Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 4/2016

01-08-2016 | Policy Watch

Measuring climate policy stringency: a shadow price approach

Authors: Wilhelm Althammer, Erik Hille

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 4/2016

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

To assess the effect of environmental policy on production structures, trade structures, or foreign direct investment, a measure for the stringency of policy is necessary. Measures typically used in empirical studies share several disadvantages: they are not available on a sectoral basis to reflect concerns of industry competitiveness; they are not available for a wide range of countries to allow for international comparisons; or they are not broad enough to reflect the multidimensionality of environmental policy. This paper develops a thorough, internationally comparable, sector-specific measure of multidimensional climate policy stringency where a shadow price approach serves as a basis. The approach is applied to climate policy by determining sector-specific emission-relevant energy costs on the basis of the sectors’ usage of emission-relevant energy carriers and the carriers’ respective prices. The resulting shadow price estimates are heterogeneous and can be applied in future research to test for carbon leakage and pollution havens.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
While Ederington et al. (2004) distinguish between a direct and an indirect effect, Copeland and Taylor (2004) similarly differentiate between a pollution haven effect and a pollution haven hypothesis.
 
2
To thoroughly analyze issues such as carbon leakage, such a stringency measure constitutes the first step as it measures the impact of policy on specific sectors. But pollution haven and carbon leakage effects also depend on the intensity of competition in certain industries. Felbermayer et al. (2013) develop a measure for the intensity of competition based on trade costs, price elasticities, and (inter)national inter-sectoral linkages of value chains.
 
3
For a detailed list of the included countries, please see Table 1.
 
4
In general, the estimated sector-specific climate policy stringencies in this paper do not change this perception.
 
5
An overview of the environmental and climate policy stringency measures can be found in Sect. 2.1.
 
6
An extensive overview of environmental policy stringency approaches can be found in Brunel and Levinson (20013b).
 
7
List and Co (2000) solve this problem by ranking states based on their weighted public and private sector pollution abatement expenditures in dollars.
 
8
The interpretation of \(Z_{E}\) and \(p_{E}\) of van Soest et al. (2006) slightly differs from the one of Morrison Paul and MacDonald (2003), who differentiate between the observed price p and the effective/shadow price Z.
 
9
For further discussion of advantages and disadvantages of the shadow price approach, see van Soest et al. (2006, pp. 1158-60).
 
10
Looking at the US food processing sector, Morrison Paul and MacDonald (2003) found differences between the observed and the shadow price for capital and agricultural goods, but not for labor, energy, and two materials inputs. The alternative approach used by Morrison (1988) and Morrison and Schwartz (1996) nests the quantities of the input under consideration instead of their prices in the cost function.
 
11
The literature on production functions provides several extensions of GL functions. For instance, Nakamura (1990) presents a non-homothetic extension of the GL cost function, which allows a broader modelling of scale effects and technological change. Data restrictions prevent us from modeling these aspects in more detail. A similar argument applies to Behrmann et al.’s (1992) extension of a CET–CES Leontief variable profit function, which allows expanded input and output substitution possibilities at the cost of introducing one additional parameter to be estimated.
 
12
For now, additional sub-subscripts are for clarity reasons left out. In the final estimating model each coefficient is also classified with regard to its country, sector, and time specification.
 
13
Other authors use the input–output specification to correct for potential heteroscedasticity, which this paper adjusts for by estimating robust standard errors (Morrison 1988; Morrison and Schwartz 1996; van Soest et al. 2006).
 
14
The results are robust to alternative time periods, which may be of the same or different lengths.
 
15
Given that WIOD does not offer sector-specific capital stock information for the whole time period under consideration, the capital stock data are constructed using the methodology explained in Appendix 1.
 
16
Shadow prices have also been estimated using PPP units. This resulted in a tendency of higher shadow prices for poorer countries, which can be interpreted such that poorer economies spend a relatively higher share of income on emission-relevant energy use or, in other words, on costs resulting from climate policy regulation.
 
17
Table 6 in Appendix 2 lists all included 33 sectors.
 
18
ISIC refers to the International Standard Industrial Classification of All Economic Activities.
 
19
The gross energy use includes the use of both energy carriers that are relevant for emissions and the ones that do not emit.
 
20
If all observations are included—also the ones that are not in the base years—the seven energy sources on average make up 86 % of the total sectors’ energy use, which is relevant for emissions and, hence, for climate policy issues. As for some years data are not available for all seven energy carriers, the explained share in the base years only is even higher and, therefore, considered a reasonable estimate for the respective year’s average energy price. In the remaining years, the total average energy price is determined by the total energy PASCHE price index. The final shadow prices have been tested for robustness and do not reveal significant differences compared to estimates using alternative base years with similar explained shares of energy use.
 
21
Table 7 in Appendix 3 summarizes the allocation of industry and household prices of the energy sources to the sectors.
 
22
In addition, both the estimated wedge coefficients and the shadow prices are provided in an Excel dataset (Online resource 2).
 
23
The rankings look the same based on the wedge coefficients.
 
24
In this comparison, one needs to bear in mind that the OECD reports effective tax rates in 2012, whereas Table 3 shows average shadow prices for the time period 1995 to 2009. Given the fact that many countries increased the taxes over the last two decades at unequal rates, the estimated correlation is relatively high.
 
25
There exist quite a number of examples for the differentiated treatment of sectors including the implementation of the European Union Emission Trading System and the distribution of the costs of the German Renewable Energy Act.
 
26
Nevertheless, the dataset contains some missing data points.
 
27
In other words, the measure is likely not to become another one that cannot be further extended due to the unavailability of data. Examples for this are the indices of Dasgupta et al. (2001) and Eliste and Fredriksson (2002).
 
28
For instance, a negative estimated wedge may only indicate that the country is subsidizing the usage of the polluting input relative to the rest of the included countries.
 
29
With regard to the cost function explained in Sect. 3, this paper follows the approach of van Soest et al. (2006), who take all cost information as exogenously given and, hence, cannot explain changes in explanatory variables of the cost function.
 
30
The constructed capital stock measure has also been compared to the one reported in the Extended Penn World Tables 4.0. for all countries in WIOD and shows a very high correlation coefficient of 0.995.
 
Literature
go back to reference Bandura, R. (2008). A survey of composite indexes measuring country performance: 2008 update. UNDP/ODS Working paper, United Nations Development Programme. Bandura, R. (2008). A survey of composite indexes measuring country performance: 2008 update. UNDP/ODS Working paper, United Nations Development Programme.
go back to reference Bao, Q., Chen, Y., & Song, L. (2011). Foreign direct investment and environmental pollution in China: A simultaneous equations estimation. Environment and Development Economics, 16(1), 71–92.CrossRef Bao, Q., Chen, Y., & Song, L. (2011). Foreign direct investment and environmental pollution in China: A simultaneous equations estimation. Environment and Development Economics, 16(1), 71–92.CrossRef
go back to reference Behrmann, J. R., Knox Lovell, C. A., Pollak, R. A., & Sickels, R. C. (1992). The CET–CES-Generalized Leontief variable profit function: An application to Indian agriculture. Oxford Economic Papers, 44(2), 341–354. Behrmann, J. R., Knox Lovell, C. A., Pollak, R. A., & Sickels, R. C. (1992). The CET–CES-Generalized Leontief variable profit function: An application to Indian agriculture. Oxford Economic Papers, 44(2), 341–354.
go back to reference Brunel, C., & Levinson, A. (2013). Measuring environmental regulatory stringency. OECD Trade and Environment Working Papers, No. 2013/05, OECD Publishing. Brunel, C., & Levinson, A. (2013). Measuring environmental regulatory stringency. OECD Trade and Environment Working Papers, No. 2013/05, OECD Publishing.
go back to reference Brunel, C., & Levinson, A. (2016). Measuring the stringency of environmental regulations. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10(1), 47–67.CrossRef Brunel, C., & Levinson, A. (2016). Measuring the stringency of environmental regulations. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 10(1), 47–67.CrossRef
go back to reference Cagatay, S., & Mihci, H. (2006). Degree of environmental stringency and the impact on trade patterns. Journal of Economic Studies, 33(1), 30–51.CrossRef Cagatay, S., & Mihci, H. (2006). Degree of environmental stringency and the impact on trade patterns. Journal of Economic Studies, 33(1), 30–51.CrossRef
go back to reference Caselli, F. (2005). Accounting for cross-country income differences. In P. Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth (pp. 679–741). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Caselli, F. (2005). Accounting for cross-country income differences. In P. Aghion & S. N. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth (pp. 679–741). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
go back to reference Coggins, J. S., & Swinton, J. R. (1996). The price of pollution: A dual approach to valuing SO2 allowances. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30(1), 58–72.CrossRef Coggins, J. S., & Swinton, J. R. (1996). The price of pollution: A dual approach to valuing SO2 allowances. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 30(1), 58–72.CrossRef
go back to reference Cole, M. A., & Elliot, R. J. R. (2003). Do environmental regulations influence trade patterns? Testing old and new trade theories. World Economy, 26(8), 1163–1186.CrossRef Cole, M. A., & Elliot, R. J. R. (2003). Do environmental regulations influence trade patterns? Testing old and new trade theories. World Economy, 26(8), 1163–1186.CrossRef
go back to reference Cole, M. A., Elliot, R. J. R., & Fredriksson, P. G. (2006). Endogenous pollution havens: Does FDI influence environmental regulations? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(1), 157–178.CrossRef Cole, M. A., Elliot, R. J. R., & Fredriksson, P. G. (2006). Endogenous pollution havens: Does FDI influence environmental regulations? Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 108(1), 157–178.CrossRef
go back to reference Costantini, V., & Crespi, F. (2008). Environmental regulation and the export dynamics of energy technologies. Ecological Economics, 66(2–3), 447–460.CrossRef Costantini, V., & Crespi, F. (2008). Environmental regulation and the export dynamics of energy technologies. Ecological Economics, 66(2–3), 447–460.CrossRef
go back to reference Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2004). Trade, growth, and the environment. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(1), 7–71.CrossRef Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2004). Trade, growth, and the environment. Journal of Economic Literature, 42(1), 7–71.CrossRef
go back to reference Dasgupta, S., Mody, A., Roy, S., & Wheeler, D. (2001). Environmental regulation and development: A cross-country empirical analysis. Oxford Development Studies, 29(2), 173–187.CrossRef Dasgupta, S., Mody, A., Roy, S., & Wheeler, D. (2001). Environmental regulation and development: A cross-country empirical analysis. Oxford Development Studies, 29(2), 173–187.CrossRef
go back to reference Diekmann, J., Kemfert, C., & Neuhoff, K. (2012). The proposed adjustment of Germany’s renewable energy law: A critical assessment. DIW Economic Bulletin, 6, 3–9. Diekmann, J., Kemfert, C., & Neuhoff, K. (2012). The proposed adjustment of Germany’s renewable energy law: A critical assessment. DIW Economic Bulletin, 6, 3–9.
go back to reference Diewert, W. E., & Wales, T. J. (1987). Flexible functional forms and global curvature conditions. Econometrica, 55(1), 43–68.CrossRef Diewert, W. E., & Wales, T. J. (1987). Flexible functional forms and global curvature conditions. Econometrica, 55(1), 43–68.CrossRef
go back to reference Ederington, J., Levinson, A., & Minier, J. (2004). Trade liberalization and pollution havens. Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy, 4(2), 1–22. Ederington, J., Levinson, A., & Minier, J. (2004). Trade liberalization and pollution havens. Advances in Economic Analysis & Policy, 4(2), 1–22.
go back to reference Eliste, P., & Fredriksson, P. G. (2002). Environmental regulations, transfers, and trade: Theory and evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(2), 234–250.CrossRef Eliste, P., & Fredriksson, P. G. (2002). Environmental regulations, transfers, and trade: Theory and evidence. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(2), 234–250.CrossRef
go back to reference European Commission. (2012). Commission Decision of 24 December 2009 determining, pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, a list of sectors and subsectors which are deemed to be exposed to a significant risk of carbon leakage (notified under document C(2009) 10251) (Text with EEA relevance), amended by Commission Decision 2011/745/EU of 11 November 2011 and Commission Decision 2012/498/EU of 17 August 2012. Treaty on the functioning of the European Union. European Commission. (2012). Commission Decision of 24 December 2009 determining, pursuant to Directive 2003/87/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council, a list of sectors and subsectors which are deemed to be exposed to a significant risk of carbon leakage (notified under document C(2009) 10251) (Text with EEA relevance), amended by Commission Decision 2011/745/EU of 11 November 2011 and Commission Decision 2012/498/EU of 17 August 2012. Treaty on the functioning of the European Union.
go back to reference Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Noh, D.-W., & Weber, W. (2005). Characteristics of a polluting technology: Theory and practice. Journal of Econometrics, 126(2), 469–492.CrossRef Färe, R., Grosskopf, S., Noh, D.-W., & Weber, W. (2005). Characteristics of a polluting technology: Theory and practice. Journal of Econometrics, 126(2), 469–492.CrossRef
go back to reference Felbermayer, G., Aichele, R., Zimmer, M., & Heiland, I. (2013). Entwicklung eines Maßes für die Intensität des internationalen Wettbewerbs auf Unternehmens- oder Sektorebene. Ifo Institute, Munich: Kurzgutachten im Auftrag des Bundesministeriums für Wirtschaft und Technologie. Felbermayer, G., Aichele, R., Zimmer, M., & Heiland, I. (2013). Entwicklung eines Maßes für die Intensität des internationalen Wettbewerbs auf Unternehmens- oder Sektorebene. Ifo Institute, Munich: Kurzgutachten im Auftrag des Bundesministeriums für Wirtschaft und Technologie.
go back to reference Filippini, M. (1996). Economies of scale and utilization in the Swiss electric power distribution industry. Applied Economics, 28(5), 543–550.CrossRef Filippini, M. (1996). Economies of scale and utilization in the Swiss electric power distribution industry. Applied Economics, 28(5), 543–550.CrossRef
go back to reference Gray, W. (1997). Manufacturing plant location: Does state pollution regulation matter? NBER Working Paper Series, No. 5880. Gray, W. (1997). Manufacturing plant location: Does state pollution regulation matter? NBER Working Paper Series, No. 5880.
go back to reference He, J. (2006). Pollution haven hypothesis and environmental impacts of foreign direct investment: The case of industrial emission of sulfur dioxide (SO2) in Chinese provinces. Ecological Economics, 60(1), 228–245.CrossRef He, J. (2006). Pollution haven hypothesis and environmental impacts of foreign direct investment: The case of industrial emission of sulfur dioxide (SO2) in Chinese provinces. Ecological Economics, 60(1), 228–245.CrossRef
go back to reference Henderson, V. (1996). Effects of air quality regulation. American Economic Review, 86, 789–813. Henderson, V. (1996). Effects of air quality regulation. American Economic Review, 86, 789–813.
go back to reference Huhtala, A., & Marklund, P.-O. (2006). Stringency of environmental targets in animal agriculture: Shedding light on policy with shadow prices. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 35(2), 193–217.CrossRef Huhtala, A., & Marklund, P.-O. (2006). Stringency of environmental targets in animal agriculture: Shedding light on policy with shadow prices. European Review of Agricultural Economics, 35(2), 193–217.CrossRef
go back to reference International Energy Agency (IEA). (2013a). Addressing climate change. Policies and Measures Database. Version June 30, 2013. International Energy Agency (IEA). (2013a). Addressing climate change. Policies and Measures Database. Version June 30, 2013.
go back to reference Javorcik, B. S., & Wei, S.-J. (2003). Pollution havens and foreign direct investment: Dirty secret or popular myth? B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 3(2), 8. Javorcik, B. S., & Wei, S.-J. (2003). Pollution havens and foreign direct investment: Dirty secret or popular myth? B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis and Policy, 3(2), 8.
go back to reference Keller, W., & Levinson, A. (2002). Pollution abatement costs and foreign direct investment inflows to U.S. states. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(4), 691–703.CrossRef Keller, W., & Levinson, A. (2002). Pollution abatement costs and foreign direct investment inflows to U.S. states. Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(4), 691–703.CrossRef
go back to reference Kettner, C., Köppl, A., Schleicher, S. P., & Thenius, G. (2008). Stringency and distribution in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme: First evidence. Climate Policy, 8(1), 41–61.CrossRef Kettner, C., Köppl, A., Schleicher, S. P., & Thenius, G. (2008). Stringency and distribution in the EU Emissions Trading Scheme: First evidence. Climate Policy, 8(1), 41–61.CrossRef
go back to reference Levinson, A. (1996). Environmental regulations and manufacturers’ location choices: Evidence from the census of manufactures. Journal of Public Economics, 62(1–2), 5–29.CrossRef Levinson, A. (1996). Environmental regulations and manufacturers’ location choices: Evidence from the census of manufactures. Journal of Public Economics, 62(1–2), 5–29.CrossRef
go back to reference Levinson, A., & Taylor, M. S. (2008). Unmasking the pollution haven effect. International Economic Review, 49(1), 223–254.CrossRef Levinson, A., & Taylor, M. S. (2008). Unmasking the pollution haven effect. International Economic Review, 49(1), 223–254.CrossRef
go back to reference List, J. A., & Co, C. Y. (2000). The effects of environmental regulations on foreign direct investment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 40(1), 1–20.CrossRef List, J. A., & Co, C. Y. (2000). The effects of environmental regulations on foreign direct investment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 40(1), 1–20.CrossRef
go back to reference Magnani, E. (2000). The environmental Kuznets curve, environmental protection policy and income distribution. Ecological Economics, 32(3), 431–443.CrossRef Magnani, E. (2000). The environmental Kuznets curve, environmental protection policy and income distribution. Ecological Economics, 32(3), 431–443.CrossRef
go back to reference Managi, S., Hibiki, A., & Tsurumi, T. (2009). Does trade openness improve environmental quality? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 58(3), 346–363.CrossRef Managi, S., Hibiki, A., & Tsurumi, T. (2009). Does trade openness improve environmental quality? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 58(3), 346–363.CrossRef
go back to reference McConnell, V. D., & Schwab, R. M. (1990). The impact of environmental regulation on industry location decisions: The motor vehicle industry. Land Economics, 66(1), 67–81.CrossRef McConnell, V. D., & Schwab, R. M. (1990). The impact of environmental regulation on industry location decisions: The motor vehicle industry. Land Economics, 66(1), 67–81.CrossRef
go back to reference Millimet, D. L., & Roy, J. (2016). Empirical tests of the pollution haven hypothesis when environmental regulation is endogenous. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 31(4), 652–677.CrossRef Millimet, D. L., & Roy, J. (2016). Empirical tests of the pollution haven hypothesis when environmental regulation is endogenous. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 31(4), 652–677.CrossRef
go back to reference Morgenstern, R. D., Pizer, W. A., & Shih, J.-S. (2001). The cost of environmental protection. Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(4), 732–738.CrossRef Morgenstern, R. D., Pizer, W. A., & Shih, J.-S. (2001). The cost of environmental protection. Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(4), 732–738.CrossRef
go back to reference Morrison, C. J. (1988). Quasi-fixed inputs in U.S. and Japanese manufacturing: A generalized Leontief restricted cost function approach. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70(2), 275–287.CrossRef Morrison, C. J. (1988). Quasi-fixed inputs in U.S. and Japanese manufacturing: A generalized Leontief restricted cost function approach. Review of Economics and Statistics, 70(2), 275–287.CrossRef
go back to reference Morrison, C. J., & Schwartz, A. E. (1996). State infrastructure and productive performance. American Economic Review, 86(5), 1095–1111. Morrison, C. J., & Schwartz, A. E. (1996). State infrastructure and productive performance. American Economic Review, 86(5), 1095–1111.
go back to reference Morrison Paul, C. J., & MacDonald, J. M. (2003). Tracing the effects of agricultural commodity prices on food processing costs. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 85(3), 633–646.CrossRef Morrison Paul, C. J., & MacDonald, J. M. (2003). Tracing the effects of agricultural commodity prices on food processing costs. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 85(3), 633–646.CrossRef
go back to reference Nakada, M. (2006). Distributional conflicts and the timing of environmental policy. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 6(1), 29–38.CrossRef Nakada, M. (2006). Distributional conflicts and the timing of environmental policy. International Environmental Agreements: Politics, Law and Economics, 6(1), 29–38.CrossRef
go back to reference Nakamura, S. (1990). A nonhomothetic generalized Leontief cost function based on pooled data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(4), 649–656.CrossRef Nakamura, S. (1990). A nonhomothetic generalized Leontief cost function based on pooled data. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 72(4), 649–656.CrossRef
go back to reference Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). (2012b). Monthly monetary and financial statistics (MEI) dataset. http://stats.oecd.org/. Accessed September 24, 2012. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). (2012b). Monthly monetary and financial statistics (MEI) dataset. http://​stats.​oecd.​org/​. Accessed September 24, 2012.
go back to reference Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). (2013). Taxing energy use: A graphical analysis. Paris: OECD Publishing. Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). (2013). Taxing energy use: A graphical analysis. Paris: OECD Publishing.
go back to reference Pasurka, C. (2008). Perspectives on pollution abatement and competitiveness: Theory, data, and analyses. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(2), 194–218.CrossRef Pasurka, C. (2008). Perspectives on pollution abatement and competitiveness: Theory, data, and analyses. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 2(2), 194–218.CrossRef
go back to reference Pittman, R. W. (1981). Issue in pollution control: Interplant cost differences and economies of scale. Land Economics, 57(1), 1–17.CrossRef Pittman, R. W. (1981). Issue in pollution control: Interplant cost differences and economies of scale. Land Economics, 57(1), 1–17.CrossRef
go back to reference Penn World Tables. (2011). Extended Penn World Tables Database Version 4.0. Released August 2011. Penn World Tables. (2011). Extended Penn World Tables Database Version 4.0. Released August 2011.
go back to reference Penn World Tables. (2012). Penn World Table Version 7.1. Released November 2012. Penn World Tables. (2012). Penn World Table Version 7.1. Released November 2012.
go back to reference Sauter, C. (2014). How should we measure environmental policy stringency? A new approach. IRENE Working Paper, 14-01. Sauter, C. (2014). How should we measure environmental policy stringency? A new approach. IRENE Working Paper, 14-01.
go back to reference van Soest, D. P., List, J. A., & Jeppesen, T. (2006). Shadow prices, environmental stringency, and international competitiveness. European Economic Review, 50(5), 1151–1167.CrossRef van Soest, D. P., List, J. A., & Jeppesen, T. (2006). Shadow prices, environmental stringency, and international competitiveness. European Economic Review, 50(5), 1151–1167.CrossRef
go back to reference Walter, I., & Ugelow, J. L. (1979). Environmental policies in developing countries. Ambio, 8(2/3), 102–109. Walter, I., & Ugelow, J. L. (1979). Environmental policies in developing countries. Ambio, 8(2/3), 102–109.
go back to reference World Input Output Database. (2012a). WIOD Environmental Accounts. Released March 2012. World Input Output Database. (2012a). WIOD Environmental Accounts. Released March 2012.
go back to reference World Input Output Database. (2012b). WIOD Socio-Economic Accounts. Released February 2012. World Input Output Database. (2012b). WIOD Socio-Economic Accounts. Released February 2012.
go back to reference Xing, Y., & Kolstad, C. D. (2002). Do lax environmental regulations attract foreign investment? Environmental and Resource Economics, 21(1), 1–22.CrossRef Xing, Y., & Kolstad, C. D. (2002). Do lax environmental regulations attract foreign investment? Environmental and Resource Economics, 21(1), 1–22.CrossRef
go back to reference Yu, H. (2011). The EU ETS and firm profits: An ex-post analysis for Swedish energy firms. Working Paper Series, No. 2011/2, Uppsala University. Yu, H. (2011). The EU ETS and firm profits: An ex-post analysis for Swedish energy firms. Working Paper Series, No. 2011/2, Uppsala University.
go back to reference Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests of aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57(298), 348–368.CrossRef Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests of aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57(298), 348–368.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Measuring climate policy stringency: a shadow price approach
Authors
Wilhelm Althammer
Erik Hille
Publication date
01-08-2016
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 4/2016
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9405-4

Other articles of this Issue 4/2016

International Tax and Public Finance 4/2016 Go to the issue