Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Social Choice and Welfare 1/2023

27-12-2022 | Original Paper

Information disclosure under liability: an experiment on public bads

Authors: Julien Jacob, Eve-Angéline Lambert, Mathieu Lefebvre, Sarah Van Driessche

Published in: Social Choice and Welfare | Issue 1/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We experimentally investigate the impact of information disclosure on managing common harms that are caused jointly by a group of liable agents. Subjects interact in a public bad setting and must choose ex ante how much to contribute in order to reduce the probability of causing a common damage. If a damage occurs, subjects bear a part of the loss according to the liability-sharing rule in force. We consider two existing rules: a per capita rule and a proportional rule. Our aim is to analyze the relative impact of information disclosure under each rule. We show that information disclosure increases contributions only under a per capita rule. This result challenges the classical results regarding the positive effects of information disclosure, since we show that this impact may depend upon the legal context. We also show that while a proportional rule leads to higher contributions than a per capita one, the positive effect of disclosure on a per capita rule makes it as efficient as a proportional rule without information disclosure.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The 2004/35/CE Directive on environmental liability stipulates that “Member States may establish national rules covering cost allocation in cases of multiple party causation. Member States may take into account, in particular, the specific situation of users of products who might not be held responsible for environmental damage in the same conditions as those producing such products. In this case, apportionment of liability should be determined in accordance with national law.” Hence, Germany and France have both chosen to enforce a per capita sharing when several agents are responsible for a common harm (see German Federal Ministry of Justice (2022) paragraph 426 for the case of Germany, and Hocquet-Berg (2017) for the case of France).
 
2
The Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act (CERCLA), in its Section 113(f), allows for proportional liability in case of indivisible harm (see Kornhauser and Revesz 1989; Pinkowski 1996; Ferrey 2009). An example is the Colorado vs. ASARCO, Inc case in 1985.
 
3
Note here that if each tortfeasor invests the same amount, then the two rules are obviously equivalent.
 
4
Note that the terms “recognition mechanism” and “naming mechanism” could also have been used instead of “identification mechanism”.
 
5
Another example of such investments is provided by Foulon et al. (2002) as regards the pulp and paper industry in British Columbia (Canada): since 1990, plants are required to use a secondary wastewater treatment process if they are be allowed to operate.
 
6
As to the identification of the lowest contributors, in practice information is gathered about all contributions, but only the lowest contributors are made publicly identified. Considering again the example of water pollution in the UK, the Environment Agency yearly conducts a global assessment of pollution from water companies and publishes a ranking of them as regards their environmental performance. See Environment Agency of United Kingdom (2022) for an example.
 
7
Note also that some papers have investigated the channels through which information disclosure leads firms to reduce emissions. Konar and Cohen (1997) notably identified that a stock price decline due to information disclosure would lead firms to subsequently change their environmental behavior. The impact of such disclosure on firms’ financial performance has been analyzed in other papers (see e.g., Capelle-Blancard and Laguna 2010; Gonenc and Scholtens 2017).
 
8
Each subject can benefit from a reduced risk even if they did not contribute to it (non-excludable), and the fact that a subject enjoys that reduced risk (of having to pay for liability in case of harm) does not prevent another subject enjoying it as well (non-rivalrous). Thus, the two properties of a public good are satisfied in the case we consider.
 
9
Under severe law, subjects always have to compensate perfectly for any harm caused to others, i.e., the probability of detection is assumed to be 100%; under mild law, the probability of detection is 50% only.
 
10
In Andreoni and Petrie (2004), the composition of the groups changes every 8 periods, for a total of 40 periods.
 
11
We decided to give subjects 19 ECUs rather than 20 ECUs in order to avoid decisions based on heuristics such as focal points where subjects choose a given proportion (one quarter, one half, and so on) of their endowment (on this point, see notably Cohen et al. 1996).
 
12
The value of \(\alpha\) is not directly related to the value of the endowment (of 19 ECUS) but results from the following trade-off: a low value of \(\alpha\) leads to a high marginal benefit from investing, which may lead to a corner solution (\(x_{i}=19\)). Conversely, a high value of \(\alpha\) leads to a low marginal benefit from investing, which reduces both the levels of the equilibrium values of x (in each of the four treatments we consider, see later) but also the difference between these equilibrium values, which could cause difficulties for the comparison between treatments in the empirical analysis. Overall, the value of 0.19 is, in our setup, the value which makes the best trade-off between the necessity to have interior solutions, and sufficiently different equilibrium values.
 
13
Note that the possibility of reaching a zero probability when all the four agents make a maximum contribution of 19 has no impact on the equilibrium values of contribution (see later). Moreover, in the data, we can see that the perspective of escaping risk has not been seen as an attractive one (see Table 3 below).
 
14
To avoid the subjects needing mathematical skills in order to understand the function of probability, they were not given the functional form of that function but a table of all probabilities instead. See the instructions in Appendix A.1.
 
15
A stands for anonymous.
 
16
ID stands for information disclosure.
 
17
As pointed out by Samek and Sheremeta (2014), photos capture and preserve the appearance of the person but do not allow for communication, which may confound the effects of identification alone. In addition to the photo, we therefore included first names.
 
18
We follow Gächter and Renner (2010) for belief elicitation. Subjects earned 6 ECUs if they correctly (± 0.5 ECUs) predicted the average contribution of the three other members and 3 ECUs divided by the (absolute) estimation error otherwise.
 
19
The model could fit with monetary gains/losses, due to a variation in the firm’s brand image or reputation. However, our experimental design does not include the possibility for other pecuniary losses other than those due to liability in case of a loss occurring.
 
20
Many SMEs are managed by owner-managers, who have at least a personal responsibility for the decisions they make for their company. They are personally identified, and are personally impacted by what happens to their company. Decisions are thus closed to those which are made for an individual purpose. As an illustration, Afsah et al. 1996 show that firms are sensitive to the opinion of local communities. We can note that SMEs, like larger firms, may also be subject to reputational monetary gains or losses, which are not captured by our experiment. As a consequence, the impact of this additional benefit/cost on SMEs could be higher than the one we measure in this experiment.
 
21
Deffains and Fluet (2013) use the word (dis)esteem which holds through the others’ view of the agent’s ability to care about, and to contribute in reducing, the expected common loss. This agent’s concern about the loss could be included in the model, through an additional cost in (3) such as: \(-p(x_{i}) \theta H\), with \(\theta\) the degree of the agent’s concern for the loss (with \(\theta \ge 0\)). (Dis)esteem is based on the underlying rationale that others cannot observe \(\theta\), but they try to infer its value, especially through the information disclosed by the identification mechanism. So, esteem (resp. disesteem) plays a role when others think that we have a high (resp. low) value of \(\theta\). Hence, \(\theta\) is only an instrumental variable, and to ease the exposition we choose not to introduce it.
 
22
For simplicity, we only consider the case where no identification mechanism holds. However, we have to note that \(\beta _{i}=0\) also captures the case where an identification mechanism holds but the agent is not sensitive to their social image. But it is not of particular relevance to distinguish these two cases for our analysis.
 
23
From a formal point of view, this Prediction is obtained from the comparison between Eqs. (4) and (8) on the one hand, and Eqs. (6) and (9) on the other hand. From the former comparison, we can deduce the impact of social image on the incentives to contribute in case of per capita sharing. From the later comparison, we can deduce the impact in case of proportional sharing. In both cases, the additional incentives (provided by the identification mechanism) depend on \(\beta _i\), \(q^{r}(.)\), and \(\Delta ^{r}\). As a result, for \(\beta _i\) and \(q^{r}(.)\) given, \(\Delta ^{PC}>\Delta ^{PR}\) leads to Prediction 3. But this can only be a conjecture, which we justify by the above argumentation.
 
24
Unless specifically noted, we report the significance levels of a two-sided Mann-Whitney rank-sum test taking individual averages as the unit of observation. Given the sample size of 60 subjects per treatment and the averages and standard deviations presented in Table 3, we must acknowledge that the statistical power of two samples comparisons can be low and is around 57% depending on the test.
 
25
See Appendix A.3 for the distributions of contributions per treatment.
 
26
The p value is based on the difference between the average contribution of the first four periods in each group and the average contribution of the last four periods in each group by individuals.
 
27
All results are robust to the use of other specifications such as OLS or individual clustered standard errors and whether or not socio-demographic variables are included.
 
28
We used this lagged variable rather than the subject’s belief about the average contribution of the other group members since we obtain the same results no matter which variable is employed, but the effects are more statistically significant with the former.
 
29
See column (3) of Table 8 in Appendix A.4.
 
30
Note that we used two different variables to account for subjects’ preferences toward risk (i.e., Risk-seeking and Gamble). There is no problem of correlation between these two variables as is often the case when risk attitudes are measured using different methods (incentivized and non-incentivized elicitations) (Attanasi et al. 2018; Crosetto and Filippin 2016).
 
31
See the example of Indonesia in Afsah et al. (1996).
 
Literature
go back to reference Afsah S, Laplante B, Wheeler D (1996) Controlling industrial pollution—a new paradigm. The World Bank—Policy Research Working Paper 1672 Afsah S, Laplante B, Wheeler D (1996) Controlling industrial pollution—a new paradigm. The World Bank—Policy Research Working Paper 1672
go back to reference Andreoni J (1988) Why free ride?: Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. J Public Econ 37:291–304CrossRef Andreoni J (1988) Why free ride?: Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. J Public Econ 37:291–304CrossRef
go back to reference Andreoni J, Petrie R (2004) Public goods experiments without confidentiality: a glimpse into fund-raising. J Public Econ 88:1605–1623CrossRef Andreoni J, Petrie R (2004) Public goods experiments without confidentiality: a glimpse into fund-raising. J Public Econ 88:1605–1623CrossRef
go back to reference Angelova V, Armantier O, Attanasi G, Hiriart Y (2014) Relative performance of liability rules: experimental evidence. Theory Decis 77:531–556CrossRef Angelova V, Armantier O, Attanasi G, Hiriart Y (2014) Relative performance of liability rules: experimental evidence. Theory Decis 77:531–556CrossRef
go back to reference Attanasi G, Georgantzís N, Rotondi V, Vigani D (2018) Lottery- and survey-based risk attitudes linked through a multichoice elicitation task. Theory Decis 84:341–372CrossRef Attanasi G, Georgantzís N, Rotondi V, Vigani D (2018) Lottery- and survey-based risk attitudes linked through a multichoice elicitation task. Theory Decis 84:341–372CrossRef
go back to reference Attanasi G, Concina L, Kamaté C, Rotondi V (2020) Firm’s protection against disasters: are investment and insurance substitutes or complements? Theory Decis 88:121–151CrossRef Attanasi G, Concina L, Kamaté C, Rotondi V (2020) Firm’s protection against disasters: are investment and insurance substitutes or complements? Theory Decis 88:121–151CrossRef
go back to reference Bennear LS, Olmstead SM (2008) The impacts of the “right to know": information disclosure and the violation of drinking water standards. J Environ Econ Manag 56:117–130CrossRef Bennear LS, Olmstead SM (2008) The impacts of the “right to know": information disclosure and the violation of drinking water standards. J Environ Econ Manag 56:117–130CrossRef
go back to reference Bernasconi M, Corazzini L, Seri R (2014) Reference dependent preferences, hedonic adaptation and tax evasion: does the tax burden matter? J Econ Psychol 40:103–118CrossRef Bernasconi M, Corazzini L, Seri R (2014) Reference dependent preferences, hedonic adaptation and tax evasion: does the tax burden matter? J Econ Psychol 40:103–118CrossRef
go back to reference Blackman A, Afsah S, Ratunanda D (2004) How do public disclosure pollution control programs work? Evidence from Indonesia. Hum Ecol Rev 11:235–246 Blackman A, Afsah S, Ratunanda D (2004) How do public disclosure pollution control programs work? Evidence from Indonesia. Hum Ecol Rev 11:235–246
go back to reference Blanco E, Lopez MC, Walker JM (2016) The opportunity costs of conservation with deterministic and probabilistic degradation externalities. Environ Resour Econ 64:255–273CrossRef Blanco E, Lopez MC, Walker JM (2016) The opportunity costs of conservation with deterministic and probabilistic degradation externalities. Environ Resour Econ 64:255–273CrossRef
go back to reference Blanco E, Haller T, Walker JM (2017) Externalities in appropriation: responses to probabilistic losses. Exp Econ 20:793–808CrossRef Blanco E, Haller T, Walker JM (2017) Externalities in appropriation: responses to probabilistic losses. Exp Econ 20:793–808CrossRef
go back to reference Boun My K, Ouvrard B (2019) Nudge and tax in an environmental public goods experiment: Does environmental sensitivity matter? Resour Energy Econ 55:24–48CrossRef Boun My K, Ouvrard B (2019) Nudge and tax in an environmental public goods experiment: Does environmental sensitivity matter? Resour Energy Econ 55:24–48CrossRef
go back to reference Bramoullé Y, Orset C (2018) Manufacturing doubt. J Environ Econ Manag 90:119–133CrossRef Bramoullé Y, Orset C (2018) Manufacturing doubt. J Environ Econ Manag 90:119–133CrossRef
go back to reference Brown J (1973) Towards an economic theory of liability. J Legal Stud 2:323–349CrossRef Brown J (1973) Towards an economic theory of liability. J Legal Stud 2:323–349CrossRef
go back to reference Brown-Kruse J, Hummels D (1993) Gender effects in laboratory public goods contributions. J Econ Behav Organ 22:255–267CrossRef Brown-Kruse J, Hummels D (1993) Gender effects in laboratory public goods contributions. J Econ Behav Organ 22:255–267CrossRef
go back to reference Buchens C, Deffains B, Palermo A (2019) Stigmatization, liability and public enforcement of law. Revue d’economie politique 129:235–259CrossRef Buchens C, Deffains B, Palermo A (2019) Stigmatization, liability and public enforcement of law. Revue d’economie politique 129:235–259CrossRef
go back to reference Calabresi G (1970) The cost of accidents, a legal and economic analysis. Yale University Press, New Haven Calabresi G (1970) The cost of accidents, a legal and economic analysis. Yale University Press, New Haven
go back to reference Capelle-Blancard G, Laguna M-A (2010) How does the stock market respond to chemical disasters? J Environ Econ Manag 59:192–205CrossRef Capelle-Blancard G, Laguna M-A (2010) How does the stock market respond to chemical disasters? J Environ Econ Manag 59:192–205CrossRef
go back to reference Cohen MD, Burkhart R, Dosi G, Egidi M, Marengo L, Warglien M, Winter S (1996) Routines and other recurring action patterns of organizations: contemporary research issues. Ind Corp Change 5(3):653–698CrossRef Cohen MD, Burkhart R, Dosi G, Egidi M, Marengo L, Warglien M, Winter S (1996) Routines and other recurring action patterns of organizations: contemporary research issues. Ind Corp Change 5(3):653–698CrossRef
go back to reference Crosetto P, Filippin A (2016) A theoretical and experimental appraisal of four risk elicitation methods. Exp Econ 19:613–641CrossRef Crosetto P, Filippin A (2016) A theoretical and experimental appraisal of four risk elicitation methods. Exp Econ 19:613–641CrossRef
go back to reference Croson RTA (2007) Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: evidence from linear public goods games. Econ Inq 45:199–216CrossRef Croson RTA (2007) Theories of commitment, altruism and reciprocity: evidence from linear public goods games. Econ Inq 45:199–216CrossRef
go back to reference Croson R, Fatas E, Neugebauer T, Morales AJ (2015) Excludability: a laboratory study on forced ranking in team production. J Econ Behav Organ 114:13–26CrossRef Croson R, Fatas E, Neugebauer T, Morales AJ (2015) Excludability: a laboratory study on forced ranking in team production. J Econ Behav Organ 114:13–26CrossRef
go back to reference de Groot JI, Schuitema G (2012) How to make the unpopular popular? Policy characteristics, social norms and the acceptability of environmental policies. Environ Sci Policy 19–20:100–107CrossRef de Groot JI, Schuitema G (2012) How to make the unpopular popular? Policy characteristics, social norms and the acceptability of environmental policies. Environ Sci Policy 19–20:100–107CrossRef
go back to reference Deffains B, Fluet C (2013) Legal liability when individuals have moral concerns. J Law Econ Organ 29:930–955CrossRef Deffains B, Fluet C (2013) Legal liability when individuals have moral concerns. J Law Econ Organ 29:930–955CrossRef
go back to reference Deffains B, Espinosa R, Fluet C (2019) Laws and norms: experimental evidence with liability rules. Int Rev Law Econ 60:1–16CrossRef Deffains B, Espinosa R, Fluet C (2019) Laws and norms: experimental evidence with liability rules. Int Rev Law Econ 60:1–16CrossRef
go back to reference Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2002) Sex differences and statistical stereotyping in attitudes toward financial risk. Evol Hum Behav 23:281–295CrossRef Eckel CC, Grossman PJ (2002) Sex differences and statistical stereotyping in attitudes toward financial risk. Evol Hum Behav 23:281–295CrossRef
go back to reference Endres A, Bertram R (2006) The development of care technology under liability law. Int Rev Law Econ 26:503–518CrossRef Endres A, Bertram R (2006) The development of care technology under liability law. Int Rev Law Econ 26:503–518CrossRef
go back to reference Endres A, Bertram R, Rundshagen B (2008) Environmental liability law and induced technical change: the role of spillovers. J Inst Theor Econ 164:254–279CrossRef Endres A, Bertram R, Rundshagen B (2008) Environmental liability law and induced technical change: the role of spillovers. J Inst Theor Econ 164:254–279CrossRef
go back to reference Ferrey S (2009) Inverting the law: superfund hazardous substance liability and supreme court reversal of all federal circuits. William Mary Environ Law Policy Rev 33:633–722 Ferrey S (2009) Inverting the law: superfund hazardous substance liability and supreme court reversal of all federal circuits. William Mary Environ Law Policy Rev 33:633–722
go back to reference Fischbacher U, Gächter S (2010) Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 100:541–556CrossRef Fischbacher U, Gächter S (2010) Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. Am Econ Rev 100:541–556CrossRef
go back to reference Flambard V, Le Lec F, Romaniuc R (2020) How does risk affect collective participation? Public good provision versus public bad prevention. Mimeo, New York Flambard V, Le Lec F, Romaniuc R (2020) How does risk affect collective participation? Public good provision versus public bad prevention. Mimeo, New York
go back to reference Foulon J, Lanoie P, Laplante B (2002) Incentives for pollution control: regulation or information? J Environ Econ Manag 44:169–187CrossRef Foulon J, Lanoie P, Laplante B (2002) Incentives for pollution control: regulation or information? J Environ Econ Manag 44:169–187CrossRef
go back to reference Gächter S, Renner E (2010) The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public goods experiments. Exp Econ 13:364–377CrossRef Gächter S, Renner E (2010) The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public goods experiments. Exp Econ 13:364–377CrossRef
go back to reference García JH, Sterner T, Afsah S (2007) Public disclosure of industrial pollution: the PROPER approach for Indonesia? Environ Dev Econ 12:739–756CrossRef García JH, Sterner T, Afsah S (2007) Public disclosure of industrial pollution: the PROPER approach for Indonesia? Environ Dev Econ 12:739–756CrossRef
go back to reference García JH, Afsah S, Sterner T (2009) Which firms are more sensitive to public disclosure schemes for pollution control? Evidence from Indonesia’s PROPER Program. Environ Resource Econ 42:151–168CrossRef García JH, Afsah S, Sterner T (2009) Which firms are more sensitive to public disclosure schemes for pollution control? Evidence from Indonesia’s PROPER Program. Environ Resource Econ 42:151–168CrossRef
go back to reference Gonenc H, Scholtens B (2017) Environmental and financial performance of fossil fuel firms: a closer inspection of their interaction environmental and financial performance of fossil fuel firms: a closer inspection of their interaction environmental and financial performance of fossil fuel firms: a closer inspection of their interaction. Ecol Econ 132:307–328CrossRef Gonenc H, Scholtens B (2017) Environmental and financial performance of fossil fuel firms: a closer inspection of their interaction environmental and financial performance of fossil fuel firms: a closer inspection of their interaction environmental and financial performance of fossil fuel firms: a closer inspection of their interaction. Ecol Econ 132:307–328CrossRef
go back to reference Greiner B (2015) Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. J Econ Sci Assoc 1:114–125CrossRef Greiner B (2015) Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. J Econ Sci Assoc 1:114–125CrossRef
go back to reference Huet-Vaughn E, Muller N, Hsu Y-C (2018) Livestreaming pollution: a new form of public disclosure and a catalyst for citizen engagement? NBER working paper 24664 Huet-Vaughn E, Muller N, Hsu Y-C (2018) Livestreaming pollution: a new form of public disclosure and a catalyst for citizen engagement? NBER working paper 24664
go back to reference Jacob J, Lambert E-A, Garcia S (2022) Efficiency of liability-sharing rules: an experimental case. J Inst Theor Econ (JITE) 178:1–42CrossRef Jacob J, Lambert E-A, Garcia S (2022) Efficiency of liability-sharing rules: an experimental case. J Inst Theor Econ (JITE) 178:1–42CrossRef
go back to reference Jacquet J, Jamieson D (2016) Soft but significant power in the Paris Agreement. Nat Clim Change 6:643–646CrossRef Jacquet J, Jamieson D (2016) Soft but significant power in the Paris Agreement. Nat Clim Change 6:643–646CrossRef
go back to reference Kahneman D, Tversky A (1973) Availability: a heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cogn Psychol 5:207–232CrossRef Kahneman D, Tversky A (1973) Availability: a heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cogn Psychol 5:207–232CrossRef
go back to reference Keser C, Montmarquette C (2008) Voluntary contributions to reduce expected public losses. J Econ Behav Organ 66:477–491CrossRef Keser C, Montmarquette C (2008) Voluntary contributions to reduce expected public losses. J Econ Behav Organ 66:477–491CrossRef
go back to reference Konar S, Cohen MA (1997) Information as regulation: the effect of community right to know laws on toxic emissions. J Environ Econ Manag 32:109–124CrossRef Konar S, Cohen MA (1997) Information as regulation: the effect of community right to know laws on toxic emissions. J Environ Econ Manag 32:109–124CrossRef
go back to reference Kornhauser LA, Revesz RL (1989) Sharing damages among multiple tortfeasors. Yale Law J 98:831–884CrossRef Kornhauser LA, Revesz RL (1989) Sharing damages among multiple tortfeasors. Yale Law J 98:831–884CrossRef
go back to reference Kornhauser LA, Revesz RL (1990) Apportioning damages among potentially insolvent actors. J Leg Stud 19:617–651CrossRef Kornhauser LA, Revesz RL (1990) Apportioning damages among potentially insolvent actors. J Leg Stud 19:617–651CrossRef
go back to reference Kornhauser L, Schotter A (1990) An experimental study of single-actor accidents. J Leg Stud 19:203–233CrossRef Kornhauser L, Schotter A (1990) An experimental study of single-actor accidents. J Leg Stud 19:203–233CrossRef
go back to reference Kornhauser L, Schotter A (1992) An experimental study of two-actor accidents. C.V. Starr Center for applied economics—economic research report Kornhauser L, Schotter A (1992) An experimental study of two-actor accidents. C.V. Starr Center for applied economics—economic research report
go back to reference Lopez-Perez R (2010) Guilt and shame: an axiomatic analysis. Theor Decis 69:569–586CrossRef Lopez-Perez R (2010) Guilt and shame: an axiomatic analysis. Theor Decis 69:569–586CrossRef
go back to reference Maestre-Andres S, Drews S, van den Bergh J (2019) Perceived fairness and public acceptability of carbon pricing: a review of the literature. Clim Policy 19:1186–1204CrossRef Maestre-Andres S, Drews S, van den Bergh J (2019) Perceived fairness and public acceptability of carbon pricing: a review of the literature. Clim Policy 19:1186–1204CrossRef
go back to reference Nalbantian HR, Schotter A (1997) Productivity under group incentives: an experimental study. Am Econ Rev 87(3):314–341 Nalbantian HR, Schotter A (1997) Productivity under group incentives: an experimental study. Am Econ Rev 87(3):314–341
go back to reference Nielsen K (2019) Dynamic risk preferences under realized and paper outcomes. J Econ Behav Organ 161:68–78CrossRef Nielsen K (2019) Dynamic risk preferences under realized and paper outcomes. J Econ Behav Organ 161:68–78CrossRef
go back to reference Pien C-P (2020) Local environmental information disclosure and environmental non-governmental organizations in Chinese prefecture-level cities. J Environ Manag 275:211–225CrossRef Pien C-P (2020) Local environmental information disclosure and environmental non-governmental organizations in Chinese prefecture-level cities. J Environ Manag 275:211–225CrossRef
go back to reference Pinkowski B (1996) Simplifying CERCLA defenses to liability. Urban Lawyer 28:197–221 Pinkowski B (1996) Simplifying CERCLA defenses to liability. Urban Lawyer 28:197–221
go back to reference Powers N, Blackman A, Lyon TP, Narain U (2011) Does disclosure reduce pollution? Evidence from India’s Green Rating Project. Environ Resour Econ 50:131–155CrossRef Powers N, Blackman A, Lyon TP, Narain U (2011) Does disclosure reduce pollution? Evidence from India’s Green Rating Project. Environ Resour Econ 50:131–155CrossRef
go back to reference Rege M, Telle K (2004) The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. J Public Econ 88:1625–1644CrossRef Rege M, Telle K (2004) The impact of social approval and framing on cooperation in public good situations. J Public Econ 88:1625–1644CrossRef
go back to reference Samek A, Sheremeta R (2014) Recognizing contributors: an experiment on public goods. Exp Econ 17:673–690CrossRef Samek A, Sheremeta R (2014) Recognizing contributors: an experiment on public goods. Exp Econ 17:673–690CrossRef
go back to reference Schatz A (2008) Regulating greehouse gases by mandatory information disclosure. VA Environ Law J 26:335–393 Schatz A (2008) Regulating greehouse gases by mandatory information disclosure. VA Environ Law J 26:335–393
go back to reference Soetevent A (2005) Anonimity in giving in a natural context—a field experiment in 30 churches. J Public Econ 89:2301–2323CrossRef Soetevent A (2005) Anonimity in giving in a natural context—a field experiment in 30 churches. J Public Econ 89:2301–2323CrossRef
go back to reference Sonnemans J, Schram A, Offerman T (1998) Public good provision and public bad prevention: the effect of framing. J Econ Behav Organ 34:143–161CrossRef Sonnemans J, Schram A, Offerman T (1998) Public good provision and public bad prevention: the effect of framing. J Econ Behav Organ 34:143–161CrossRef
go back to reference Steg L, Groot JIMD, Dreijerink L, Abrahamse W, Siero F (2011) General antecedents of personal norms, policy acceptability, and intentions: the role of values, worldviews, and environmental concern. Soc Nat Resour 24:349–367CrossRef Steg L, Groot JIMD, Dreijerink L, Abrahamse W, Siero F (2011) General antecedents of personal norms, policy acceptability, and intentions: the role of values, worldviews, and environmental concern. Soc Nat Resour 24:349–367CrossRef
go back to reference Tadelis S (2011) The power of shame and the rationality of trust. Haas School of Business Working Paper Tadelis S (2011) The power of shame and the rationality of trust. Haas School of Business Working Paper
go back to reference Thaler R, Johnson E (1990) Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: the effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Manag Sci 36:643–660CrossRef Thaler R, Johnson E (1990) Gambling with the house money and trying to break even: the effects of prior outcomes on risky choice. Manag Sci 36:643–660CrossRef
go back to reference Tietenberg T (1998) Disclosure strategies for pollution control. Environ Resour Econ 11:587–602CrossRef Tietenberg T (1998) Disclosure strategies for pollution control. Environ Resour Econ 11:587–602CrossRef
go back to reference Walker JM, Gardner R (1992) Probabilistic destruction of common-pool resources: experimental evidence. Econ J 102:1149–1161CrossRef Walker JM, Gardner R (1992) Probabilistic destruction of common-pool resources: experimental evidence. Econ J 102:1149–1161CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Information disclosure under liability: an experiment on public bads
Authors
Julien Jacob
Eve-Angéline Lambert
Mathieu Lefebvre
Sarah Van Driessche
Publication date
27-12-2022
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Social Choice and Welfare / Issue 1/2023
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Electronic ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-022-01444-0

Other articles of this Issue 1/2023

Social Choice and Welfare 1/2023 Go to the issue