption poverty (%)
28.11
34.72
18.48
12.80
30.81
CP (% sample)
28.11
20.60
7.51
3.57
3.95
Source: author’s calculations based on ECV 2014
Figure 1 illustrates kernel density estimates of monthly earnings for salaried and self-employed workers (Table 2 reports the corresponding sample means along other descriptive statistics). Job income disparities between salaried and self-employed workers are clearly visible, as the earnings distribution for salaried workers is shifted to the right. Also, within salaried workers, household heads employed in the formal sector earn significantly more than their counterparts in the informal sector, as depicted in the right graph of Fig. 1.
Table 2
Descriptive statistics
 
Whole sample
Self-employed
Salaried workers
Salaried informal
Salaried formal
 
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Mean
Std. Dev.
Monthly earnings
523.89
527.05
382.22
466.59
730.72
541.70
414.79
296.22
875.98
566.61
Age (years)
44.29
12.09
46.69
12.30
40.80
10.88
40.03
11.35
41.15
10.63
Gender (male = 1)
0.79
0.40
0.78
0.41
0.81
0.39
0.73
0.44
0.84
0.36
Ethnic origin (minority = 1)
0.20
0.40
0.23
0.42
0.14
0.35
0.17
0.37
0.13
0.34
Living in couple (yes = 1)
0.74
0.44
0.73
0.44
0.75
0.43
0.67
0.47
0.79
0.41
Hh size
4.03
1.95
4.10
2.09
3.93
1.74
4.02
1.89
3.88
1.66
Remittances (yes = 1)
0.03
0.17
0.04
0.19
0.02
0.14
0.03
0.16
0.02
0.13
Number of other hh members working
0.66
0.82
0.62
0.84
0.72
0.79
0.68
0.82
0.73
0.77
Tenure (years)
15.36
13.85
19.11
15.01
9.90
9.63
8.94
9.80
10.34
9.52
Education
  Without formal schooling
0.06
0.24
0.09
0.28
0.02
0.15
0.04
0.20
0.01
0.12
  Some primary
0.15
0.36
0.20
0.40
0.08
0.27
0.14
0.35
0.05
0.22
  Primary completed
0.33
0.47
0.37
0.48
0.26
0.44
0.35
0.48
0.21
0.41
  Some secondary
0.16
0.36
0.15
0.36
0.16
0.37
0.22
0.41
0.14
0.34
  Secondary completed
0.16
0.37
0.11
0.32
0.23
0.42
0.17
0.38
0.25
0.43
  Post-secondary
0.14
0.35
0.07
0.25
0.25
0.43
0.08
0.27
0.33
0.47
Area of residence (area = 1)
  Urban
0.51
0.50
0.40
0.49
0.67
0.47
0.62
0.49
0.69
0.46
  North region
0.30
0.46
0.28
0.45
0.33
0.47
0.25
0.43
0.36
0.48
  Coast region
0.15
0.36
0.16
0.36
0.14
0.35
0.17
0.38
0.13
0.34
  Central region
0.30
0.46
0.30
0.46
0.32
0.47
0.36
0.48
0.29
0.46
  South region
0.24
0.43
0.27
0.44
0.21
0.41
0.21
0.41
0.21
0.41
Labor market
  Small firm
0.70
0.46
0.96
0.21
0.33
0.47
0.74
0.44
0.15
0.35
  Medium firm
0.08
0.27
0.04
0.19
0.15
0.35
0.15
0.35
0.15
0.35
  Large firm
0.22
0.41
0.01
0.09
0.52
0.50
0.11
0.31
0.71
0.45
  Managers
0.01
0.12
0.00
0.06
0.03
0.17
0.01
0.08
0.04
0.20
  Professionals
0.06
0.24
0.02
0.13
0.12
0.33
0.02
0.15
0.17
0.37
  Technicians
0.03
0.17
0.01
0.09
0.06
0.24
0.02
0.14
0.08
0.28
  Office workers
0.02
0.15
0.00
0.06
0.05
0.22
0.02
0.14
0.06
0.25
  Service workers
0.15
0.36
0.14
0.35
0.17
0.37
0.15
0.36
0.18
0.38
  Skilled agricultural workers
0.29
0.45
0.43
0.49
0.09
0.29
0.11
0.31
0.08
0.27
  Craft and related trades workers
0.15
0.36
0.16
0.37
0.15
0.36
0.24
0.43
0.10
0.31
  Plant and machine operators
0.10
0.30
0.07
0.25
0.15
0.35
0.17
0.38
0.13
0.34
  Elementary occupations workers
0.17
0.38
0.17
0.37
0.18
0.39
0.26
0.44
0.15
0.35
  Agriculture
0.36
0.48
0.51
0.50
0.13
0.34
0.16
0.36
0.12
0.33
  Mining
0.02
0.12
0.00
0.05
0.03
0.18
0.03
0.18
0.03
0.18
  Manufacturing
0.10
0.30
0.07
0.26
0.14
0.34
0.15
0.36
0.13
0.33
  Construction
0.10
0.30
0.11
0.32
0.07
0.26
0.11
0.31
0.06
0.23
  Commerce and trade
0.12
0.32
0.13
0.33
0.10
0.30
0.12
0.33
0.09
0.28
  Transport and communications
0.07
0.26
0.07
0.26
0.08
0.27
0.13
0.34
0.05
0.22
  Services
0.20
0.40
0.07
0.26
0.39
0.49
0.17
0.37
0.49
0.50
Observations
22,103
13,118
8,985
2,830
6,155
Values are proportions between 0 and 1, unless otherwise specified; income data in USD
Source: Author’s calculations based on ECV 2014
In Fig. 2, I plot the kernel distributions of household revenues for salaried and self-employed workers. The distributions are similar to those of monthly earnings. Since household heads’ earnings account, on average, for 69% of household incomes, it is not surprising to find higher poverty rates among informal workers.

4 Empirical specification

The aim of this article is to analyse the relationship between poverty and informal employment in Ecuador. In particular, it aims to address the following questions: Does being poor affect the probability of having informal employment? Is being an informal worker a determinant of poverty? That is, are informality and poverty interrelated? In this framework, informality and poverty are assumed to affect each other in both directions. On the one hand, informal employment affects the poverty status of the household mainly through low earnings. On the other hand, household poverty may be the main reason for a household head to accept informal employment, since they cannot afford to be unemployed.
Modeling this inverse relationship is usually challenging. First, the analysis needs to account for the potential endogeneity of household poverty and household head’s informal employment status, as well as for unobserved factors that may affect these two phenomena simultaneously. Second, focusing the analysis only on working individuals raises the problem of sample selection. Third, poverty is measured at the household level, while informality and other human capital variables are based on individual status. While the latter problem is handled by focusing the analysis on a sample of household heads (see Section 3), a simultaneous equations probit model with sample selection is well suited to tackling the first two issues. The model is specified as follows:
$$ y_{1i}=\gamma_{1}y_{2i}+ \beta_{1} X_{1i} +\varepsilon_{1i}, $$
(1)
$$ y_{2i}= \gamma_{2}y_{1i}+\beta_{2} X_{2i} +\varepsilon_{2i}, $$
(2)
$$ y_{3i}= \alpha z_{i} + \varepsilon_{3i}, $$
(3)
where y1i is a dummy variable indicating the ith household head’s employment status, i.e. formal/informal, y2i is a dummy variable indicating the ith household’s poverty status, and Xji is a vector of sociodemographic and work-related characteristics of the ith household head, with j = 1,2. Equation 3 is the selection equation, thus y3i is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the household head works and 0 otherwise. zi is a vector of sociodemographic characteristics similar to Xji, but not equal.5 The estimation of this model is thoroughly discussed by Mallar (1977).6 The model is estimated as a simultaneous equations maximum likelihood probit model with sample selection. Corrected standard errors are obtained by bootstrapping (1200 repetitions).

4.1 Explanatory variables

The variables used for the estimation are standard in the literature. In Eqs. 1 and 2, I control for economic sectors (ten classified according to the UN International Standard Industrial Classification), occupations (nine classified according to the ILO International Standard Classification of Occupations), tenure, tenure squared, gender of the household head, age of the household head, age squared, ethnic origin of the household head, educational attainment (six categories), whether the household is a remittance receiver, household size, share of other household members working, share of other household members working formally, firm-size variables, whether the household is located in an urban area, and geographical region.7
Equation 1 is identified by the exclusion of the number of other household members working and the dummy variable indicating the ethnic origin of the household head. While both of these variables are highly correlated with household poverty, they do not affect by themselves the decision to accept informal employment other than through household poverty. The approach builds on Amuedo-Dorantes (2004), arguing that these household-specific variables influence one’s behavior in the labor market only through household poverty, which captures households’ difficulty in covering the minimum living requirements defined by the poverty line—see also Nazier and Ramadan (2015).
Equation 2 is identified by the exclusion of the dummy variables indicating the size of the firm (with small size as the reference category). Again, while these variables are expected to affect the likelihood of working informally, they are not by themselves determinants of household poverty other than through the type of job held by the household head.8 Table 8 presents the definition for each variable used in the estimation.
The logic behind the use of these variables is that individual characteristics such as the respondent’s age, tenure and education are found to affect both informality and poverty. More experienced and educated workers are supposed to be more productive and have access to better-paid jobs. Firm and regional characteristics are also important. For instance, smaller firms with limited access to capital markets might be more inclined to hire workers on an informal basis in order to reduce labor-related costs. Industry of activity may also affect the duration of the services. Jobs in construction, tourism and agricultural sectors are characterized by their relatively short duration. In addition, poverty is mostly concentrated in rural areas that are mainly characterized by agricultural employment.
Finally, household characteristics such as household size and the number of household members working are also expected to affect the likelihood of poverty. For instance, while poverty increases with household size, it decreases with more household members working, due to their contribution to household income. However, with an increasing number of household members working informally, the likelihood of poverty may increase if informal work is coupled with low earnings.

5 Results

5.1 Salaried workers

Table 3 presents the results from the joint estimation of Eqs. 1 and 2. Several findings are worth discussing. First of all, both the poverty status and the informal employment condition of the household head have a positive and significant effect on the informality and poverty equations, respectively. That is, poor household heads are more likely to work informally, and household heads having informal employment, as wage or salaried employees, are more likely to be poor. These results are in line with those found by Amuedo-Dorantes (2004) in Chile and Devicienti et al. (2009) in Argentina.
Table 3
Simultaneous equation probit model: salaried workers
 
Informal employment
 
Household poverty
 
Coef.
Std.
Mg. effect
Std.
 
Coef.
Std.
Mg. effect
Std.
Household poverty
0.176*
0.083
0.052*
0.024
     
Informal employment
     
0.091***
0.023
0.027***
0.007
Age
−0.058***
0.014
−0.017***
0.004
 
−0.076***
0.012
−0.023***
0.004
Age squared
0.001***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
 
0.001***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
Living in couple (yes = 1)
−0.154***
0.068
−0.047***
0.021
 
−0.051***
0.059
−0.015***
0.018
Gender (male = 1)
−0.315***
0.131
−0.099***
0.044
 
0.195***
0.065
0.056***
0.018
Ethnic origin (minority = 1)
     
0.410***
0.047
0.135***
0.017
Household size
0.037***
0.018
0.011***
0.005
 
0.204***
0.011
0.061***
0.003
Number of hh members working
     
−0.167***
0.024
−0.050***
0.007
Share of hh members working formally
−0.398***
0.072
−0.117***
0.021
 
−0.307***
0.053
−0.092***
0.016
Remittance receiver household
0.177
0.189
0.055
0.063
 
−0.171
0.127
−0.048
0.033
Education level (ref. without formal schooling)
  Some primary
−0.064
0.120
−0.018
0.034
 
−0.029***
0.110
−0.009***
0.032
  Primary completed
−0.307***
0.154
−0.085***
0.040
 
−0.330***
0.102
−0.093***
0.027
  Some secondary
−0.346***
0.190
−0.092***
0.045
 
−0.398***
0.105
−0.106***
0.025
  Secondary completed
−0.585***
0.279
−0.150***
0.061
 
−0.590***
0.109
−0.154***
0.024
  Post-secondary
−0.802***
0.396
−0.198***
0.079
 
−0.772***
0.121
−0.195***
0.025
  Tenure
−0.041***
0.006
−0.012***
0.002
 
−0.015***
0.005
−0.005***
0.002
  Tenure squared
0.001***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
 
0.000***
0.000
0.000
0.000
  Medium firm
−0.926***
0.051
−0.202***
0.009
     
  Large firm
−1.782***
0.047
−0.508***
0.012
     
Economic sectors (ref. services)
  Mines
0.559***
0.101
0.193***
0.039
 
0.253**
0.087
0.082**
0.030
  Manufacturing
0.149**
0.066
0.046**
0.021
 
−0.021
0.059
−0.006
0.018
  Construction
0.390***
0.077
0.129***
0.028
 
0.124
0.072
0.039
0.023
  Commerce
0.086
0.068
0.026
0.021
 
0.129**
0.060
0.040**
0.019
  Transportation
0.739***
0.076
0.260***
0.029
 
0.071
0.078
0.022
0.024
  Agriculture
0.263**
0.088
0.083**
0.029
 
0.264***
0.073
0.085***
0.025
  Other
0.158
0.091
0.049
0.030
 
0.027
0.081
0.008
0.025
Occupations (ref. skill-agricultural workers)
  Managers
0.033
0.179
0.010
0.054
 
−0.399**
0.156
−0.102**
0.033
  Professionals
0.229
0.141
0.072
0.047
 
−0.002
0.117
−0.001
0.035
  Technicians
0.085
0.139
0.026
0.043
 
−0.263**
0.111
−0.072**
0.027
  Office workers
−0.142
0.138
−0.040
0.037
 
−0.187
0.109
−0.052
0.028
  Service workers
0.180
0.102
0.055
0.033
 
−0.068
0.085
−0.020
0.024
  Craft and related trades workers
0.517***
0.096
0.171***
0.035
 
−0.033
0.088
−0.010
0.026
  Plant and machine operators
0.266**
0.099
0.084**
0.033
 
−0.224**
0.086
−0.063**
0.022
  Elementary occupations workers
0.170
0.087
0.052
0.028
 
0.017
0.079
0.005
0.024
  Urban
−0.032
0.170
−0.010
0.050
 
−0.491
0.036
−0.155
0.012
Regions (ref. coastal region)
  North region
−0.338***
0.075
−0.095***
0.020
 
−0.622***
0.042
−0.170***
0.010
  Central region
0.072
0.090
0.022
0.028
 
−0.731***
0.052
−0.174***
0.009
  South region
−0.051
0.075
−0.015
0.021
 
−0.596***
0.048
−0.154***
0.010
R squared
0.0002
    
0.0001
   
No. observations
8,985
    
8,985
   
Overidentification test (nR2 )
1.797
    
0.8985
   
\({\chi ^{2}_{2}}\) at 5% significance level
5.991
    
5.991
   
Bootstrapped standard errors. 1200 repetitions; ***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05
Second, one can see that informal salaried work is less likely among more tenured household heads. Indeed, experience is of high value in a market in which 50% of workers have acquired, at most, primary school education. In this respect, the role of education is of particular importance, since the higher the level of education the less likely is the household head to work informally, and also the less likely she or he is to be poor. In fact, having post-secondary education decreases the probability of being an informal salaried worker by 20% and the probability of being poor by the same proportion, compared to those workers without formal education.
Informal salary employment is more frequent in low-productivity and low-income sectors in which low-skilled workers are in higher demand. This is, for instance, the case of the transportation and construction sectors, and for small firms that may need to reduce labor costs. Indeed, medium- and large-size firms, compared to small firms, are subject to more institutional control and face the prospect of disciplinary action from the government. Thus, informal salaried work is less likely to occur there. This fact is also confirmed from the descriptive statistics—74% of informal salaried work is concentrated in small firms.
It is also interesting to see how minorities (Afro-American and indigenous people) are more likely to be in poverty than mestizos or white people. Ethnic segregation is a common feature of the Ecuadorian labor market. It is stronger when one takes into account that ethnic minorities face pre-market discrimination. They have, in general, limited access to education and health services, and are concentrated mainly in rural areas (Canelas and Salazar 2014; Atal et al. 2009).
Finally, the regional dummies capture geographical differences and region-specific shocks that influence the informality and poverty status of the household. For instance, household poverty, as measured by the IBN index, is more frequent in the coastal region than in the rest of the country. The coastal region employs low-skilled labor for agriculture and fishing, particularly on cacao and banana plantations, rice fields, in the tuna industry and on shrimp farms. The high dependence on agriculture and fishing and its geographical location makes the region more vulnerable to natural phenomena such as El Niño, which in turn increases the incidence of poverty. In addition to this, the economy relies heavily on tourism, making the labor market more inclined towards short-term/seasonal occupations than the rest of the country. On the other hand, informal salaried work seems 10% less likely in the northern region of the country compared to the coastal region, and equally likely in all other regions.
These findings support the view of informal salaried work as a second-best strategy that substitutes for the lack of formal employment and to which individuals turn when they face difficulties meeting their basic needs. Labor formalization in the covered sector in Ecuador has notably increased in recent years. According to Cruces et al. (2015), the percentage of wage/salaried workers registered with the system’s contributory scheme rose from 33.0% in 2003 to 54.7% in 2012. A recent report from the ILO (2014) attributes the positive trend in wage labor formalization, mostly since 2007, to a set of policies designed to improve working conditions. The measures include, among other things, the expansion of health insurance for children under the age of 18 and spouses of registered workers, mortgage loans for affiliated members, an active minimum wage policy and the strengthening of labor inspection offices. It is therefore possible that those workers who remain informal have no other option than to do so.

5.2 Self-employed

The previous analysis focused only on salaried employees, with the definition of informality relying on whether the firms in which these employees work comply with the legislation. However, as mentioned above, salaried workers represent only 40% of the working population. The remaining 60% are self-employed workers.
Since this group of workers is more heterogeneous than the group of salaried workers, as shown in the descriptive statistics, estimating the determinants of self-employment will provide us with a clearer picture of the informal sector in the country.
Table 4 shows the results of the joint estimation of Eqs. 1 and 2 using the whole sample of workers. Several points are worth noting. First, both the poverty status and informal employment condition of the household head have a positive and significant effect on the informality and poverty equations, respectively. This is similar to the results of the estimations using only salaried workers (specification 1). However, the marginal effect of poverty on informal employment is multiplied by two in this specification.
Table 4
Simultaneous equation probit model: all workers
 
Informal employment
 
Household poverty
 
Coef.
Std.
Mg. effect
Std.
 
Coef.
Std.
Mg. effect
Std.
Household poverty
0.243***
0.061
0.095***
0.024
     
Informal employment
     
0.039***
0.011
0.014***
0.004
Age
0.071***
0.012
0.028***
0.005
 
−0.062***
0.007
−0.023***
0.003
Age squared
−0.001***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
 
0.000***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
Living in couple (yes = 1)
0.197***
0.044
0.078***
0.018
 
−0.205***
0.033
−0.077***
0.012
Gender (male = 1)
−0.169**
0.075
−0.066**
0.029
 
0.210***
0.036
0.075***
0.012
Ethnic origin (minority = 1)
     
0.402***
0.026
0.153***
0.010
Number of hh members working
     
−0.184***
0.015
−0.067***
0.006
Share of hh members working formally
−0.255***
0.037
−0.100***
0.014
 
−0.169***
0.030
−0.062***
0.011
Household size
−0.018
0.013
−0.007
0.005
 
0.183***
0.006
0.067***
0.002
Remittance receiver household
0.221**
0.078
0.084**
0.029
 
−0.451***
0.066
−0.147***
0.019
Education level (ref. without formal schooling)
  Some primary
0.037
0.070
0.014
0.027
 
−0.255***
0.046
−0.090***
0.015
  Primary completed
0.107
0.078
0.042
0.031
 
−0.626***
0.043
−0.215***
0.014
  Some secondary
0.135
0.084
0.053
0.032
 
−0.682***
0.048
−0.218***
0.013
  Secondary completed
0.200***
0.093
0.077***
0.035
 
−0.873***
0.052
−0.266***
0.012
  Post-secondary
0.370***
0.109
0.140***
0.039
 
−1.097***
0.062
−0.310***
0.012
  Tenure
0.030***
0.003
0.012***
0.001
 
−0.013***
0.003
−0.005***
0.001
  Tenure squared
0.000***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
 
0.000***
0.000
0.000***
0.000
  Medium firm
−1.541***
0.038
−0.512***
0.008
     
  Large firm
−2.766***
0.051
−0.759***
0.005
     
Economic sectors (ref. services)
  Mines
−0.195
0.145
−0.078
0.058
 
0.335***
0.080
0.129***
0.032
  Manufacturing
0.365***
0.056
0.137***
0.020
 
−0.042
0.048
−0.015
0.017
  Construction
1.101***
0.059
0.350***
0.013
 
0.057
0.053
0.021
0.020
  Commerce
0.400***
0.042
0.150***
0.015
 
−0.014
0.045
−0.005
0.017
  Transportation
0.717***
0.065
0.250***
0.019
 
0.058
0.057
0.022
0.021
  Agriculture
1.206***
0.071
0.429***
0.021
 
0.307***
0.053
0.114***
0.020
  Other
−0.517***
0.059
−0.204***
0.022
 
0.054
0.060
0.020
0.022
Occupations (ref. skill-agricultural workers):
  Managers
0.032
0.145
0.013
0.056
 
−0.499***
0.129
−0.160***
0.034
  Professionals
0.216*
0.104
0.083*
0.039
 
−0.145
0.082
−0.051
0.028
  Technicians
0.049
0.113
0.019
0.044
 
−0.337***
0.088
−0.114***
0.027
  Office workers
−0.539***
0.129
−0.212***
0.049
 
−0.237**
0.091
−0.082**
0.029
  Service workers
0.506***
0.074
0.188***
0.025
 
−0.134**
0.056
−0.048**
0.020
  Craft and related trades workers
−0.001
0.073
0.000
0.029
 
−0.037
0.056
−0.013
0.020
  Plant and machine operators
−0.262**
0.086
−0.104**
0.034
 
−0.254***
0.061
−0.089***
0.020
  Elementary occupations workers
0.200***
0.059
0.077***
0.022
 
0.063
0.040
0.023
0.015
  Urban
0.090
0.051
0.035
0.020
 
−0.551
0.024
−0.200
0.009
Regions (ref. coastal region)
  North region
0.163***
0.044
0.063***
0.017
 
−0.584***
0.026
−0.200***
0.008
  Central region
0.055
0.058
0.022
0.022
 
−0.772***
0.032
−0.241***
0.008
  South region
0.290***
0.051
0.111***
0.019
 
−0.641***
0.027
−0.214***
0.008
R squared
0.0000
    
0.0000
   
No. observations
22,103
    
22,103
   
Overidentification test (nR2 )
0.0000
    
0.0000
   
\({\chi ^{2}_{2}}\) at 5% significance level
5.991
    
5.991
   
Bootstrapped standard errors. 1200 repetitions; ***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05
Second, more educated persons seem more likely to work informally (being self-employed). Similarly, professional workers are also more likely to be self-employed. This result is worth discussing since, together with the positive significant coefficient of household poverty, it suggests that neither segmented nor competitive labor market models may entirely explain the causes and consequences of informal work in the country. In other words, it suggests that the Ecuadorian labor market is composed of at least two sub-segments. The first is mostly characterized by economically constrained workers, probably low-skilled, for whom the economic status of the household plays a role in the decision to work informally. The second sub-segment is composed of those high-skilled workers for whom economic constraints, here captured by poverty status, may not be the reason for becoming self-employed. Indeed, it is possible that high-skilled workers in Ecuador have an incentive to become self-employed, if by doing so they end up with higher earnings, more satisfaction in their jobs and/or better working conditions (e.g., flexible working hours) than if they were salaried workers.
This paper argues that the Ecuadorian labor market exhibits the characteristics of a heterogeneous market, in which informal work is both a demand-led phenomenon and a voluntary and primarily supply-led form of employment—i.e., a last-resource option for low-skilled and income-constrained workers and a voluntary choice for more educated and entrepreneurial ones.
Finally, it is worth noting the effect of remittances not only in alleviating poverty but also in increasing the likelihood of self-employment. In the late 1990s, Ecuador suffered one of the worst macroeconomic and financial crises in its history, which resulted in the adoption of the US dollar in January 2000. The destruction of wealth in the wake of the crisis and the concomitant loss of jobs set off the largest emigration wave in Ecuador’s history (Jacome 2004). As a consequence, during the first half of the 2000s, the amount of remittances received by Ecuador was comparable to oil revenues and allowed households to recover from the crisis. Since access to credit markets is limited in the country, it is possible that remittances have played an important role in alleviating liquidity constraints faced by Ecuadorian entrepre- neurs. However, more research is needed concerning the mechanisms through which remittances affect self-employment.

5.3 Low-skilled versus high-skilled workers

To further study the effects of education on poverty and self-employment, Eqs. 1 and 2 are re-estimated separately for workers with less than secondary education and for those with secondary or post-secondary education. These estimates are particularly important as they shed more light on the hypothesis of a heterogeneous labor market in Ecuador.
The results in Table 5 show that poverty increases the likelihood of informal work among low-skilled workers by 10%, and that it has no significant effect on informal work among high-skilled workers, suggesting that for this group of workers the motivations for self-employment are not related to the economic status of the household.
Table 5
Simultaneous equation probit model by educational level
 
Self-employment
Household poverty
 
Coef.
Mg. effect
Coef.
Mg. effect
High-skill workers
 
0.097
0.022
0.005
0.001
 
(0.125)
(0.029)
(0.017)
(0.004)
Low-skill workers
 
0.270***
0.086***
0.054***
0.022***
 
(0.074)
(0.023)
(0.014)
(0.006)
Overidentification test (nR2)
High-skill workers
2.673
 
0.668
 
Low-skill workers
0.000
  
0.000
\({\chi ^{2}_{2}}\) at 5% significance level
5.991
 
5.991
 
Bootstrapped standard errors. 1200 repetitions
***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05
From a policy perspective, this result shows the heterogeneity of the Ecuadorian labor market and the need for public policies targeting specific groups of workers.

6 Robustness checks

6.1 Consumption poverty line

As discussed in Section 3, the use of the UBN indicator to define poverty is not free from criticism, mainly because the likelihood of being categorized as poor when using the UBN may increase with the number of variables used to construct the index.
In order to verify the validity of the results, I re-estimate Eqs. 1 and 2 using the official consumption poverty line as a measure of poverty. The estimates, presented in Table 6, reinforce again the main conclusion of the paper.
Table 6
Simultaneous equation probit model: consumption poverty line
 
Salaried workers
All workers
 
Informal employment
Household poverty
Informal employment
Household poverty
 
Coef.
Mg. effect
Coef.
Mg. effect
Coef.
Mg. effect
Coef.
Mg. effect
 
0.158*
0.046*
0.176***
0.028***
0.228***
0.090***
0.086***
0.023***
 
(0.080)
(0.024)
(0.026)
(0.004)
(0.058)
(0.023)
(0.012)
(0.003)
R squared
0.0002
 
0.0003
 
0.0000
 
0.0000
 
No. observations
8,985
 
8,985
 
22,103
 
22,103
 
Overidentification test (nR2 )
1.797
 
2.696
 
0.0000
 
0.0000
 
\({\chi ^{2}_{2}}\) at 5% significance level
5.991
 
5.991
 
5.991
 
5.991
 
Bootstrapped standard errors. 1200 repetitions; ***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05

6.2 Different specifications

In the specification used above, I have controlled for the double causality between poverty and informality using a simultaneous maximum likelihood probit model. In order to verify the validity of the results, I also estimate Eqs. 1 and 2 using three different specifications, for both informal salaried workers and self-employed. Columns 1–4 of Table 7 show the results of the univariate probit model without controlling for endogeneity. In columns 5–8, endogeneity is corrected by means of a maximum likelihood bivariate probit model. The last two columns show the results using a 2SLS linear IV model. The validity of the exclusion restrictions is not directly testable in the bivariate probit model, so I report diagnostic tests for the linear probability model using the same set of instruments as in Section 4.9
Table 7
Robustness checks
 
Univariate probit
Bivariate probit
2SLS
 
Informal employment
Household poverty
Informal employment
Household poverty
Informal employment
Household poverty
 
Coef
Mg effect
Coef
Mg effect
Coef
Mg effect
Coef
Mg effect
Coef
Coef
 
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
(7)
(8)
(9)
(10)
A. IBN
  Salaried workers
   Household poverty
0.19***
0.06***
  
1.01***
0.24**
   
0.16*
 
(0.04)
(0.01)
  
(0.06)
(0.02)
  
(0.07)
 
   Informal employment
  
0.23***
0.07***
  
0.30***
0.08***
 
0.04***
   
(0.04)
(0.01)
  
(0.06)
(0.02)
 
(0.01)
   Tests of overidentifying restrictions:
   Sargan (score) \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.545419 (p = 0.4602)
0.547488 (p = 0.4590)
   Basmann \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.543085 (p = 0.4612)
0.547488 (p = 0.4593)
  All workers
   Household poverty
−0.01
−0.00
  
0.34***
0.06***
  
0.13***
 
 
(0.03)
(0.01)
  
(0.10)
0.02)
  
(0.03)
 
   Self-employment
  
0.02
0.01
  
0.11***
0.03***
 
0.04***
   
(0.02)
(0.01)
  
(0.04)
(0.01)
 
(0.01)
Tests of overidentifying restrictions:
Sargan (score) \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.011146 (p = 0.9159)
0.680322 (p = 0.4095)
   Basmann \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.011127 (p = 0.9160)
0.679173 (p = 0.4099)
B. Consumption poverty
  Salaried workers
   Household poverty
0.32***
0.10***
  
1.10*
0.26*
  
0.21*
 
 
(0.05)
(0.01)
  
(0.45)
(0.12)
  
(0.10)
 
   Informal employment
  
0.37***
0.06***
  
0.56***
0.10***
 
0.13***
   
(0.04)
(0.01)
  
(0.07)
(0.01)
 
(0.03)
   Tests of overidentifying restrictions:
   Sargan (score) \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.653192 (p = 0.4190)
1.92961 (p = 0.1648)
   Basmann \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.650404 (p = 0.4200)
1.92986 (p = 0.1657)
  All workers
   Household poverty
0.02
0.01
  
0.27***
0.05***
  
0.14**
 
 
(0.03)
(0.01)
  
(0.08)
(0.02)
  
(0.04)
 
   Self-employment
  
0.09**
0.02**
  
0.26***
0.06
 
0.08***
   
(0.03)
(0.01)
  
(0.04)
(0.01)
 
(0.01)
   Tests of overidentifying restrictions:
   Sargan (score) \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.192641 (p = 0.6607)
1.50146 (p = 0.2204)
   Basmann \({\chi ^{2}_{1}}\)
        
0.192303 (p = 0.6610)
1.49898 (p = 0.2208)
Bootstrapped standard errors. 500 repetitions. *p < 0.05, **p < 0.01, ***p < 0.001. Instruments: firm size (small, medium, large), number of other household members working, ethnic origin of the hh head
Complete estimates available from the author upon request
While the estimates have different coefficients, as for salaried workers, their sign and significance level remain similar to the previous estimates in all specifications, and thus the main conclusion of the paper, for this group of workers, remains unchanged.
Regarding the estimates using self-employment as the definition of informality, the only results that differ from those in Section 5 are those using the univariate probit model. In fact, while self-employment is still positive and statistically significant in the poverty equation, the role of poverty in the likelihood of informal employment is less clear. Depending on the definition of poverty used, the variable is either positive or negative, but in both cases it is not statistically significant. These results highlight the importance of taking into account the simultaneous two-way relationship between these two phenomena.

7 Discussion

These results show, first, the relevance of poverty for both informal salaried work and self-employment in Ecuador. In particular, household poverty, as measured both by the IBN index and household consumption, increases the likelihood of engaging in informal salaried work and self-employment by around 5 and 10%, respectively.10 This finding, along with the concentration of informal workers in low-productivity and low-income sectors, supports the view of informal work as a second-best strategy that substitutes for the lack of formal employment and to which individuals turn when they face difficulties meeting their basic needs. Indeed, in the absence of unemployment benefits, workers have no choice but to work, even if they have to do it informally—in particular, when the fraction of non-labor income is small, as it is in Ecuador.
Nonetheless, as noted by Cortés Aguilar et al. (2013), at least in Latin American countries, the cate- gories of informality and self-employment are too broad to be conclusive. Indeed, when looking at the determinants of self-employment one notices that high-skilled workers, proxied by educational level, are 12% more likely to be self-employed than those without formal education. Further, when the sample is divided into low- and high-skilled workers, the results show that poverty increases the likelihood of informal work among low-skilled workers by around 10%, and that it has no significant effect on informal work among high-skilled workers. These findings support the view of informal work as a voluntary choice for this group of workers.
While, on average, informal employment is associated with lower earnings than formal employment, as shown in Table 2, the evidence also shows that this is not the case for all groups of workers. As shown in Fig. 1, there is an overlap between the earnings distribution of formal and informal workers.
Additionally, non-monetary incentives are likely to play a role. The study of Cortés Aguilar et al. (2013) on job satisfaction among different Latin American countries shows, among other things, that self-employed professionals and business owners are more satisfied than salaried workers with their incomes, while self-employed farmers and fisherman are less satisfied with their jobs and incomes. Along this line, a report from the World Bank (2012) found that being their “own boss” and having “flexible time schedules” are the main motivations for informality across small-firm owners and entrepreneurs in Ecuador. The study also reports that only around 30% of this group cite the inability to find wage employment as a reason for informality. This evidence, coupled with the results of this study, reinforce the idea of a heterogeneous labor market in which some workers are better-off as self-employed while others are worse-off.
Second, the results also show that both informal salaried work and self-employment increase the likelihood of household poverty by 3 and 2%, respectively. While the effects of informality on poverty are lower than the effects of poverty on informality, the results raise concerns about the implications of informal work (salaried or self-employment) for poverty. In particular, informal work, here defined as the lack of social security coverage, concerns more than 60% of the population under study. With a high percentage of low-skilled workers and with poverty rates being the highest among this group of workers, future implications of the lack of retirement benefits are worrisome.
These results suggest several broader implications and avenues for future research. For one, consistent with the literature on heterogeneous labor markets, these results show the relevance of diversity among informal workers in the country and speak to the need for public policies targeting different groups of workers. The findings further offer additional evidence on the relevance of education for decreasing poverty and its effect on informality. In particular, they show the need of incentives appealing to various levels of skills. In terms of future analysis, the findings highlight the need for studies looking at small-firm survival in Ecuador, as well as the role of remittances in alleviating liquidity constraints faced by entrepreneurs in the country.

8 Conclusion

This study uses microeconomic data from the Ecuadorian Family Expenditure survey of 2014 to study the determinants of poverty and informality in the country, taking into account the possible two-way relationship that exists between these two phenomena. The estimations confirm previous results in the literature that, despite controlling for many relevant variables, informality and poverty are correlated and so this double causality should be taken into account when studying these factors.
In Ecuador, as in many Latin American countries, a high proportion of informal employment is of poor quality. In general, informally employed workers are found to have a relatively low education level and low wages, which supports the idea that these workers have no choice but to work informally. However, the complexity of the informal sector supports the view of a heterogeneous informal market in which work in the informal sector is both a demand-led phenomenon and a voluntary and primarily supply-led form of employment. Informal work is both a last-resort option for low-skilled workers and a voluntary choice for better-educated and entrepreneurial workers.
From a policy perspective, since poverty and informality are interrelated, the results suggest that no public policy could effectively eliminate either of the two phenomena if nothing is also done to alleviate the other. It is clear, for instance, that poverty reduction could only be sustainable if more and better employment opportunities are created. For the vast majority of households in Ecuador, labor income is the main (if not the only) source of income. Thus, quality job creation through enterprise development, as well as investment in education and training, is of great importance.
Last but not least, policies aiming to increase fiscal revenues from the higher-paid segment of the informal sector (salary jobs or self-employment) should be designed in such a way that they also provide incentives for these workers to become formal workers. Since more than 50% of informal workers are concentrated in small firms, measures to increase the incentives of small enterprises to become formal should also be part of these reforms.

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank the Editor and two anonymous referees for their valuable comments and suggestions on previous versions of this paper.
This study has been prepared within the UNU-WIDER pro- ject on ‘The growth-employment-poverty nexus in Latin America in the 2000s’. Part of this paper was written when the author was a Research Fellow at UNU-WIDER. A previous version of this article circulated as UNU-WIDER working paper.

Compliance with Ethical Standards

Conflict of interest

The author declares that she has no conflict of interest.
The opinions expressed in this article are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the UNU-WIDER, its Board of Directors, or the countries they represent.
Open Access This article is licensed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 IGO License, which permits any non-commercial use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the UNU-WIDER, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. If you remix, transform, or build upon this article or a part thereof, you must distribute your contributions under the same licence as the original.
The use of the UNU-WIDER’s name, and the use of the UNU-WIDER’s logo, shall be subject to a separate written licence agreement between the UNU-WIDER and the user and is not authorized as part of this CC-IGO licence. Note that the link provided above includes additional terms and conditions of the licence.
The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.
Appendix

Appendix

Table 8
Variables definition
Variable
Definition
Hh poverty
Dummy variable for poverty status of the hh (poor = 1)
Informal employment
Dummy variable for informal employment of the hh head (informal = 1)
Monthly earnings
Household head’s monthly earnings
Remittances
Dummy variable for receiving remittances (yes = 1)
Hh size
Number of persons in the household
Number of hh members working
Number of other household members working
Number of hh members working formally
Number of other household members with formal employment
Living in couple
Dummy variable for married or couples living together
Gender
Dummy variable for gender of the hh head (male = 1)
Ethnic origin
Dummy variable for ethnic origin of the hh head (minority = 1)
Age
Household head’s age in years
Education
  Without formal schooling
Dummy variable indicating no formal schooling
  Some primary
Dummy variable for some years of primary education
  Primary completed
Dummy variable for completed primary education
  Secondary
Dummy variable for some years of secondary education
  Secondary
Dummy variable for completed secondary education
  Post-secondary
Dummy variable for more than completed secondary education
Area of residence
  Urban
Dummy variable for urban residence
  North region
Dummy variable for northern region residence
  Coast region
Dummy variable for coastal region residence
  Central region
Dummy variable for central region residence
  South region
Dummy variable for southern region residence
Labor market
  Tenure
Years of tenure
  Small firm
Dummy variable if the firm has fewer than 10 workers
  Medium firm
Dummy variable if the firm has 10–49 workers
  Large firm
Dummy variable if the firm has more than 50 workers
  Agriculture
Dummy variable for the agriculture and fishing industries
  Mining
Dummy variable for the mining industry
  Manufacturing
Dummy variable for the manufacturing industry
  Construction
Dummy variable for the construction industry
  Commerce and trade
Dummy variable for the commerce and trade related services industry
  Transportation
Dummy variable for the transportation and communications industries
  Services
Dummy variable for personal and social services industries
  Managers
Dummy variable for managers and directors
  Professionals
Dummy variable for professionals
  Technicians
Dummy variable for technicians
  Office workers
Dummy variable for office workers
  Service workers
Dummy variable for service workers
  Skilled agricultural worker
Dummy variable for skilled agricultural workers
  Craft and related trades workers
Dummy variable for craft and related trades workers
  Plant and machine operators
Dummy variable for plant and machine operators
  Elementary occupations workers
Dummy variable for elementary occupations workers
Footnotes
1
Estimates based on the official consumption poverty line, considering informal salaried workers and self-employed together.
 
2
This indicator has already been calculated by the INEC and the variable is available in the dataset.
 
3
The poverty status of the households was obtained using the codes provided by the INEC.
 
4
In the second row, the proportions showed in columns 2 and 3 add to that of column 1, and those in columns 4 and 5 add to that in column 3.
 
5
The selection equations include age, age squared, marital status, educational attainment, a dummy variable indicating the number of children aged less than 5 years old, a dummy variable indicating whether the respondent is attending school, whether the household is a remittance receiver, and geographical region/area dummy variables. The selection equations are identified by the exclusion from the structural equations of the dummy variables indicating whether the respondent is attending school and the number of children under the age of 5 (Amuedo-Dorantes 2004).
 
6
See also Maddala (1983).
 
7
See variables definition on the Appendix.
 
8
Overidentification test statistics are provided in Section 5.
 
9
See Angrist (2001) and Heckman (1978) for a discussion of the methods.
 
10
Similar results were found for informal salaried work in Chile (3–6%).
 
Literature
go back to reference Amuedo-Dorantes, C. (2004). Determinants and poverty implications of informal sector work in Chile. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 52(2), 347–368.CrossRef Amuedo-Dorantes, C. (2004). Determinants and poverty implications of informal sector work in Chile. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 52(2), 347–368.CrossRef
go back to reference Angrist, J. D. (2001). Estimation of limited dependent variable models with dummy endogenous regressors: simple strategies for empirical practice. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 19(1), 2–16.CrossRef Angrist, J. D. (2001). Estimation of limited dependent variable models with dummy endogenous regressors: simple strategies for empirical practice. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 19(1), 2–16.CrossRef
go back to reference Atal, J. P., Ñopo, H., Winder, N. (2009). New century, old disparities: gender and ethnic wage gaps in Latin America. Working Paper 109, Inter-American Development Bank. Atal, J. P., Ñopo, H., Winder, N. (2009). New century, old disparities: gender and ethnic wage gaps in Latin America. Working Paper 109, Inter-American Development Bank.
go back to reference Canelas, C. (2014). Minimum wage and informality in Ecuador. Working Paper 2014/006, UNU-WIDER. Canelas, C. (2014). Minimum wage and informality in Ecuador. Working Paper 2014/006, UNU-WIDER.
go back to reference Canelas, C., & Salazar, S. (2014). Gender and ethnic inequalities in LAC countries. IZA Journal of Labor & Development, 3(1), 18.CrossRef Canelas, C., & Salazar, S. (2014). Gender and ethnic inequalities in LAC countries. IZA Journal of Labor & Development, 3(1), 18.CrossRef
go back to reference Chaudhuri, S., & Mukhopadhyay, U. (2010). Revisiting the informal sector: a general equilibrium approach. New York: Springer.CrossRef Chaudhuri, S., & Mukhopadhyay, U. (2010). Revisiting the informal sector: a general equilibrium approach. New York: Springer.CrossRef
go back to reference Cortés Aguilar, A., García Muñoz, T. M., Moro-Egido, A. I. (2013). Heterogeneous self-employment and satisfaction in Latin America. Journal of Economic Psychology, 39, 44–61.CrossRef Cortés Aguilar, A., García Muñoz, T. M., Moro-Egido, A. I. (2013). Heterogeneous self-employment and satisfaction in Latin America. Journal of Economic Psychology, 39, 44–61.CrossRef
go back to reference Cruces, G., Fields, G. S., Jaume, D., Viollaz, M. (2015). The growth–employment–poverty nexus in Latin America in the 2000s: Ecuador country study. Working Paper 76/2015, UNU-WIDER. Cruces, G., Fields, G. S., Jaume, D., Viollaz, M. (2015). The growth–employment–poverty nexus in Latin America in the 2000s: Ecuador country study. Working Paper 76/2015, UNU-WIDER.
go back to reference Cunningham, W., & Maloney, W. (2001). Heterogeneity among Mexican microenterprise sector: an application of factor and cluster analysis. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 50(1), 131–156.CrossRef Cunningham, W., & Maloney, W. (2001). Heterogeneity among Mexican microenterprise sector: an application of factor and cluster analysis. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 50(1), 131–156.CrossRef
go back to reference Devicienti, F., Groisman, F., Poggi, A. (2009). Informality and poverty: are these processes dynamically interrelated? Evidence from Argentina. Working Paper 146, ECINEQ. Devicienti, F., Groisman, F., Poggi, A. (2009). Informality and poverty: are these processes dynamically interrelated? Evidence from Argentina. Working Paper 146, ECINEQ.
go back to reference Fields, G. S. (1975). Rural–urban migration, urban unemployment and underemployment, and job-search activity in LDCs. Journal of Development Economics, 2 (2), 165–187.CrossRef Fields, G. S. (1975). Rural–urban migration, urban unemployment and underemployment, and job-search activity in LDCs. Journal of Development Economics, 2 (2), 165–187.CrossRef
go back to reference Gasparini, L., & Tornarolli, L. (2009). Labor informality in Latin America and the Caribbean: patterns and trends from household survey microdata. Desarrollo y Sociedad, 2009, 13–80.CrossRef Gasparini, L., & Tornarolli, L. (2009). Labor informality in Latin America and the Caribbean: patterns and trends from household survey microdata. Desarrollo y Sociedad, 2009, 13–80.CrossRef
go back to reference Günther, I., & Launov, A. (2012). Informal employment in developing countries: opportunity or last resort? Journal of Development Economics, 97(1), 88–98. Günther, I., & Launov, A. (2012). Informal employment in developing countries: opportunity or last resort? Journal of Development Economics, 97(1), 88–98.
go back to reference Harati, R. (2013). Heterogeneity in the Egyptian informal labour market: choice or obligation? Revue d’économie Politique123(4), 623–639.CrossRef Harati, R. (2013). Heterogeneity in the Egyptian informal labour market: choice or obligation? Revue d’économie Politique123(4), 623–639.CrossRef
go back to reference Harris, J. R., & Todaro, M. P. (1970). Migration, unemployment & development: a two-sector analysis. American Economic Review, 60(1), 126–142. Harris, J. R., & Todaro, M. P. (1970). Migration, unemployment & development: a two-sector analysis. American Economic Review, 60(1), 126–142.
go back to reference Heckman, J. J. (1978). Dummy endogenous variables in a simultaneous equation system. Econometrica, 46(4), 931–959.CrossRef Heckman, J. J. (1978). Dummy endogenous variables in a simultaneous equation system. Econometrica, 46(4), 931–959.CrossRef
go back to reference ILO. (2014). Trends in informal employment in Ecuador: 2009–2012. Notes on formalization. Geneva: International Labour Organization. ILO. (2014). Trends in informal employment in Ecuador: 2009–2012. Notes on formalization. Geneva: International Labour Organization.
go back to reference Jacome, L. (2004). The late 1990s financial crisis in Ecuador: institutional weaknesses, fiscal rigidities, and financial dollarization at work. Working Paper 04/12, IMF.CrossRef Jacome, L. (2004). The late 1990s financial crisis in Ecuador: institutional weaknesses, fiscal rigidities, and financial dollarization at work. Working Paper 04/12, IMF.CrossRef
go back to reference Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. The Manchester School, 22(2), 139–191.CrossRef Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. The Manchester School, 22(2), 139–191.CrossRef
go back to reference Loayza, N. V., Serven, L., Sugawara, N. (2009). Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean. Policy Research Working Paper 4888, World Bank. Loayza, N. V., Serven, L., Sugawara, N. (2009). Informality in Latin America and the Caribbean. Policy Research Working Paper 4888, World Bank.
go back to reference Maddala, G. (1983). Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Maddala, G. (1983). Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Mallar, C. D. (1977). The estimation of simultaneous probability models. Econometrica, 45(7), 1717–1722.CrossRef Mallar, C. D. (1977). The estimation of simultaneous probability models. Econometrica, 45(7), 1717–1722.CrossRef
go back to reference Maurizio, R. (2012). Labour informality in Latin America: the case of Argentina, Chile, Brazil and Peru. Working Paper 165, Brooks World Poverty Institute. Maurizio, R. (2012). Labour informality in Latin America: the case of Argentina, Chile, Brazil and Peru. Working Paper 165, Brooks World Poverty Institute.
go back to reference Nazier, H., & Ramadan, R. (2015). Informality and poverty: a causality dilemma with application to Egypt. Advances in Management and Applied Economics, 5(4), 1–4. Nazier, H., & Ramadan, R. (2015). Informality and poverty: a causality dilemma with application to Egypt. Advances in Management and Applied Economics, 5(4), 1–4.
go back to reference Paulson, A., & Townsend, R. (2005). Financial constraints and entrepreneurship: evidence from the Thai financial crisis. Economic Perspectives, 29(3), 34–48. Paulson, A., & Townsend, R. (2005). Financial constraints and entrepreneurship: evidence from the Thai financial crisis. Economic Perspectives, 29(3), 34–48.
go back to reference Webster, C., Wu, F., Zhang, F., Sarkar, C. (2016). Informality, property rights, and poverty in China’s ‘Favelas’. World Development, 78, 461–476.CrossRef Webster, C., Wu, F., Zhang, F., Sarkar, C. (2016). Informality, property rights, and poverty in China’s ‘Favelas’. World Development, 78, 461–476.CrossRef
go back to reference World Bank. (2012). Ecuador: the faces of informality. Washington, DC: World Bank. World Bank. (2012). Ecuador: the faces of informality. Washington, DC: World Bank.
go back to reference World Bank. (2013). World Development Report 2013: Jobs. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef World Bank. (2013). World Development Report 2013: Jobs. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Informality and poverty in Ecuador
Author
Carla Canelas
Publication date
19-12-2018
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Small Business Economics / Issue 4/2019
Print ISSN: 0921-898X
Electronic ISSN: 1573-0913
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0102-9

Other articles of this Issue 4/2019

Small Business Economics 4/2019 Go to the issue