Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2014

01-04-2014

On revolt and endogenous economic policy in autocratic regimes

Authors: Joel M. Guttman, Rafael Reuveny

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Numerous empirical studies have investigated the direction of causality between democracy and economic growth (as well as the level of income per capita), but this empirical work has been paralleled by relatively few theoretical models that endogenize the institutional structure of the regime. Moreover, the different types of autocratic regimes have received relatively little attention. This paper develops a game-theoretic model of endogenous economic policy in autocratic regimes facing a revolt or an insurgency. In this model, there are three players: the regime, the rebels, and the masses. There are three stages in the game. In the first stage, the regime determines the level of infrastructure and the tax rate. In the second stage, the masses allocate their time between production and helping the rebels. In the third stage, the regime and the rebels simultaneously choose their fighting effort levels in a contest, in which the probability of survival of the regime is determined. It is found that autocratic regimes facing a revolt endogenously sort themselves into “tinpot” regimes that maximize their consumption at the cost of their survival, and (weak and strong) “totalitarian” regimes that maximize their probability of survival at the expense of their consumption. Empirical implications of the model are derived, and the relevance of the model to public policy is discussed.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
An important exception to this rule is the work of Acemoglu and Robinson (e.g., Acemoglu and Robinson 2001). For a related analysis of the shift from dictatorial to democratic regimes over the course of economic transition, see Brezis and Schnytzer (2003).
 
2
In 2005, Freedom House changed its classification of Russia from “partly free” to “not free”. The 2010 Freedom House report on Russia begins with the following summary: “The executive branch maintained its tight controls on the media, civil society, and the other branches of government in 2009, and took additional steps to rein in religious and academic freedom. The large-scale disqualification of opposition candidates helped secure a sweeping victory for the ruling United Russia party in local and regional elections in October”. (See http://​www.​freedomhouse.​org/​template.​cfm?​page=​22&​year=​2010&​country=​7904.)
 
3
Unlike the totalitarian regime of Arendt (1951) and others, however, the regime in our model does not actually mobilize mass support. The masses in our model either support the rebels or work; they do not actively support the regime.
 
4
See Shughart (2006) for an analytical history of terrorism.
 
5
For a similar approach to formulating the regime’s discounted utility, see Grossman and Noh (1994).
 
6
For another study using the logistic functional form for the conflict resolution function, see Skaperdas and Syropolous (1996). See Hirshleifer (1989, 1995) for discussions of the logistic functional form in comparison to the simpler, “ratio” function suggested by Tullock (1980).
 
7
We use the subscript ‘o’ to denote rebels’ variables (for opposition), as the subscript ‘r’ is used for the regime’s variables.
 
8
By assuming that the masses receive utility from helping the rebels, we model this help as a “consumption” good, not as an investment in the success of the revolt. This approach allows us to avoid the free-rider problem inherent in the alternative assumption, that helping the rebels is an investment good. See Guttman et al. (1994) for evidence that political participation is a consumption good. In addition to simplifying a complex analytical problem, this assumption contrasts with the usual practice of treating the masses as a unitary actor to avoid the free-rider problem.
 
9
If θ>1/β, the masses would have no incentive to help the rebels, and so there would be no fighting between the regime and the rebels in our model.
 
10
Maximizing lnU r yields the same results as maximizing U r since lnU r is monotonically increasing in U r .
 
11
This may occur, for example, if the opposition’s resource base, Y, is very large relative to the regime’s resources, z, a point to which we will return shortly.
 
12
The case ∂x/∂g>0 and \(\hat{x}<0\) does not exist as an interior solution in the third stage because, as demonstrated in the next subsection, if ∂x/∂g>0, the regime will optimally will increase G until it achieves h =0, implying x>0 for any positive z (since xβzhY).
 
13
Since τ and G 0+g must be related to each other so as to satisfy =1, the regime actually has only one choice variable in the first stage, once it has moved into the region under study. Therefore τ is equated to \(\hat{\tau}\) before differentiating (26) w.r.t. g.
 
14
This expression assumes that G >G 0, so that g >0. If the expression is negative, then g =0.
 
15
Lambert’s W function satisfies the condition W(v)e W(v)=v. For a discussion of this function, its properties and scientific applications, see, for example, Cordless et al. (1996).
 
16
These parameter values were chosen on the basis of their empirical plausibility and because they permit interesting effects of the relevant parameter changes to be observed.
 
17
For a sophisticated formal model of coups and regime survival, see Gallego and Pitchik (2004).
 
18
See Haggard and Kaufman (1995), Gasiorowski (1995), Alesina et al. (1996), Przeworski et al. (2000), Przeworski and Limongi (1997), Chong and Calderon (2000), Boix and Stokes (2003), and Glaeser et al. (2004), among others.
 
19
As we pointed out in the introduction, according to Arendt (1951) and many other political scientists, in a true totalitarian regime the masses are mobilized to support the regime. The less salient is that case, the more the regime tends to descend into tyranny, as appears to be happening, for example, in Iran today.
 
20
We are holding the tax rate τ constant here, since we are interested in the sign of the partial derivative of x w.r.t. g.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91, 938–963. CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2001). A theory of political transitions. American Economic Review, 91, 938–963. CrossRef
go back to reference Alesina, A., Ozler, S., Roubini, N., & Swagel, P. (1996). Political instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 189–211. CrossRef Alesina, A., Ozler, S., Roubini, N., & Swagel, P. (1996). Political instability and economic growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 189–211. CrossRef
go back to reference Arendt, H. (1951). The origins of totalitarianism. New York: Schocken. Arendt, H. (1951). The origins of totalitarianism. New York: Schocken.
go back to reference Arshinov, V., & Fuchs, C. (2003). Preface. In V. Arshinov & C. Fuchs (Eds.), Causality, emergence, self-organization (pp. 5–18). Moscow: NIA-Priroda. Arshinov, V., & Fuchs, C. (2003). Preface. In V. Arshinov & C. Fuchs (Eds.), Causality, emergence, self-organization (pp. 5–18). Moscow: NIA-Priroda.
go back to reference Bar-El, R. (2009). Dictatorships, development, and the virtue of political instability. Public Choice, 138, 29–44. CrossRef Bar-El, R. (2009). Dictatorships, development, and the virtue of political instability. Public Choice, 138, 29–44. CrossRef
go back to reference Barro, R. (1996a). Democracy and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 1–27. CrossRef Barro, R. (1996a). Democracy and growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 1, 1–27. CrossRef
go back to reference Barro, R. (1996b). Getting it right. Cambridge: MIT Press. Barro, R. (1996b). Getting it right. Cambridge: MIT Press.
go back to reference Boix, C., & Stokes, S. C. (2003). Endogenous democratization. World Politics, 55, 517–549. CrossRef Boix, C., & Stokes, S. C. (2003). Endogenous democratization. World Politics, 55, 517–549. CrossRef
go back to reference Brezis, E. S., & Schnytzer, A. (2003). Why are the transition paths in China and Eastern Europe so different? A political economy perspective. Economics of Transition, 11, 3–23. CrossRef Brezis, E. S., & Schnytzer, A. (2003). Why are the transition paths in China and Eastern Europe so different? A political economy perspective. Economics of Transition, 11, 3–23. CrossRef
go back to reference Chaturvedi, A., & Münster, J. (2007). Long live the king? On dictatorship and development. Berlin: WZB. Unpublished. Chaturvedi, A., & Münster, J. (2007). Long live the king? On dictatorship and development. Berlin: WZB. Unpublished.
go back to reference Chong, A., & Calderon, C. (2000). Causality and feedback between institutional measures and economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12, 69–81. CrossRef Chong, A., & Calderon, C. (2000). Causality and feedback between institutional measures and economic growth. Economics and Politics, 12, 69–81. CrossRef
go back to reference Cordless, R. M., Gonnet, G. H., Hare, D. E. G., Jeffrey, D. J., & Knuth, D. E. (1996). On Lambert’s W function. Advances in Computational Mathematics, 5, 329–359. CrossRef Cordless, R. M., Gonnet, G. H., Hare, D. E. G., Jeffrey, D. J., & Knuth, D. E. (1996). On Lambert’s W function. Advances in Computational Mathematics, 5, 329–359. CrossRef
go back to reference Galetovic, A., & Sanhueza, R. (2000). Citizens, autocrats, and plotters: a model and new evidence on coups d’etat. Economics and Politics, 12, 183–204. CrossRef Galetovic, A., & Sanhueza, R. (2000). Citizens, autocrats, and plotters: a model and new evidence on coups d’etat. Economics and Politics, 12, 183–204. CrossRef
go back to reference Gallego, M. (1998). Economic performance and leadership accountability: an econometric analysis. Economics and Politics, 10, 249–296. CrossRef Gallego, M. (1998). Economic performance and leadership accountability: an econometric analysis. Economics and Politics, 10, 249–296. CrossRef
go back to reference Gallego, M., & Pitchik, C. (2004). An economic theory of leadership turnover. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2361–2382. CrossRef Gallego, M., & Pitchik, C. (2004). An economic theory of leadership turnover. Journal of Public Economics, 88, 2361–2382. CrossRef
go back to reference Gasiorowski, M. J. (1995). Economic crises and political regime change: an event history analysis. American Political Science Review, 89, 882–897. CrossRef Gasiorowski, M. J. (1995). Economic crises and political regime change: an event history analysis. American Political Science Review, 89, 882–897. CrossRef
go back to reference Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 271–303. CrossRef Glaeser, E. L., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2004). Do institutions cause growth? Journal of Economic Growth, 9, 271–303. CrossRef
go back to reference Grossman, H. I., & Noh, S. J. (1994). Proprietary public finance and economic welfare. Journal of Public Economics, 53, 187–204. CrossRef Grossman, H. I., & Noh, S. J. (1994). Proprietary public finance and economic welfare. Journal of Public Economics, 53, 187–204. CrossRef
go back to reference Gundlach, E., & Paldam, M. (2009). A farewell to critical junctures: sorting out long-run causality of income and democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 34–54. CrossRef Gundlach, E., & Paldam, M. (2009). A farewell to critical junctures: sorting out long-run causality of income and democracy. European Journal of Political Economy, 25, 34–54. CrossRef
go back to reference Guttman, J. M., Hilger, N., & Shachmurove, Y. (1994). Voting as investment vs. voting as consumption: new evidence. Kyklos, 27, 197–207. CrossRef Guttman, J. M., Hilger, N., & Shachmurove, Y. (1994). Voting as investment vs. voting as consumption: new evidence. Kyklos, 27, 197–207. CrossRef
go back to reference Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. R. (1995). The political economy of democratic transitions. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. R. (1995). The political economy of democratic transitions. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Hillman, A., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1, 17–39. CrossRef Hillman, A., & Riley, J. G. (1989). Politically contestable rents and transfers. Economics and Politics, 1, 17–39. CrossRef
go back to reference Hirshleifer, J. (1989). Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice, 38, 101–112. CrossRef Hirshleifer, J. (1989). Conflict and rent-seeking success functions: ratio vs. difference models of relative success. Public Choice, 38, 101–112. CrossRef
go back to reference Hirshleifer, J. (1995). Theorizing about conflict. In K. Hartley & T. Sandler (Eds.), Handbook of defense economics (Vol. 1, pp. 165–189). Amsterdam: Elsevier. CrossRef Hirshleifer, J. (1995). Theorizing about conflict. In K. Hartley & T. Sandler (Eds.), Handbook of defense economics (Vol. 1, pp. 165–189). Amsterdam: Elsevier. CrossRef
go back to reference Islam, M. N., & Winer, S. L. (2004). Tinpots, totalitarians (and democrats): an empirical investigation of the effects of economic growth on civil liberties and political rights. Public Choice, 118, 289–323. CrossRef Islam, M. N., & Winer, S. L. (2004). Tinpots, totalitarians (and democrats): an empirical investigation of the effects of economic growth on civil liberties and political rights. Public Choice, 118, 289–323. CrossRef
go back to reference Kauffman, S. A. (1993). The origins of order: self-organization and selection in evolution. New York: Oxford University Press. Kauffman, S. A. (1993). The origins of order: self-organization and selection in evolution. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative measures. Economics and Politics, 7, 207–227. CrossRef Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1995). Institutions and economic performance: cross-country tests using alternative measures. Economics and Politics, 7, 207–227. CrossRef
go back to reference Lipset, S. M. (1959). Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53, 69–105. CrossRef Lipset, S. M. (1959). Some social requisites of democracy: economic development and political legitimacy. American Political Science Review, 53, 69–105. CrossRef
go back to reference Londregan, J. B., Bienen, H., & van de Walle, N. (1995). Ethnicity and leadership succession in Africa. International Studies Quarterly, 39, 1–25. CrossRef Londregan, J. B., Bienen, H., & van de Walle, N. (1995). Ethnicity and leadership succession in Africa. International Studies Quarterly, 39, 1–25. CrossRef
go back to reference Londregan, J. B., & Poole, K. T. (1990). Poverty, the coup trap, and the seizure of executive power. World Politics, 42, 151–183. CrossRef Londregan, J. B., & Poole, K. T. (1990). Poverty, the coup trap, and the seizure of executive power. World Politics, 42, 151–183. CrossRef
go back to reference Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712. CrossRef Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 681–712. CrossRef
go back to reference McBride, M. (2005). Crises, reforms, and regime persistence in sub-Saharan Africa. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 688–707. CrossRef McBride, M. (2005). Crises, reforms, and regime persistence in sub-Saharan Africa. European Journal of Political Economy, 21, 688–707. CrossRef
go back to reference McGuire, M. C., & Olson M. Jr., (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: the invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96. McGuire, M. C., & Olson M. Jr., (1996). The economics of autocracy and majority rule: the invisible hand and the use of force. Journal of Economic Literature, 34, 72–96.
go back to reference O’Kane, R. H. T. (1987). The likelihood of coups. Aldershot: Avebury. O’Kane, R. H. T. (1987). The likelihood of coups. Aldershot: Avebury.
go back to reference Olson M. Jr. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576. CrossRef Olson M. Jr. (1993). Dictatorship, democracy, and development. American Political Science Review, 87, 567–576. CrossRef
go back to reference Overland, J., Simons, K. L., & Spagat, M. (2005). Political instability and growth in dictatorships. Public Choice, 125, 445–470. CrossRef Overland, J., Simons, K. L., & Spagat, M. (2005). Political instability and growth in dictatorships. Public Choice, 125, 445–470. CrossRef
go back to reference Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1997). Modernization: theories and facts. World Politics, 49, 155–183. CrossRef Przeworski, A., & Limongi, F. (1997). Modernization: theories and facts. World Politics, 49, 155–183. CrossRef
go back to reference Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and development: political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. New York: Cambridge University Press. CrossRef Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M. E., Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and development: political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950–1990. New York: Cambridge University Press. CrossRef
go back to reference Robinson, J. A. (1999). When is a state predatory? Harvard University. Unpublished. Robinson, J. A. (1999). When is a state predatory? Harvard University. Unpublished.
go back to reference Roemer, J. E. (1985). Rationalizing revolutionary ideology: a tale of Lenin and the tsar. Econometrica, 53, 85–108. CrossRef Roemer, J. E. (1985). Rationalizing revolutionary ideology: a tale of Lenin and the tsar. Econometrica, 53, 85–108. CrossRef
go back to reference Shughart, W. F. (2006). An analytical history of terrorism. Public Choice, 128, 7–39. CrossRef Shughart, W. F. (2006). An analytical history of terrorism. Public Choice, 128, 7–39. CrossRef
go back to reference Skaperdas, S., & Syropolous, C. (1996). Can the shadow of the future harm cooperation? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 29, 355–372. CrossRef Skaperdas, S., & Syropolous, C. (1996). Can the shadow of the future harm cooperation? Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 29, 355–372. CrossRef
go back to reference Smith, B. (2004). Oil wealth and regime survival in the developing world, 1960–1999. American Journal of Political Science, 48, 232–246. CrossRef Smith, B. (2004). Oil wealth and regime survival in the developing world, 1960–1999. American Journal of Political Science, 48, 232–246. CrossRef
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: the economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice. Tullock, G. (1974). The social dilemma: the economics of war and revolution. Blacksburg: Center for Study of Public Choice.
go back to reference Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press. Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In J. M. Buchanan, R. D. Tollison, & G. Tullock (Eds.), Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society (pp. 97–112). College Station: Texas A&M University Press.
go back to reference Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: an economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872. CrossRef Wintrobe, R. (1990). The tinpot and the totalitarian: an economic theory of dictatorship. American Political Science Review, 84, 849–872. CrossRef
go back to reference Tullock, G. (2001). Monarchies, hereditary and non-hereditary. In W. F. Shughart II & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 140–156). Cheltenham Gloss: Edward Elgar. Tullock, G. (2001). Monarchies, hereditary and non-hereditary. In W. F. Shughart II & L. Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice (pp. 140–156). Cheltenham Gloss: Edward Elgar.
go back to reference Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CrossRef Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. CrossRef
go back to reference Wintrobe, R. (2004). Rational revolutions. Homo Oeconomicus, 21, 171–196. Wintrobe, R. (2004). Rational revolutions. Homo Oeconomicus, 21, 171–196.
Metadata
Title
On revolt and endogenous economic policy in autocratic regimes
Authors
Joel M. Guttman
Rafael Reuveny
Publication date
01-04-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0012-3

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2014

Public Choice 1-2/2014 Go to the issue