Skip to main content
Top

1998 | Book

Marxian Economics: A Reappraisal

Essays on Volume III of Capital

Editor: Riccardo Bellofiore

Publisher: Palgrave Macmillan UK

insite
SEARCH

Table of Contents

Frontmatter

Method and Value

Frontmatter
1. Engels, Logic and History
Abstract
It should be remembered that volume III of Capital was edited by Engels; furthermore, to a considerable extent he set the framework for its reception through his commentaries. This contribution concerns the interpretation of the place of volume III in the structure of Capital as a whole advanced by Engels in his 1894 preface and 1895 supplement. However, there is a continuity between these texts and the logical-historical method Engels claimed to have found when he reviewed Marx’s Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy (1859). According to this method, Marx’s exposition is simply a corrected reflection of the historical development of the system of capitalist production. In his comments in volume III of Capital Engels interprets this method as implying that Marx started in volume I by describing a historical stage of ‘simple commodity production’, that it was there that value attained its ‘classical form’, and that subsequently the picture changed when, with capitalist production, commodity value appeared in a ‘secondary’ derivative form.
Christopher J. Arthur
2. The Structure of Marx’s Argument in Capital
Abstract
The anniversary of the publication of volume III of Marx’s Capital is a good occasion to reflect on the construction of the work as a whole, and in particular on the rationale underlying the distinctions Marx drew between the analysis in its first and third volumes. This is particularly worthwhile in light of contemporary contributions that develop certain ideas suggested by Marx but in isolation from the larger framework of his work as a whole. In my view, doing so can be of considerable value. But, at the same time something important gets lost. It is this something important that I propose to discuss here.
David P. Levine
3. Some Reflections on Marx’s Theory of Value
Abstract
Two controversies concerning Marx’s theory of value were of particular importance during the 1960s and 1970s. The first is well known and has attracted most of the attention of Marxian scholars during these decades: I allude to the celebrated ‘transformation problem’2 and to the spirited debates that followed the publication of Sraffa’s Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities. The second one, however, is much less well known among economists but is also of fundamental importance: it was more methodological in character and centred mainly on Marx’s ‘logic’ and the relationship between Marx and Hegel.
Gilbert Faccarello
4. Capital, Labour and Time: The Marxian Monetary Labour Theory of Value as a Theory of Exploitation
Abstract
The last point to which attention is still to be drawn in the relation of labour to capital is this, that as the use value which confronts money posited as capital, labour is not this or another labour, but labour pure and simple, abstract labour; absolutely indifferent to its particular specificity, but capable of all specificities…. This economic relation — the character which capitalist and worker have as the extremes of a single relation of production — therefore develops more purely and adequately in proportion as labour loses all the characteristics of art; as its particular skill becomes something more abstract and irrelevant, and as it becomes more and more a purely abstract activity, a purely mechanical activity, hence indifferent to its particular form…. Here it can be seen once again that the particular specificity of the relation of production, of the category — here, capital and labour — becomes real only with the development of a particular material mode of production and of a particular stage in the development of the industrial productive forces. (This point in general to be particularly developed in connection with this relation, later; since it is here already posited [gesetzes] in the relation itself, while, in the case of the abstract concepts, exchange value, circulation, money, it still lies more in our subjective reflection.)
Riccardo Bellofiore, Roberto Finelli
5. Land Rent and the Logic of Capital
Abstract
Marx’s theory of land rent was the object of study during the 1970s and early 1980s principally as a by-product of the debate among Marxist and neo-Ricardian economists on the transformation problem.2 Another issue that has revived interest in Marx’s rent theory is the problem of speculation in the building sector (Lipietz, 1974; Broadbent, 1975; Folin, 1976), a problem that has continued to draw attention to draw Marx’s contribution until recently (Clark, 1987; Persky and White, 1988; Bovaird, 1993).
Marco E. L. Guidi
6. The (Dis)Orderly Process of Capitalist Competition
Abstract
For most of the past one hundred years, Marxist economists have produced and disseminated a particular set of stories about capitalism and socialism. According to these well-known accounts, capitalism is a singularly destructive, crisis-prone system governed by the ‘logic of capital’, which is often expressed in terms of economic ‘laws of motion’ and the ‘drive to accumulate’ on the part of capitalists. Socialism, in contrast, represents the suppression or elimination of such a logic and its underlying laws and drives, and thus creates the possibility of a rational, planned way of organizing economic and social life.
Jack Amariglio, David F. Ruccio
7. Towards a General Theory of Capitalism: Suggestions from Chapters 23 and 27
Abstract
In this chapter two theories of capitalism are confronted. The first claims that private ownership of the means of production is the basic institution of capitalism and that the two opposing classes — capitalists and workers — must be defined on the ground of the distinction between ownership and propertylessness. This theory will be called the ‘S-theory’ since, although it predominates in Marx’s and orthodox Marxist thought, it originated with Adam Smith.
Ernesto Screpanti

Money

Frontmatter
8. The Relation between the Rate of Profit and the Rate of Interest: A Reassessment after the Publication of Marx’s Manuscript of the Third Volume of Das Kapital
Abstract
Almost one hundred years after the appearance of volume III of Das Kapital, edited by Engels, Marx’s own manuscript has been published at last (Marx, 1992). Engels’ labours to edit it as a coherent book have often been admired, especially in view of the fact that he finalised a task that Marx had failed to accomplish. But in view of the manuscript one experiences something of the sensation one feels when the original of a Greek sculpture is discovered, albeit damaged, of which a more polished Roman copy had been known. The translation might be compared to a photograph which lacks the original colours.
Bertram Schefold
9. The Emergence of Credit Money
Abstract
Marx’s argument on money, credit and fictitious capital in volume III of Capital relies on a logic of ‘emergence’, which deserves attention not just for methodological reasons. What is meant by logic of emergence?
Heiner Ganssmann
10. Money, Form and Determination of Value
Abstract
The concept of form of value is certainly one of Marx’s outstanding contributions. A short discussion of the difficulties of the contemporary monetary theory in its most developed version (the neoclassical one) will show that this concept is the necessary starting point (or the rational basis) for monetary theory, hence for price theory, whatever the choice of a particular value theory.
Carlo Benetti, Jean Cartelier
11. Money, Interest and Finance in Marx’s Capital
Abstract
According to Marx, money capital, lent by its capitalist owner to an industrial capitalist, is ‘potential capital’. Interest payments made by borrowers to lenders are part of the global surplus value produced by labourers and appropriated by capitalists. There is no law of division of surplus value between profit and interest, no natural interest. Interest-bearing capital becomes a commodity sui generis. Its market price, the interest rate, is an irrational form of price. As a market price, the interest rate seems to arise from money capital as its own independent source.
Suzanne de Brunhoff
12. Fictitious Capital and Crises
Abstract
This chapter is concerned with just a section of part V (‘The Division of Profit into Interest and Profit of Enterprise’) of volume III of Capital. 3 This section consists of the chapters 25 to 35. Although these should properly be grouped as a separate part, their unity escaped Engels’ attention and is accordingly missing in the current arrangement of volume III. This ‘ideal’ part (which could possibly be titled ‘Credit and Crises’ or ‘Money Capital and Fictitious Capital’, and will be referred to henceforth as ‘the unidentified part’) is not unrelated to what remains of part V (chapters 21-4 and 36) but should be considered more strictly as a follow-up of part IV, ‘The Transformation of Commodity Capital and Money Capital into Commodity-Dealing Capital and Money-Dealing Capital’ (Merchants Capital).4 It should also be noted that the unidentified part is less related to the nature of interest and to the difference between interest and profit (an issue fairly similar to that of rent and of the difference between rent and profit in part VII) than to that section of part IV where money-dealing capital is presented as a subspecies of merchant’s capital.
Ferdinando Meacci
13. Finance Capital Revisited
Abstract
This chapter deals with the concept of finance capital — a high topic in early-twentieth-century Marxist literature — emphasizing its usefulness as an instrument with which to analyses modern capitalist economies. Drawing mainly on Marx’s observations on chapter 27 Volume III of Capital, ‘The Role of Credit in Capitalist Production’, on Hilferding’s Finance Capital and on the more general Marxian framework (capital as a social relation) it seems possible to replace this pseudo divorce (also known as the ‘corporate revolution’) with a new phase of capitalism in which capitalists are as dominant as before, although operating through a different institutional apparatus. In this sense the chapter resurrects the more general meaning of finance capital so as to include not only capital at the disposition of banks but also capital at the command of non- banking entities and/or individuals. Both forms of private wealth — bank deposits and tradable securities — are seen as enjoying the same essential properties of liquidity (readily convertible into its money equivalent) and increasing value (appreciation, interest, dividends) and should therefore qualify as finance capital. Breaking away from the notion that the dominance of finance capital evolves through the dominance of financial institutions it seems possible to speak of a financial phase as a stage in which an ever-increasing proportion of the capital used in industry is finance capital without resorting to the unlikely task of demonstrating the preeminence of the banking sector over non-banking activities.
Nelson Prado, Alves Pinto
14. Marx on the Natural Rate of Interest: Did Marx Hold a Monetary Theory of Income Distribution?
Abstract
This chapter bears upon the question of whether the monetary theory of income distribution — as by suggested Sraffa in Productions of Commodities by Means of Commodities — must be considered equally alien to Marx’s system as it was to classical political economy. Sraffa, who was clearly inspired by the works of the classical economists and Marx, remarked that his own system leaves open the possibility that the money rate of interest determines the rate of profit:
The rate of profit, as a ratio, has a significance which is independent of any prices, and can well be ‘given’ before the prices are fixed. It is accordingly susceptible of being determined from outside the system of production, in particular by the level of the money rates of interest (Sraffa, 1960, p. 33).
It is well known that this idea, upon which Sraffa did not elaborate, implies a radical reversal of the causality in the theory of income distribution that is found in the works of Ricardo and Thornton.
Henk W. Plasmeijer
15. Asset Speculation in Marx’s Theory of Money
Abstract
A leading problem for contemporary Marxist economics is to explain the general commodity price level in monetary systems based on state credit when the value of the national currency is not determined by its guaranteed convertibility into gold or some other external asset. The problem arises because the coherent and persuasive theory of money that Marx, following Tooke (see Arnon, 1990), developed in Capital (1867) presupposes the existence of an international commodity money system. (For the sake of brevity I will refer to this system as a ‘gold standard’ system, and abuse precise language by distinguishing between ‘gold’, that is, the money commodity, on the one hand, and ‘commodities’, that is, all other produced commodities, on the other.) On the gold standard assumption, Marx was able to outline theoretically transparent and convincing explanations for the level of commodity prices in terms of gold or national currencies defined as a given quantity of gold. But we encounter substantial problems when trying to apply this theory to a monetary system in which the values of national currencies are not fixed in terms in gold since there appears to be no relation at all between the national currency, which is the debt of the state. and commodity production.
Duncan K. Foley
16. Marx’s Theory of Money and Interest: A Reconsideration in the Light of Robertson and Keynes
Abstract
Marx’s analysis of the role of money in a capitalist economy marked a significant advance with respect to classical political economy, and in particular with respect to Ricardo. For Marx, money was no longer just a means of circulation but also a store of value. This has significant macroeconomic implications.
Claudio Sardoni
17. Preliminaries to a Monetary Theory of Production: The Labour Theory of Value, Liquidity Preference and the Two Price Systems
Abstract
This chapter is intended to provide a preliminary analysis of a component of a larger project whose goal is to develop a ‘monetary theory of production’. The focus here will be the appropriate theories of value to be adopted in the larger project. The foundations for a monetary theory of production can be found in the works of Karl Marx and John Maynard Keynes, while Michal Kalecki has also provided some insights that help synthesize the approaches of the former authors. While authors have found it useful to synthesize the works of Marx and Keynes, I believe Dudley Dillard was among the few who fully recognized the importance of the labour theory of value (LTV) for Keynes’ own approach to the monetary theory of production (Wray 1993a).
L. Randall Wray
Backmatter
Metadata
Title
Marxian Economics: A Reappraisal
Editor
Riccardo Bellofiore
Copyright Year
1998
Publisher
Palgrave Macmillan UK
Electronic ISBN
978-1-349-26118-5
Print ISBN
978-1-349-26120-8
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-26118-5