Skip to main content
Top
Published in:

Open Access 24-06-2024 | Original Paper

On the optimality of policy choices in the face of biased beliefs, retrospective voting and the down-up problem

Authors: Carlos Seixas, Diogo Lourenço

Published in: Social Choice and Welfare | Issue 2/2024

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Previous literature has shown that voters’ biased beliefs regarding policy outcomes incentivize the selection of seemingly better, but socially worse, policies. It has also shown that voters’ tendency to gauge an incumbent’s competence by the present state of the economy (retrospective voting) could counteract biased beliefs. In this article, we argue that, when the advantageous consequences of a measure of policy only accrue with considerable lag (the down-up problem), retrospective voting instead amplifies the effects of biased beliefs. Still, we find that it may nevertheless be optimal for an incumbent to select good long-term policies if the incumbent is strongly motivated by the success of the chosen policies. Finally, we investigate the robustness of these conclusions by considering an incumbent bias, limited accountability, and the introduction of incentive and threshold contracts.
Notes

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

1 Introduction

A crucial question in any democracy is whether its institutional framework and incentive schemes lead political agents to choose policies that foster voters’ welfare (Buchanan 1989; Besley 2004; Gersbach 2012; Besley et al. 2016). Any plausible answer to this question must consider the motivations, limitations and behavioral patterns of both voters and political agents.
As everyday experience and, evermore, systematic evidence show, human beings are far from omniscient agents of unlimited computational capacity. Instead, their cognition and behavior are adjusted to the epistemic and practical circumstances of everyday, social life (Ross 2007). This means that their action is often based on incomplete and sometimes misleading information, processed with all sorts of inferential shortcuts that enable decision-making in loco and real-time. An upshot of this is that humans are also prone to systematic error and bias. Voters, of course, are no different, as evidence from psychology (Redlawsk 2006; Richard and Redlawsk 2006), political science (Althaus 1998; Bergmann 2018) or economics (Caplan 2002, 2007) growingly shows.
Models that wish to begin to capture the variegated tapestry of real voters’ behavior must go beyond the consistency criteria that would define an abstract notion of ‘rationality’ or of ‘rational voter’. Indeed, in a well-known work, Caplan (2007) calls the rational voter “a myth", and there is a growing concern with accounting for behavioral and cognitive biases in political choice (Bischoff and Siemers 2013; Diermeier and Li 2017; Apolte and Müller 2022).
A well-studied departure from the ideal voter is the voter with biased beliefs. Frankovic (2016, 2018), for instance, shows that the public often holds inaccurate beliefs, particularly when they align with prior political preferences. Lee et al. (2021), on the other hand, offer evidence to the effect that government officials “have more accurate factual beliefs" (p. 1326) than voters. One of the consequences of biases in voters’ beliefs is an increased likelihood that a policy with good outcomes for voters is, nevertheless, unpopular, or vice-versa. This has been studied by many (for a survey see Benczes and Szabó 2022). Bischoff and Siemers (2013), in particular, develop a dynamic party competition model that, besides biased beliefs, also takes into account another important regularity in voters’ behavior: their propensity to vote retrospectively, i.e., to assess the competence of a political agent based on their estimates of the state of the economy.1
One of the conclusions of Bischoff and Siemers (2013) is that political agents face a trade-off. A bad yet popular policy bolsters election outcomes today, but its nefarious later consequences harm election outcomes tomorrow. The authors find that, in the most empirically plausible settings, policies will form “a mediocre mix of either good yet unpopular or popular though bad policies" (Bischoff and Siemers 2013, p.164), a conclusion with strong echoes in the literature (Dornbusch and Edwards 1990; Rovira Kaltwasser 2009; Acemoglu et al. 2013; Mudde and Rovira Kaltwasser 2017, 2018; Benczes and Szabó 2022). Crucially, however, they also show that retrospective voting counteracts the potentially deleterious effects of biased voting and thus could foster the selection of socially better policies.
In this article, we study policy choices whose effects are felt with a lag that is significant with respect to the electoral cycle. In structural or supply side policies such a long lag is especially likely. Here, the “self-correction mechanism" provided by retrospective voting in Bischoff and Siemers (2013) is unavailable. In fact, retrospective voting should instead amplify the effect of biased beliefs, further incentivizing political agents to choose a bad policy.
Indeed, policies improving overall welfare sometimes have a negative short and medium-term effect on both the economy and welfare, as their advantages and benefits only accrue or become evident to voters much later on. This phenomenon may be called the down-up problem. Policies to fight climate change, population ageing, or mounting public debt offer examples. The down-up problem often results in policy myopia or short-termism, as political agents favor their own short-term goals over long-term welfare (Rogoff 1990; MacKenzie 2016; Boston 2017).
In this paper, we extend the model of Bischoff and Siemers (2013) to accommodate the down-up problem. It is introduced by assuming, in contrast with Bischoff and Siemers (2013), that important consequences of a measure of policy are lagged to such a degree that they are only evident in the subsequent electoral term, as in the works of Gersbach (2003, 2004) and Müller (2007). As in the latter contribution, our strategy hinges on considering the complex motivations of political agents. We assume that they care not only about (re)election, but also about the results of their policies (Adams et al. 2005; Shieh and Pan 2010).
As for biased beliefs and retrospective voting, we follow Bischoff and Siemers (2013), incorporating the former through voters’ estimates of the goodness of a measure of policy, and the latter through their assessment of a political agent’s competence upon observation of the state of the economy.
Like Bischoff and Siemers (2013), we deduce that policy choices in equilibrium could range from socially optimal to socially pernicious. We therefore show that these authors’ conclusion that the incumbent may choose a good long term policy-mix when voters have biased beliefs is robust to the introduction of the down-up problem. However, we also further elucidate what it takes for this to happen in the face of this problem. We show that two conditions are necessary and jointly sufficient: the incumbent must not worry only about reelection and must set enough store by the success of the chosen policies.
We believe this result to be insightful and non-trivial. If Bischoff and Siemers (2013) conclude that retrospective voting corrects inefficiencies brought by biased beliefs, making the selection of good policies a possible outcome, we show that when down-up issues are considered, such an outcome only results if the political agent is motivated to undertake socially good policies.
We also extend our baseline model by considering three extensions, the first two adapted from Bischoff and Siemers (2013). First, we introduce an incumbent bias to capture the empirical fact that an elected politician has greater chances of reelection (Alesina and Rosenthal 1995). Second, we investigate limited accountability, capturing the fact that a political agent does not fully control the outcome of a measure of policy (Kiewiet 2000; Leigh 2009; Duch and Stevenson 2010). Third, we address incentive and threshold contracts seeking to motivate political agents to choose socially desirable policies (as developed by Gersbach (2003, 2004); Gersbach and Liessem (2008); Müller (2007), surveyed in Gersbach (2012) and further extended in Gersbach (2017); Gersbach and Ponta (2017); Britz et al. (2022)).
These extensions offer the following main conclusions: (i) an incumbent bias leads the incumbent to choose better policies; (ii) limited accountability can increase the quality of the policies chosen, and, finally, (iii) threshold and incentive contracts can also increase the quality of the policies chosen, but there are circumstances in which the opposite is true.
This article is organized as follows. In Sect. 2, we discuss the assumptions and workings of the model. Its equilibrium is characterized in Sect. 3. The extensions to the baseline model are treated in Sect. 4. Section 5 discusses the results and concludes.

2 Framework

2.1 Point of departure: Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model

Our model builds on that of Bischoff and Siemers (2013). Here, there is a continuum \(i \in \left[ 0,1\right] \) of voters and two competing parties that run for term t on their respective policy platforms. There is no abstention, and the elected party implements the promised platform, \(\eta _{t}\),2 which determines the macroeconomic performance (\(a_t\)), voter i’s income (\(y_{it}\)) and utility at t:
$$\begin{aligned} U_{it}= U_{it}(a_{it}(\eta _{t}),y_{it}(\eta _{t}))\equiv U_{it}\left( \eta _{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(1)
Before implementation, however, the voter can but estimate the effect a policy platform would have on her utility:
$$\begin{aligned} {\hat{U}}_{it}\equiv {\hat{U}}_{it}\left( \eta _{t}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(2)
Policy platforms can be good (\(\eta _{g}\)), bad (\(\eta _{b}\)) or any linear combination of the two (\(0\le \beta \le 1\) denoting the weight of the bad policy). To capture biased beliefs, Bischoff and Siemers (2013) assume that a majority of voters incorrectly estimates that \({\hat{U}}_{it}\left( \eta _{b}\right) \succ {\hat{U}}_{it}\left( \eta _{g}\right) \), i.e., that the bad policy is best for them, while, in fact \(U_{it}\left( \eta _{g}\right) \succ U_{it}\left( \eta _{b}\right) \) holds.
Besides \({\hat{U}}_{it}\), in Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model voter i’s behavior also hinges on her perception of candidates’ competence, or valence (\(\gamma \)). This perception results from her comparison of the economy’s performance in \(t-1\) (\(a_{t-1}(\eta _{t-1})\)) with a subjective benchmark (\(\bar{a}_i\)). A better (worse) than expected performance is associated with a higher (lower) valence for the party in power in the previous period, the incumbent (I): \(\gamma _{it}^I\left( \eta _{t-1}\right) >\left( <\right) 0\). The opposition party (O) has a valence of zero: \(\gamma _{it}^O=0\). Both parties are assumed to be, in fact, equally competent.
Voting behaviour is probabilistic. The probability of i’s voting for party \(j\in \{I,O\}\), \(\pi _{it}^j\), depends on the difference in the estimated utilities of the running platforms, corrected by differences in perceived valence. As these two components are assumed to be additively separable, the expected vote share for each party is given by:
$$\begin{aligned} \Pi _{t}^j\left( {\hat{U}}_{it}^j\left( \eta _{t}^{j}\right) ,{\hat{U}}_{it}^{-j}\left( \eta _{t}^{-j}\right) , \gamma _{it}^j,\gamma _{it}^{-j}\right) =\int \limits _{i=0}^{1}\pi _{it}di=\Lambda _{t}^{j}\left( \eta _{t}^j,\eta _{t}^{-j} \right) +V_{t}^{j}\left( \gamma _{it}^j,\gamma _{it}^{-j}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(3)
where \(\Lambda _{t}^{j}\) and \(V_{t}^{j}\) are the policy-related and the valence-related vote shares of party j, respectively. The policy-related share is further defined by (see Bischoff and Siemers 2013, pp.171–172):
$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda _{t}^j(\eta _t^j,\eta _t^{-j})=\frac{1}{2}+(\beta _t^j-\beta _t^{-j})\cdot f \end{aligned}$$
(4)
where \(f>0\) accounts for the effects of biased beliefs. As for the valence-related share, it is given by3
$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}^I\left( \eta _{t-1}^I\right) =\beta _{t-1}^I\cdot \left( -v\right) +\left( 1-\beta _{t-1}^I\right) \cdot v=\left( 1-2\beta _{t-1}^I\right) \cdot v \end{aligned}$$
(5)
$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}^O\left( \eta _{t-1}^O\right) \equiv -V_{t}^I\left( \eta _{t-1}^I\right) \end{aligned}$$
(6)
Competing parties are assumed to be perfectly informed office-seekers and to behave non-cooperatively with a horizon of two periods. They select their running platform by considering its impact on election probability today and discounted valence tomorrow, i.e., the platform that maximizes:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _t^j = \Pi _{t}^j\left( {\hat{U}}_{it}^j,{\hat{U}}_{it}^{-j}, \gamma _{it}^j,\gamma _{it}^{-j}\right) +\delta E(V_{t+1}^j) \end{aligned}$$
(7)
where \(\delta \in \left( 0,1\right] \) is the discount factor that captures the time preference of both politicians and voters.
In this setup, the parties face a clear trade-off: running on a worse policy for term t may bolster the odds of an election victory, but its implementation will damage voters’ perceptions of the party in the future. In other words, retrospective voting may alleviate the effect of biased beliefs and promote the selection of better policy platforms.

2.2 Modeling the down-up problem

In Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model, as just summarily described, the effect of a policy platform on voters’ utility is exhausted during the term of its implementation t. Its only subsequent impact is on the parties’ valence in the election for term \(t+1\). However, there are policies that are painful (agreeable) to voters when first implemented, and whose overall beneficial (harmful) effects are not immediately obvious, but only felt after the election for a subsequent term (the down-up problem). Such policies are often necessary to address major issues, such as climate change, population ageing, mounting public debt, and others.4
To study the down-up problem, we modify Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model in several ways. Instead of two parties running for term t, we assume that an already elected incumbent, unconstrained by electoral promises, chooses and implements a policy-platform for term t that affects voters in both t and \(t+1\). The opposition runs for term \(t+1\).5 The election for term \(t+1\) now takes place at the end of term t, when the future effects of the implemented policy are yet unperceived by voters.
Voter i’s real utilities at t therefore now depend on both \(\eta _{t}\) and \(\eta _{t-1}\):
$$\begin{aligned} U_{it}\equiv U_{it}\left( \eta _{t},\eta _{t-1}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(8)
The down-up problem itself is captured by imposing, for all voters, that the bad policy produces better results immediately, at t, \(U_{it}\left( \eta _{gt}, \eta _{t-1}\right) <U_{it}\left( \eta _{bt},\eta _{t-1}\right) \), but that the good policy is, indeed, better overall:
$$\begin{aligned} U_{it}\left( \eta _{gt}, \eta _{t-1}\right) +\delta U_{it+1}\left( \eta _{t+1},\eta _{gt}\right) >U_{it}\left( \eta _{bt},\eta _{t-1}\right) +\delta U_{it+1}\left( \eta _{t+1},\eta _{bt}\right) \end{aligned}$$
(9)
Biased beliefs impose, however, that voters at t fail to appreciate that the good policy is better overall.6
If, due to the down up problem, a bad policy has a better outcome during the term of its implementation, unlike Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model, then it should yield positive valence (\(v>0\)) to the incumbent in the election for the subsequent term. In other words,7
$$\begin{aligned} V_{t}^I\left( \eta _{t}^I\right) =\beta _{t}^I\cdot v+\left( 1-\beta _{t}^I\right) \cdot \left( -v\right) =v\cdot \left( 2\beta _{t}^I-1\right) \end{aligned}$$
(10)
As in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), the opposition enjoys the symmetrical valence.
Clearly, retrospective voting no longer counteracts biased beliefs in promoting the selection of a better policy. Under these assumptions, a pure office-seeker incumbent would (trivially) never implement a better policy. However, besides office-seeking, parties and politicians may be directly motivated by the effects of the policies they implement (Evans 2018).8 Accordingly, we generalize candidates’ objective functions to accommodate both motivations. We take a leaf from Müller (2007), who assumes that the political agent is concerned with the social impact of the chosen policies, but only while holding office. That impact can offer a private gain in addition to the satisfaction and advantages of holding office.
We introduce both motivations in an additively separable way. The office-seeking motivation is captured by a lump-sum value \(Z>0\). The policy-seeking motivation is captured with a function similar to a voter’s utility: \(W_{t}^j\equiv W^j_{t}\left( \eta _{t},\eta _{t-1}\right) \). Thus, it will also be true that \(W^j_{t}\left( \eta _{gt},\eta _{t-1}\right) <W^j_{t}\left( \eta _{bt},\eta _{t-1}\right) \) and
$$\begin{aligned} W^j_{t}\left( \eta _{gt},\eta _{t-1}\right) +\delta W^j_{t+1}\left( \eta _{t+1},\eta _{gt}\right) >W^j_{t}\left( \eta _{bt},\eta _{t-1}\right) +\delta W^j_{t+1}\left( \eta _{t+1},\eta _{bt}\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(11)
The incumbent is perfectly informed and chooses the policy platform at t that maximises:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _{t}^I(\eta _{t})=\left( 1-m\right) Z+mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{t},\eta _{t-1}\right) +\delta \Pi _{t}^I\left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{t+1},\eta _{t}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(12)
The parameter \(0\le m \le 1\) measures the motivational weight of implementing good policies. In other words, a high m indicates more of a “policy success-seeker”, while a low m more of an “office-seeker”.
Regarding the, also perfectly informed, opposition, it runs against the incumbent for term \(t+1\). Since, as in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), the incumbent and the opposition behave non-cooperatively, they both run on the bad platform in the election for period \(t+1\). This is less obvious in our setup than in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), since in their model political agents are pure office seekers, while now they have two sources of motivation. However, as with voters, a bad policy yields a higher policy payoff in the term of implementation, while any effects after term \(t+1\) are outside the horizon of the game. We may thus focus on the incumbent’s policy choice in term t. In other words, we can consider \(W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{t},\eta _{t-1}\right) \equiv W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{t}\right) \) and \(W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{t+1},\eta _{t}\right) \equiv W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{t}\right) \) from the point of view of the incumbents’ strategic choice.

3 Political equilibrium

To deduce the political equilibrium, for simplicity and without loss of generality, we normalize the utility of the good policy in term t and the utility of the bad policy in \(t+1\) to zero, that is, \(W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) =0\) and \(W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) =0\). As a result, given (11), we have \(\delta W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) >W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) \). We also recall that, as in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), we assume that the policy platform chosen by the incumbent can be purely good, \(\eta _g\), purely bad, \(\eta _b\), or any linear combination of the two (\(0\le \beta \le 1\) denoting the weight of the bad policy).
The incumbent’s payoff, as given by (12), can therefore be expressed as:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _{t}^I\left( \beta _{t}\right) =\left( 1-m\right) Z+m\beta _{t}W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\delta Q\left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+m\left( 1-\beta _{t}\right) W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(13)
where \(Q=\frac{1}{2}+\left( f+v\right) \left( 2\beta _t-1\right) \) is the probability of reelection. It reflects the fact that, in the face of the down-up problem, the choice of a bad policy not only bolsters the probability of reelection through the effect of biased beliefs, as measured by f, but also, unlike Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model, through its impact on valence, as measured by v.
For ease of exposition, we define:
  • \(Q^{max}\) to denote the maximum reelection probability, given by \(\left( \frac{1}{2}+f+v\right) \) and obtained when the purely bad policy is chosen (\(\beta _t=1\)).
  • \(Q^{min}\) to denote the minimum reelection probability, given by \(\left( \frac{1}{2}-f-v\right) \) and obtained when the purely good policy is chosen (\(\beta _t=0\)).
  • \(Q'_{\beta }\) to denote the marginal impact on the reelection probability of worsening the policy platform (\(\frac{\partial Q}{\partial \beta }\)), given by \(2\left( f+v\right) \).
Proposition 1
Given the definitions of \(Q^{max}\), \(Q^{min}\) and \(Q'_{\beta }\):
(a)
\(\beta _t=0\) if \(\delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( Q^{min}-Q'_{\beta }\right) \ge mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\delta \left( 1-m\right) ZQ'_{\beta }\).
 
(b)
\(\beta _t=1\) if \(\delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) Q^{max}\le mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\delta \left( 1-m\right) ZQ'_{\beta }\).
 
(c)
\(\beta _t\in \left( 0,1\right) \) if \(\dfrac{mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\delta \left( 1-m\right) ZQ'_{\beta }}{Q^{max}}<\delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \) \(<\dfrac{mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\delta \left( 1-m\right) ZQ'_{\beta }}{\left( Q^{min}-Q'_{\beta }\right) }\).
 
Proof
See Appendix A. \(\square \)
Proposition 1 identifies conditions that are sufficient to ensure that the incumbent chooses the purely good policy (case a), the purely bad policy (case b), or a mixture (case c). As in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), all three are, therefore, possible, so this result is robust. In their original model, however, the trade-off driving the results was between bolstering the odds of election today versus those of election tomorrow, as retrospective voting penalized more popular, but worse, policies. In the model revised to account for the down-up problem, retrospective voting instead further incentivizes the selection of worse policies. The key trade-off is now between the reelection probability and a lower incumbent satisfaction with the policy choice.
In the interpretation of Proposition 1, a crucial magnitude is given by:
$$\begin{aligned} mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\delta \left( 1-m\right) ZQ'_{\beta } \end{aligned}$$
(14)
It is the sum of the incumbent’s satisfaction with a bad policy in the term of its implementation (\(mW^I_{t}(\eta _{bt})\)) and the marginal future electoral benefits that choosing a worse policy today would bring (\(\delta \left( 1-m\right) ZQ'_{\beta }\)). Even though the worsening of the implemented policy platform has a constant marginal impact on the reelection probability, the expected benefit is higher, the higher the reelection probability.
A purely good policy is chosen (case a), if the present value of the future satisfaction derived from choosing the good policy (\(\delta mW^I_{t+1}(\eta _{gt})\)), weighed by the loss in reelection probability from not implementing any bit of the bad policy platform, is high enough to compensate (14). In other words, the purely good policy is chosen, ceteris paribus, if the incumbent values the effect of its policies high enough.
In the other extreme, if it values it so little that even with the highest odds of reelection (\(\delta mQ^{max}W^I_{t+1}(\eta _{gt})\)) does not compensate (14), then the purely bad policy is chosen (case b).
The effects of biased beliefs and retrospective voting, measured by f and v, are also key. If \(Q^{min}\le Q'_{\beta }\), then \(3\left( f+v\right) \ge \frac{1}{2}\), and only case (b) is possible. Also noteworthy is whether the incumbent is more or less of an office-seeker. The lower the m, the higher the \(\beta _t\). In other words, the more a political agent seeks the perks of being in office, the higher the fraction of the bad policy implemented. Indeed, if \(m=0\) the purely bad platform is always implemented (case b). This case is a simple extension of Bischoff and Siemers (2013)’s model to a context characterised by the down-up problem. In the face of this problem, valence does not counteract the effect of biased beliefs, so a pure office-seeker (\(m=0\)) always selects the bad platform, which motivates our considering policy-seeking politicians too.

4 Extensions of the baseline model

We now offer three extensions of the baseline model. First, we introduce an incumbent bias, to capture the regularity that incumbents tend to enjoy higher odds of reelection. Second, we introduce limited accountability to capture the fact that policy outcomes are not all within the control of the political agent. Finally, we assess the impact of threshold and incentive contracts on the behaviour of the incumbent.

4.1 Incumbent bias

Incumbent bias refers to the often observed tendency of officeholders to benefit from an electoral advantage over challengers. Many reasons have been adduced to explain the bias. Incumbents benefit from greater resources, established networks, access to voters, name recognition, and others (Fouirnaies and Hall 2014; Meirowitz 2008; Carson et al. 2007; Hirano and Snyder 2009; Gordon and D., L. 2009; Hall and Snyder 2015).
As in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), an incumbent bias may be captured by introducing a parameter \(\rho ^{Inc}>0\) into the reelection probability. The incumbent assesses the impact of the bias in favour of reelection. The payoff function for the incumbent then reads:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta _{t}^I\left( \beta _{t}\right) =&\left( 1-m\right) Z+m\beta _{t}W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\nonumber \\&\quad +\delta \left( Q+\rho ^{Inc}\right) \left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+m\left( 1-\beta _{t}\right) W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(15)
Proposition 2
In equilibrium, the higher the incumbent bias, the better the chosen policy platform: \(\dfrac{\partial \beta _t}{\partial \rho ^{Inc}}<0\).
Proof
See Appendix A. \(\square \)
An incumbent bias allows the incumbent to select a better policy while enjoying a higher reelection probability than would be the case absent the bias. The incumbent can benefit from the good policy results in the second period without having to build as much valence through the selection of a worse policy platform. This is an important result, as this advantage allows the incumbent to undertake better policies without as much regard for immediate results.
As in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), the bias counteracts the effect of retrospective voting. In that model, retrospective voting incentivizes the selection of better policies. If the incumbent enjoys a positive bias, there is less need to choose a better policy to build valence. By contrast, if the down-up problem is at issue, retrospective voting incentivizes the selection of a worse policy platform. Symmetrically, an incumbent bias now fosters the selection of a better policy platform.

4.2 Limited accountability

The outcomes of any policy always partly transcend the political agent that is behind it. Among other possibilities, they often depend on the policies of other actors. This is not, however, always obvious to voters. Consequently, an incumbent may be punished or rewarded independently of the responsibility for a policy outcome. This affects both the incumbent’s valence and the policy payoff. As in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), we extend our model to capture this by letting both magnitudes depend not only on \(\beta _t\), as before, but also on a nondeterministic \(0<\beta _t^{ex}<1\), which might be interpreted as the, not always predictable, strategy of other, exogenous actors. The fraction of the outcome the incumbent knows to control is captured by the coefficient k (\(0<k<1\)). They further depend on exogenous stochastic shocks, \(\varepsilon \).
The incumbent’s valence now becomes:
$$\begin{aligned} V^{I}_{t}\left( \beta _{t},\beta _t^{ex}\right)&=k\left[ \beta _{t}\cdot v+\left( 1-\beta _{t}\right) \left( -v\right) \right] +\left( 1-k\right) \left[ \beta _t^{ex}\cdot v+\left( 1-\beta _t^{ex}\right) \left( -v\right) \right] +\varepsilon \nonumber \\&=v\left[ k\left( 2\beta _{t}-1\right) +\left( 1-k\right) \left( 2\beta _t^{ex}-1\right) \right] +\varepsilon \end{aligned}$$
(16)
The incumbent forms an expectation as to the value of the nondeterministic variables, \(\beta _t^{ex}\) and \(\varepsilon \), with \(0<E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) <1\) and \(E\left( \varepsilon \right) =0\), respectively. The (expected) payoff at t then reads:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta ^I_t\left( \beta _{t}\right) =&\left( 1-m\right) Z+mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) \left[ k\beta _{t}+\left( 1-k\right) E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) \right] +\delta Q_{l}\nonumber \\ {}&\cdot \left\{ \left( 1-m\right) Z+mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left[ k\left( 1-\beta _{t}\right) +\left( 1-k\right) \left( 1-E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) \right) \right] \right\} \end{aligned}$$
(17)
In this new setup, the probability of reelection, now denoted by \(Q_{l}\) to emphasize the existence of limited accountability, is given by \(Q_{l}=\frac{1}{2}+\left( f+kv\right) \left( 2\beta _{t}-1\right) +\left( 1-k\right) v\left( 2E\left( \beta ^{ex}_{t}\right) -1\right) \).9 The marginal impact on the reelection probability of worsening the policy platform (\(\frac{\partial Q_{l}}{\partial \beta }\)) is now \(Q'_{\beta l}=2\left( f+kv\right) \), while the minimum reelection probability, \(Q^{min}_{l}\), changes to \(\frac{1}{2}-f-kv+\left( 1-k\right) v\left( 2E(\beta ^{ex}_{t})-1\right) \).
Proposition 3
Suppose the incumbent faces limited accountability. Given the definitions of \(Q^{min}_{l}\) and \(Q'_{\beta l}\):
  • If \(E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) \) increases, i.e., if the incumbent expects a worse strategy by exogenous actors, the incumbent’s policy platform becomes better. In other words, \(\dfrac{\partial \beta _t}{\partial E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) }<0\).
  • If the fraction of control, i.e., k, increases, all outcomes are possible:
    (a)
    The policy platform becomes better, i.e., \(\dfrac{\partial \beta _t}{\partial k}<0\), if: \(\dfrac{vW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) }{\delta Q_{\beta l}^{'2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\dfrac{\left( 1-m\right) Z}{2mk^{2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\dfrac{1}{2k^2}> v\dfrac{Q^{min}_{l}}{Q_{\beta l}^{'2}}+E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) \left[ \dfrac{Q'_{\beta l}+2k^2v}{2k^2Q'_{\beta l}}\right] \);
     
    (b)
    The policy platform becomes worse, i.e., \(\dfrac{\partial \beta _t}{\partial k}\ge 0\), if: \( \dfrac{vW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) }{\delta Q_{\beta l}^{'2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\dfrac{\left( 1-m\right) Z}{2mk^{2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\dfrac{1}{2k^2}< v\dfrac{Q^{min}_{l}}{Q_{\beta l}^{'2}}+E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) \left[ \dfrac{Q'_{\beta l}+2k^2v}{2k^2Q'_{\beta l}}\right] \);
     
    (c)
    The policy platform remains the same, i.e., \(\dfrac{\partial \beta _t}{\partial k}=0\), if: \( \dfrac{vW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) }{\delta Q_{\beta l}^{'2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\dfrac{\left( 1-m\right) Z}{2mk^{2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\dfrac{1}{2k^2}= v\dfrac{Q^{min}_{l}}{Q_{\beta l}^{'2}}+E\left( \beta _t^{ex}\right) \left[ \dfrac{Q'_{\beta l}+2k^2v}{2k^2Q'_{\beta l}}\right] \);
     
Proof
See Appendix A. \(\square \)
According to Proposition 3, when the strategy of exogenous actors bolsters the incumbent’s valence, the latter chooses a better policy platform, as valence becomes a (marginally) lesser concern. A higher payoff in the second period is consequently achievable through the selection of a better policy. This is similar to Bischoff and Siemers (2013).
As for the fraction of control, k, Proposition 3 establishes that its effect on the quality of the policy platform can go either way. This contrasts with Bischoff and Siemers (2013), where an increase in the fraction of control unequivocally increases the quality of the policy platform. In their model, when the incumbent enjoys greater control, both parties are motivated to increase valence, i.e., to improve their policy platforms. In ours, on the other hand, due to the down-up problem, the desire to increase valence leads to the symmetrical result. Hence, Proposition 3 predicts that an increase in the fraction of control may lead to worse policy platforms instead (case b).
This said, the improvement predicted by Bischoff and Siemers (2013) is also possible (case a). It hinges on the relative magnitude of the benefit of holding office (Z), the payoff at t of the bad policy ( \(W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) \)), and the payoff at \(t+1\) of the good policy (\(W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \)). When the incumbent enjoys greater control over policy outcomes, a relatively lower payoff of the good policy at \(t+1\) incentivizes the choice of a better policy platform to compensate. This rationale is different than what drives the results in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), since in their model political agents are pure office seekers. Finally, the fraction of control may be irrelevant (case c) when cases (a) and (b) balance out.

4.3 Incentive and threshold contracts

A proposal to address the down-up problem is the adoption of incentive contracts (Gersbach 2003, 2004; Müller 2007). Incentive contracts make the utility of political agents dependent on the outcomes they can influence (Gersbach 2012). This can be achieved through a reward of a monetary or intangible nature. The reward would be granted during or after the term ends, conditional on the outcome of the policies implemented while in office. For instance, there are scholars supporting linking the pay of members of congress to the growth in real domestic product (McPike 2011).
An alternative to incentive contracts are threshold contracts, suggested by Liessem (2008); Gersbach and Liessem (2008). These contracts identify “a performance level that a politician must reach by the end of a term to obtain the right to stand for reelection" (Gersbach 2012, p.824). The performance level could be defined by candidates during the campaign or set by an external authority, such as a court.10
Extant examples of measures similar to incentive or threshold contracts often address budget issues. The No Budget, No Pay Law in the U.S. (Public Law No: 113–3, 2013) suspends the debt ceiling and penalizes Congress members for not passing budget bills on time. New York has a similar law (N.Y. LEGIS. LAW §5), and California’s Proposition 1F (CAL. CONST. art. III, §8, amended 2009) prohibits pay raises for state officials in deficit years. In Italy, mayors face sanctions for overspending (Grembi et al. 2016).
Devising either kind of contract faces challenges. First, the tasks and challenges of officeholders are not determined in advance. Second, it is difficult to objectively assess the outcomes of their actions. Third, enforcement is problematic (Gersbach 2017; Britz et al. 2022).
To study incentive contracts in our model, we take a leaf from Müller (2007). In his model, a political agent seeking reelection must make future income dependent on the results of the chosen policies. Adapting to our model, we impose that the incumbent is only allowed to run for reelection after accepting a contract that establishes that the compensation in the second term (\(t+1\)) includes a reward that is proportional to the policy payoff in that period11: \(\sigma \left( 1-\beta _{t}\right) W^I_{t+1}\), where \(0< \sigma \le 1\).
As a result, the payoff reads:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta ^{I}_t\left( \beta _{t}\right){} & {} =\left( 1-m\right) Z+m\beta _{t}W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) \nonumber \\{} & {} \quad +\delta Q\left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+m\left( 1+\sigma \right) \left( 1-\beta _{t}\right) W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(18)
These assumptions lead to the following proposition:
Proposition 4
For \(0<\sigma \le 1\), two outcomes are possible:
(a)
\(If \ 0<m\le 1\), the higher the \(\sigma \), that is, the more the future utility depends on the economic performance in the second term, the better the chosen policy platform, i.e., \(\dfrac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial \sigma }<0\);
 
(b)
\(If \ m=0,\ then \ \dfrac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial \sigma }=0\), that is, the incentive contract has no effect on the chosen policy platform.
 
Proof
See Appendix A. \(\square \)
In face of the down-up problem and retrospective voting, as here modeled, if the incumbent is in some degree concerned with the success of its policies, an incentive contract of the kind considered here fosters better policies, as in Gersbach (2003, 2004). However, without policy motivated incumbents, the incentive contract has no effect on the chosen policy platform. In other words, a purely bad policy platform could still be implemented.
As the reward depends on the economic results of the period, the type of contract just considered is more of a short-term contract. Alternatively, we could devise a longer-term incentive contract, according to which the politician’s reward would be delayed until the next period in office or after retirement (Gersbach 2012). In the first case, the incumbent has a greater incentive to choose the bad policy, as more benefits would accrue at \(t+1\) from applying it at t. In the second case, the reward would not depend on the reelection probability and the contract would indeed offer a greater incentive to choose the good policy. On the other hand, such a contract would face an increased difficulty in the definition of which results are due to the politician in office and which to the retired politician.
To investigate whether threshold contracts fare better, we seek inspiration in Gersbach and Liessem (2008). Here, an incumbent is only eligible for reelection if a contractually set performance level is achieved.
We introduce them into our model by assuming that the incumbent signs a contract according to which the chosen policy platform must have a fraction of the bad policy, \(\beta _{t}\), below a prespecified value, that is \(\beta _{t}\le \overline{\beta }\), which measures a minimum quality of the policy the incumbent must ensure. Otherwise, the incumbent will be barred from standing for reelection.12
With these assumptions, we deduce the following proposition:
Proposition 5
Suppose a threshold contract imposing \(\beta _{t}\le \overline{\beta }\) and let \(\beta ^*\) be the optimal choice of \(\beta _t\) if no such contract were in force. Given the definitions of \(Q'_{\beta }\) and \(Q^{min}\) for the baseline model:
(a)
When \(\beta ^*\le \overline{\beta }\), \(\beta _{t}=\beta ^*\), as defined by conditions (a), (b) and (c) in proposition 1.
 
(b)
When \(\beta ^*>\overline{\beta }\)
(i)
\(\beta _{t}=\overline{\beta }\) if \(m\left( 1-\overline{\beta }\right) W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) <\delta \left( Q^{min}+\overline{\beta }Q'_{\beta }\right) \) \( \left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+m\left( 1-\overline{\beta }\right) W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right] \)
 
(ii)
\(\beta _{t}=1\) if \(m\left( 1-\overline{\beta }\right) W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) \ge \delta \left( Q^{min}+\overline{\beta }Q'_{\beta }\right) \) \( \left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+m\left( 1-\overline{\beta }\right) W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right] \)
 
 
Proof
See Appendix A. \(\square \)
When the optimal policy choice is not worse than the threshold, the contract is not binding, and the incumbent chooses the same platform as in its absence (case a). When the optimal policy choice is worse than the threshold, the threshold contract is binding and the incumbent faces a dilemma: either to run for reelection and choose \(\overline{\beta }\), or forego reelection and ignore what happens in \(t+1\). In this latter case, the incumbent has no incentive to choose any other than the purely bad policy as it is the only one that yields a positive result in period t.
If the payoff from choosing \(\overline{\beta }\), which enables running for reelection, is higher than the payoff of choosing the purely bad policy, which maximizes the payoff at t but forestalls the reelection, the incumbent chooses \(\overline{\beta }\). Here, the contract incentivizes the incumbent to choose a better policy than in its absence (case b.i). Threshold contracts could thus enhance the quality of the policy platforms chosen.
However, if the payoff from choosing \(\overline{\beta }\) is lower than the payoff of choosing the purely bad policy, the incumbent chooses the latter (case b.ii). In for a penny, in for a pound, the threshold contract would in this case worsen the policy platform chosen. Threshold contracts thus expand the set of circumstances in which the purely bad policy platform is the best response.
Even though our model is not intended to throw light on the creation these contracts, it offers noteworthy suggestions. For instance, if the threshold contract results from an electoral campaign, as in Gersbach and Liessem (2008), voters’ biased beliefs could lead to the selection of a high \(\overline{\beta }\), reinforcing the conclusion that threshold contracts need not make a positive difference to the policy platform chosen. This problem will still hold in the presence of sophisticated threshold contracts, such as, “vote-share contracts", which are contingent upon the actual results of an election and require incumbents to obtain a specific majority of the votes to stand for reelection (Gersbach 2012). This makes the reelection process more challenging for incumbents compared to first-time candidates and may reinforce the need to apply bad policies in order to get more votes in the reelection.
An alternative to both incentive and threshold contracts, proposed by Gersbach and Ponta (2017), is offering politicians the choice between a flexible and a fixed pension plan. This would encourage office seekers to choose better policies without desincentivizing policy seekers from enacting beneficial long-term policies.

5 Discussion and conclusion

This article models the policy choices of an incumbent in the presence of biased beliefs, retrospective voting, and the down-up problem. In the face of the latter problem, retrospective voting reinforces the effect of biased beliefs in incentivizing the selection of socially pernicious policies. Our findings suggest, however, that when incumbents are genuinely motivated to achieve policy success and when the long-term benefits of policies are sufficiently valued, they may still opt for socially beneficial policies. Our analysis also reveals that an incumbency bias and the anticipation of limited accountability can nudge incumbents towards policies that yield long-term societal benefits. This indicates that, especially at times when structural reforms are called for, there might be an advantage to keeping government in office and even for that government to lose some control over policy outcomes. Similarly, implementing incentive and threshold contracts emerges as a potentially valuable tool for aligning incumbents’ choices with socially optimal outcomes. However, the effectiveness of such mechanisms is contingent upon the specific design of the contracts and, under the circumstances of our model, may still require an appropriate inherent motivation of the incumbent.
Abundant empirical evidence buttresses the importance of candidates that care about the quality of the policies implemented (Perry and Wise 1990; Naff and Crum 1999; Vandenabeele 2009; Fedele and Naticchioni 2016). Still, this only begs the question of how to design a democratic set-up that fosters the selection of such candidates. Given biased beliefs and the assumption that bad policies produce better results in the short term, parties have an incentive to select “office-seekers”, who have better chances of electoral victory.
With its division of powers between national and regional governments, federalism makes it possible for politicians to transition between local, subnational, and federal levels of government, and vice versa (Borchert and Stolz 2011; Edinger and Jahr 2015; Francis and Kenny 2000; Semenova and Dowding 2023). This possibility offers promising avenues to address the challenge of selecting candidates motivated by policy payoffs over short-term electoral gains. It increases scrutiny by allowing governance at multiple levels, making the actions and policies of incumbents more visible. Federally structured governments perform better compared to unitary states in terms of indices of democracy and the safeguarding of rights, as well as in enhancing quality of life (Kincaid 2010). This indicates that such heightened scrutiny makes it more difficult for office-seekers to prioritize short-term gains without facing repercussions. Federalism also encourages diverse policy experimentation, with regions acting as laboratories to demonstrate the long-term benefits of sound policies (Stansel 2005; Pierson 1995; Shin 2019). This can shift voter preferences towards candidates prioritizing long-term benefits. Furthermore, in a federal system, regional and local governments are closer to their constituencies (Oates 1972, 1999), enhancing the electorate’s ability to assess candidates’ motivations and track records. This proximity favors those genuinely committed to policy payoffs. Moreover, federalism fosters political diversity and competition (Tiebout 1956; Qian and Roland 1998; Weingast 1995; Koethenbuerger 2011; Balaguer-Coll et al. 2010; Breton 1998; Crowley and Sobel 2011), thus preventing monopolization of power based on short-term policy gains and incentivizing parties to build reputations for effective governance. This relates to our extension about limited accountability, where the incumbent might have an incentive to apply better policies when there is less control over policy outcomes. Finally, federalism often leads to higher levels of civic engagement and political participation (Inman and Rubinfeld 2020; Bowler and Donovan 2002; Lane and Ersson 2005), with engaged electorates demanding more accountability and supporting candidates committed to public service.
Adjusting the compensation for holding office represents another strategy to promote the selection of candidates motivated by policy success rather than electoral victory (Smart and Strum 2004; Caselli and Morelli 2004; Besley 2004; Mattozzi and Merlo 2008). In our model, compensations such as higher wages do not have a role in the first period. However, in the second period, a higher wage could increase the desirability of holding office, and therefore foster worse policies to ensure reelection. A similar conclusion is found in Smart and Strum (2004). Contrasting with this, Caselli and Morelli (2004), Besley (2004) and Mattozzi and Merlo (2008) conclude that increasing politicians’ pay increases their quality. Our results on incentive contracts indicate that a link between compensation and policy outcomes might indeed lead to better policies, but the motivation of political agents is still of the essence. Furthermore, higher compensation could attract individuals with a strong commitment to policy payoffs, who might otherwise be deterred by the financial sacrifices associated with political office.
Summing up, the main conclusion of this work is that, in the setting we investigate, some self-correction mechanism as in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), or external incentives as in Gersbach (2004) and Müller (2007), are not necessarily sufficient for ensuring that a good policy is chosen and implemented. The latter further requires that two elements be present, first, that the political agent is to a certain degree motivated to apply a good policy and, second, that the benefits perceived are sufficiently high. Still, we emphasize that we have focused on policies whose positive effects take a considerable lag to be observed and felt, and therefore that our results are particularly applicable to measures of policy seeking structural change.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank the editors and two anonymous reviewers for helpful and thorough comments and suggestions.

Declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors have no relevant financial or non-financial interests to disclose.
Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/​.

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.
Appendix

Appendix A

Proof of Proposition 1
Based on (13), the first order condition for the optimal choice of \(\beta \) is given by:
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \Theta _{t}^{I}\left( \beta _{t}\right) }{\partial \beta _{t}}=0\nonumber \\&\Leftrightarrow \beta _{t}=\frac{mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +2\delta \left( f+v\right) \left( 1-m\right) Z-\delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( \frac{1}{2}-3f-3v\right) }{4\delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( f+v\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(A1)
Therefore, we have \(\beta _{t}=0\) if \(\delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( \frac{1}{2}-3\left( f+v\right) \right) \ge mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +2\delta \left( 1-m\right) Z\left( f+v\right) \) and \(\beta =1\) if \( \delta mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( \frac{1}{2}+f+v\right) \le mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +2\delta \left( 1-m\right) Z\left( f+v\right) \). Using the definitions for the probabilities, we reach proposition 1. \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 2
Using (15), we get:
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial \rho ^{Inc}}=-\frac{1}{4\left( f+v\right) }<0 \end{aligned}$$
(A2)
\(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 3
Given the definitions of \(Q'_{\beta l}\) and \(Q^{min}_{l}\) and using (17), we get:
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial E\left( \beta _{t}^{ex}\right) }=-\frac{\left( 1-k\right) }{2k}-\frac{2\left( 1-k\right) v}{2Q'_{\beta l}}<0, \, \text {for} \, \text {all} \, k \, \text {with} \, 0<k<1 \end{aligned}$$
(A3)
We can also deduce from (17):
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial k}&=-\frac{vW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) }{\delta Q^{'2}_{\beta l}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }-\frac{\left( 1-m\right) Z}{2mk^{2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }-\frac{1}{2k^{2}}\nonumber \\ {}&\quad +v\frac{Q^{min}_{l}}{Q^{'2}_{\beta l}}+E\left( \beta ^{ex}_t\right) \frac{Q'_{\beta l}+2k^2v}{2k^2Q'_{\beta l}} \end{aligned}$$
(A4)
Then, we have \(\frac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial k}<\left( >\right) \left( =\right) 0\) if \(\frac{vW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) }{\delta Q^{'2}_{\beta l}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\frac{\left( 1-m\right) Z}{2mk^{2}W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) }+\frac{1}{2k^{2}}>\left( <\right) \left( =\right) v\frac{Q^{min}_{l}}{Q^{'2}_{\beta l}}+E\left( \beta ^{ex}_t\right) \frac{Q'_{\beta l}+2k^2v}{2k^2Q'_{\beta l}}\). \(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 4
Using (18), we get:
$$\begin{aligned}&\frac{\partial \beta _{t}}{\partial \sigma }={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} -\dfrac{W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) }{4 \delta W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( f+v\right) \left( 1+\sigma \right) ^2}-\dfrac{\left( 1-m\right) Z}{2mW^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( 1+\sigma \right) ^2}<0 \, \text {if} \, 0<m\le 1 \\ \\ 0 \, \text {if} \, m=0 \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
(A5)
\(\square \)
Proof of Proposition 5
Based on (13), absent a threshold contract, the first order condition for the optimal choice of \(\beta \) is given by (A1): this is defined as \(\beta ^*\).
Assume a threshold contract according to which the incumbent must select a fraction of the bad policy, \(\beta _{t}\), below a prespecified value, that is \(\beta _{t}\le \overline{\beta }\), to be able to stand for reelection. Assuming that \(\beta ^*\) is lower or equal to \(\overline{\beta }\), we reach case (a) of the proposition by reasoning as in the proof of Proposition 1. If \(\beta ^*\) is higher than \(\overline{\beta }\), the incumbent is barred from reelection. The incumbent must then compare the payoff from choosing a purely bad policy (maximizing the payoff in the first period and not running for reelection) and given by \(mW^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\left( 1-m\right) Z\), with the payoff from choosing \(\overline{\beta }\) (offering a chance for reelection), given by \(m\overline{\beta }W^I_{t}\left( \eta _{bt}\right) +\left( 1-m\right) Z+\delta \left[ \frac{1}{2}+\left( f+v\right) \left( 2\overline{\beta }-1\right) \right] \left[ \left( 1-m\right) Z+m\left( 1-\overline{\beta }\right) W^I_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right] \). Given the definitions of \(Q'_{\beta }\) and \(Q^{min}\), we deduce cases (b) of the proposition. \(\square \)

Appendix B

Suppose that, instead of an incumbent and an opposition, there are two equal, competing parties (\(j=A;B\)), as in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), which offer policy platform \(\eta _{t}^A\), \(\eta _{t}^B\) respectively. In the election for term t, voters choose between these two platforms. Again, the parties consider two terms. Similarly to Bischoff and Siemers (2013), both parties’ payoff functions include the party’s probability of being elected for term t as well as the expected valence effect for the next election. Moreover, we add to the parties’ payoff the policy benefit accrued in the next term,13
The resulting payoff function for party j reads:
$$\begin{aligned} \Theta ^j_t\left( \beta _{t}^j, \beta _{t}^{-j}\right)&=\frac{1}{2}+v_0^j+\left( \beta _t^{j}-\beta _t^{-j}\right) f+\delta \left[ \right. \nonumber \\&\quad \left( \frac{1}{2}+v_0^j+\left( \beta _t^{j}-\beta _t^{-j}\right) f\right) \nonumber \\&\quad \times \left( \left( 1-m\right) \left( 2\beta _{t}^j-1\right) v+m\left( 1-\beta _{t}^j\right) W_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right) \nonumber \\&\quad +\left( \frac{1}{2}-v_0^j-\left( \beta _t^{j}-\beta _t^{-j}\right) f\right) \nonumber \\&\quad \times \left. \left( \left( 1-m\right) \left( 2\beta _{t}^{-j}-1\right) v+m\left( 1-\beta _{t}^{-j}\right) W_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
(B6)
The \(\beta _{t}^j\) that maximizes the payoff is:
$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{t}^j=\frac{-f-2\delta \left( 1-m\right) v\left( \dfrac{1}{2}-f+v_0^j\right) +\delta mW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( \dfrac{1}{2}+v_0^j\right) -2\delta fmW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \beta _{t}^{-j}}{2\delta f\left( 2v\left( 1-m\right) \right) -mW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) } \end{aligned}$$
(B7)
\(\beta _{t}^{-j}\) is similar, but with \(-v_0^j\) instead of \(v_0^j\). Solving the system, we get:
$$\begin{aligned} \beta _{t}^{j}&=\frac{4\delta f\left[ mfW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) +\left( 1-m\right) v\right] }{1-\left( 4\delta mfW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right) ^2}-\nonumber \\ {}&\quad -\frac{2\delta ^2\left[ m^2 fW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) ^2 +4\left( 1-m\right) ^2 v^2\left( \dfrac{1}{2}-f+v_0^j\right) -4m\left( 1-m\right) vfW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \left( \frac{3}{2}-2f+v_0^j\right) \right] }{1-\left( 4\delta mfW_{t+1}\left( \eta _{gt}\right) \right) ^2} \end{aligned}$$
(B8)
\(\beta _{t}^{-j}\) is similar, but with \(-v_0^j\) instead of \(v_0^j\).
Despite the unilluminating complexity of this version of the model, the political agents still weigh the benefits of the good policy payoff in the next period against the benefits of holding office and winning elections. The former will contribute to better policies and the latter to worse ones. As a result, when down-up issues are considered and in the presence of biased beliefs and retrospective voting, good policies are only implemented if the political agents are motivated beyond mere office-seeking.

Appendix C

List of Symbols
\(\eta _t\)
Policy platform chosen in period t
\(\eta _g\)
Good policy platform
\(\eta _b\)
Bad policy platform
\(\beta _{t}\)
Fraction of bad policy chosen in period t
\(a_t\)
Macroeconomic performance in period t
\(\bar{a}_i\)
Voter i’s subjective benchmark of the macroeconomic performance
\(y_{it}\)
Voter i’s income in period t
\(U_{it}\)
Voter i’s utility in period t
\({\hat{U}}_{it}\)
Voter i’s estimated utility in period t
\(\gamma _{it}^I\)
Voter i’s perception of incumbent’ competence in period t
\(\gamma _{it}^O\)
Voter i’s perception of opposition’ competence in period t
\(\pi _{it}^j\)
Probability of voters i voting for party j in period t
\(\Pi _{t}^{j}\)
Expected vote share for party j in period t
\(\Lambda _{t}^{j}\)
Policy-related vote shares of party j in period t
\(V_{t}^{j}\)
Valence-related vote shares of party j in period t
f
Biased beliefs effect on the election probability
v
Valence effect on the election probability
\(\Theta _{t}^{j}\)
Politician j’s payoff in period t
Z
Lump-sum value that the politician gets from being in office
\(W_{t}^{j}\)
Benefit the politician gets in period t from the policy she implements
\(\delta \)
Discount factor
Q
Probability of incumbent’s reelection
\(Q^{max}\)
The incumbent’s maximum reelection probability
\(Q^{min}\)
The incumbent’s minimum reelection probability
\(Q'_{\beta }\)
The incumbent’s marginal impact on the reelection probability of worsening the policy platform
\(\rho ^{Inc}\)
Incumbent bias
\(\beta _{t}^{ex}\)
Strategy of other, exogenous actors in period t
\(\epsilon \)
Exogenous stochastic shocks
k
Fraction of the outcome the incumbent knows to control
\(Q_l\)
Probability of incumbent’s reelection with limited accountability
\(Q^{min}_{l}\)
The incumbent’s minimum reelection probability with limited accountability
\(Q'_{\beta l}\)
The incumbent’s marginal impact on the reelection probability of worsening the policy platform with limited accountability
\(\sigma \)
The proportion of the policy payoff in the second term that is given as a reward to the incumbent
\(\bar{\beta }\)
The minimum quality of the policy the incumbent must ensure under a threshold contract
\(\beta ^*\)
The optimal choice \(\beta _t\) if the threshold contract were not in force
Footnotes
1
On retrospective voting, see Fair (1996); Lewis-Beck (1986); Duch and Stevenson (2006); Manacorda et al. (2011); Bechtel and Hainmueller (2011)
 
2
A list of all notation is presented in Appendix C.
 
3
To ensure that the probabilities remain between 0 and 1, Bischoff and Siemers (2013) assumed that \(\frac{1}{2}+f+v\le 1\). We adopt the same condition throughout.
 
4
Ever more studies examine alternative political and institutional frameworks that facilitate or hinder governance and policy with a long-term perspective (Jacobs 2016; Boston 2017; Bernauer 2013; González-Ricoy and Gosseries 2016; Jacobs 2011; Jacques 2021; Lindvall 2017; Morel et al. 2011)
 
5
As we show in appendix B, the mechanisms guiding policy choices would be similar if we explicitly modeled the election leading to term t. This suggests that our results are robust. The argument becomes, however, involved, sacrificing ease of exposition for little insight. We also assume that voters do not punish the incumbent for violations of electoral promises. In an extension of the baseline model, available upon request, we show that accounting for such penalizations would incentivize the choice of policies better aligned with promises, but the mechanisms guiding such choices would remain the same, suggesting, again, that our results are robust. Evidence also indicates that trustworthiness is less relevant to voters than attention to public opinion or the pursuit of common interests (Werner 2019) and that not all promises are perceived as election pledges (Dupont et al. 2019).
 
6
As in Bischoff and Siemers (2013), biased beliefs make it so that the implementation of the bad policy marginally increases election probability, as measured by f.
 
7
We assume that valence only depends on the policy implemented in the period and that previous policies are disregarded. This dovetails the evidence of voters’ short-sightedness (Urminsky and Zauberman (2015); Weaver (1986); Jacobs and Matthews (2012, 2017); MacKenzie (2016).
 
8
Baudewyns and Camatarri (2020)’s empirical findings suggest that candidates’ decision to run is not solely linked to either policy or office-seeking motives. On the compatibility of the two, see Warwick (2005); Linhart (2013); Wagner and Meyer (2014). The two motives could be further subdivided (Fox and Lawless 2005; Rohde 1979; Fowler and McClure 1989; Maestas et al. 2006).
 
9
Recall that \(1/2+f+v\le 1\), ensuring \(0\le Q_{l} \le 1\).
 
10
These contracts are surveyed in Gersbach (2012) and further discussed in Gersbach (2017) and Britz et al. (2022).
 
11
The policy payoff depends on \(\eta _t\), hence on the quality of the chosen platform. Instead of the policy payoff, which is a directly unobservable magnitude, the target could be a level of macroeconomic performance (\(a_t\)), which would also depend on \(\eta _t\) and, consequently, on \(\beta _t\).
 
12
The definition of \(\overline{\beta }\) would require common knowledge of \(\eta _g\). We could instead define the threshold as corresponding to observable macro variables. Still, as the macroeconomic performance \(a_t\) depends on \(\eta _t\), it will also be contingent on \(\beta _t\).
 
13
In relation to the model of Sect. 2.2 for simplicity, we do not consider the benefit from holding office Z and the policy payoff of the bad policy in the first term, \(W_t\left( \eta _{bt}\right) \).
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu A, Egorov G, Sonin K (2013) A political theory of populism. Q J Econ 128(2):771–805CrossRef Acemoglu A, Egorov G, Sonin K (2013) A political theory of populism. Q J Econ 128(2):771–805CrossRef
go back to reference Adams J, Merrill S III, Grofman B (2005) A unified theory of party competition: a crossnational analysis integrating spatial and behavioral factors. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Adams J, Merrill S III, Grofman B (2005) A unified theory of party competition: a crossnational analysis integrating spatial and behavioral factors. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Alesina A, Rosenthal H (1995) Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Alesina A, Rosenthal H (1995) Partisan politics, divided government, and the economy. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Althaus S (1998) Information effects in collective preferences. Am Polit Sci Rev 92(3):545–558CrossRef Althaus S (1998) Information effects in collective preferences. Am Polit Sci Rev 92(3):545–558CrossRef
go back to reference Apolte T, Müller J (2022) The persistence of political myths and ideologies. Eur J Polit Econ 71:102076CrossRef Apolte T, Müller J (2022) The persistence of political myths and ideologies. Eur J Polit Econ 71:102076CrossRef
go back to reference Balaguer-Coll MT, Prior D, Tortosa-Ausina E (2010) Decentralization and efficiency of local government. Ann Reg Sci 45(3):571–601CrossRef Balaguer-Coll MT, Prior D, Tortosa-Ausina E (2010) Decentralization and efficiency of local government. Ann Reg Sci 45(3):571–601CrossRef
go back to reference Baudewyns P, Camatarri S (2020) Office or policies? exploring candidates’ motivations to run for a party and the triggering role of political contexts. In: Baudewyns P, Camatarri S (ed) Parliamentary candidates between voters and parties. Routledge, London, pp 31–53 Baudewyns P, Camatarri S (2020) Office or policies? exploring candidates’ motivations to run for a party and the triggering role of political contexts. In: Baudewyns P, Camatarri S (ed) Parliamentary candidates between voters and parties. Routledge, London, pp 31–53
go back to reference Bechtel MM, Hainmueller J (2011) How lasting is voter gratitude? An analysis of the short- and long-term electoral returns to beneficial policy. Am J Polit Sci 55(4):852–868CrossRef Bechtel MM, Hainmueller J (2011) How lasting is voter gratitude? An analysis of the short- and long-term electoral returns to beneficial policy. Am J Polit Sci 55(4):852–868CrossRef
go back to reference Benczes I, Szabó K (2022) An economic understanding of populism: a conceptual framework of the demand and the supply side of populism. Polit Stud Rev 21(4):1–17 Benczes I, Szabó K (2022) An economic understanding of populism: a conceptual framework of the demand and the supply side of populism. Polit Stud Rev 21(4):1–17
go back to reference Bergmann E (2018) Conspiracy & populism: the politics of misinformation. Springer, GermanyCrossRef Bergmann E (2018) Conspiracy & populism: the politics of misinformation. Springer, GermanyCrossRef
go back to reference Besley T (2004) Incentive pay for policy-makers? J Eur Econ Assoc 2(2–3):193–215CrossRef Besley T (2004) Incentive pay for policy-makers? J Eur Econ Assoc 2(2–3):193–215CrossRef
go back to reference Besley T, Persson T, Reynal-Querol M (2016) Resilient leaders and institutional reform: theory and evidence. Economica 83(332):584–623CrossRef Besley T, Persson T, Reynal-Querol M (2016) Resilient leaders and institutional reform: theory and evidence. Economica 83(332):584–623CrossRef
go back to reference Bischoff I, Siemers L (2013) Biased beliefs and retrospective voting: why democracies choose mediocre policies. Public Choice 156(1/2):163–80CrossRef Bischoff I, Siemers L (2013) Biased beliefs and retrospective voting: why democracies choose mediocre policies. Public Choice 156(1/2):163–80CrossRef
go back to reference Borchert J, Stolz K (2011) Introduction: political careers in multi-level systems. Region Feder Stud 21(2):205–222CrossRef Borchert J, Stolz K (2011) Introduction: political careers in multi-level systems. Region Feder Stud 21(2):205–222CrossRef
go back to reference Boston J (2017) Governing for the future: designing democratic institutions for a better tomorrow. Emerald Publishing Limited, Bingley Boston J (2017) Governing for the future: designing democratic institutions for a better tomorrow. Emerald Publishing Limited, Bingley
go back to reference Bowler S, Donovan T (2002) Democracy, institutions and attitudes about citizen influence on government. Br J Polit Sci 32(2):371–390CrossRef Bowler S, Donovan T (2002) Democracy, institutions and attitudes about citizen influence on government. Br J Polit Sci 32(2):371–390CrossRef
go back to reference Breton A (1998) Competitive governments: an economic theory of politics and public finance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Breton A (1998) Competitive governments: an economic theory of politics and public finance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Britz V, Ebrahimi A, Gersbach H (2022) Incentive pay for policy-makers? J Public Econ Theory 24(2):259–275CrossRef Britz V, Ebrahimi A, Gersbach H (2022) Incentive pay for policy-makers? J Public Econ Theory 24(2):259–275CrossRef
go back to reference Buchanan J (1989) The public-choice perspective. In: Bastiat F (ed) Essays on the political economy. University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, pp 13–24 Buchanan J (1989) The public-choice perspective. In: Bastiat F (ed) Essays on the political economy. University of Hawaii Press, Honolulu, pp 13–24
go back to reference Caplan B (2002) Systematically biased beliefs about economics: Robust evidence of judgemental anomalies from the survey of americans and economists on the economy. Econ J 112(479):433–458CrossRef Caplan B (2002) Systematically biased beliefs about economics: Robust evidence of judgemental anomalies from the survey of americans and economists on the economy. Econ J 112(479):433–458CrossRef
go back to reference Caplan B (2007) The myth of the rational voter. why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton University Press, Princeton Caplan B (2007) The myth of the rational voter. why democracies choose bad policies. Princeton University Press, Princeton
go back to reference Carson J, Engstrom E, Roberts J (2007) Candidate quality, the personal vote, and the incumbency advantage in congress. Am Polit Sci Rev 101(2):289–301CrossRef Carson J, Engstrom E, Roberts J (2007) Candidate quality, the personal vote, and the incumbency advantage in congress. Am Polit Sci Rev 101(2):289–301CrossRef
go back to reference Caselli F, Morelli M (2004) Bad politicians. J Public Econ 88(3–4):759–782CrossRef Caselli F, Morelli M (2004) Bad politicians. J Public Econ 88(3–4):759–782CrossRef
go back to reference Crowley GR, Sobel RS (2011) Does fiscal decentralization constrain leviathan? new evidence from local property tax competition. Public Choice 149(1–2):5–30CrossRef Crowley GR, Sobel RS (2011) Does fiscal decentralization constrain leviathan? new evidence from local property tax competition. Public Choice 149(1–2):5–30CrossRef
go back to reference Diermeier D, Li C (2017) Electoral control with behavioral voters. J Polit 79(3):890–902CrossRef Diermeier D, Li C (2017) Electoral control with behavioral voters. J Polit 79(3):890–902CrossRef
go back to reference Dornbusch R, Edwards S (1990) Macroeconomic populism. J Dev Econ 32(2):247–277CrossRef Dornbusch R, Edwards S (1990) Macroeconomic populism. J Dev Econ 32(2):247–277CrossRef
go back to reference Duch RM, Stevenson R (2006) Assessing the magnitude of the economic vote over time and across nations. Elect Stud 25(3):528–547CrossRef Duch RM, Stevenson R (2006) Assessing the magnitude of the economic vote over time and across nations. Elect Stud 25(3):528–547CrossRef
go back to reference Duch RM, Stevenson R (2010) The global economy, competency, and the economic vote. J Polit 72(1):105–123CrossRef Duch RM, Stevenson R (2010) The global economy, competency, and the economic vote. J Polit 72(1):105–123CrossRef
go back to reference Edinger M, Jahr S (2015) Political careers in Europe: career patterns in multi-level systems. Bloomsbury Publishing, Baden-BadenCrossRef Edinger M, Jahr S (2015) Political careers in Europe: career patterns in multi-level systems. Bloomsbury Publishing, Baden-BadenCrossRef
go back to reference Evans M (2018) Policy-seeking and office-seeking: categorizing parties based on coalition payoff allocation. Polit Policy 46(1):4–31CrossRef Evans M (2018) Policy-seeking and office-seeking: categorizing parties based on coalition payoff allocation. Polit Policy 46(1):4–31CrossRef
go back to reference Fair RC (1996) Econometrics and presidential elections. J Econ Perspect 10(3):89–102CrossRef Fair RC (1996) Econometrics and presidential elections. J Econ Perspect 10(3):89–102CrossRef
go back to reference Fedele A, Naticchioni P (2016) Moonlighting politicians: motivation matters! German Econ Rev 17(2):127–156CrossRef Fedele A, Naticchioni P (2016) Moonlighting politicians: motivation matters! German Econ Rev 17(2):127–156CrossRef
go back to reference Fouirnaies A, Hall AB (2014) The financial incumbency advantage: causes and consequences. J Polit 76(3):711–724CrossRef Fouirnaies A, Hall AB (2014) The financial incumbency advantage: causes and consequences. J Polit 76(3):711–724CrossRef
go back to reference Fowler LL, McClure RD (1989) Political ambition: who decides to run for congress. Yale University Press, New Haven Fowler LL, McClure RD (1989) Political ambition: who decides to run for congress. Yale University Press, New Haven
go back to reference Fox RL, Lawless JL (2005) To run or not to run for office: explaining nascent political ambition. Am J Polit Sci 49(3):642–659CrossRef Fox RL, Lawless JL (2005) To run or not to run for office: explaining nascent political ambition. Am J Polit Sci 49(3):642–659CrossRef
go back to reference Francis WL, Kenny L (2000) Up the political ladder: career paths in us politics. SAGE, Thousand Oaks Francis WL, Kenny L (2000) Up the political ladder: career paths in us politics. SAGE, Thousand Oaks
go back to reference Gersbach H (2003) Incentive contracts and elections for politicians and the down-up problem. In: Sertel M, Koray S (eds) Advances in economic design. Springer, Berlin, pp 65–76CrossRef Gersbach H (2003) Incentive contracts and elections for politicians and the down-up problem. In: Sertel M, Koray S (eds) Advances in economic design. Springer, Berlin, pp 65–76CrossRef
go back to reference Gersbach H (2004) Competition of politicians for incentive contracts and elections. Public Choice 121(1/2):157–177CrossRef Gersbach H (2004) Competition of politicians for incentive contracts and elections. Public Choice 121(1/2):157–177CrossRef
go back to reference Gersbach H (2017) Redesigning democracy: more ideas for better rules. Springer, BerlinCrossRef Gersbach H (2017) Redesigning democracy: more ideas for better rules. Springer, BerlinCrossRef
go back to reference Gersbach H, Liessem V (2008) Incentive contracts and elections for politicians with multi-task problems. J Econ Behav Organ 68(2):401–411CrossRef Gersbach H, Liessem V (2008) Incentive contracts and elections for politicians with multi-task problems. J Econ Behav Organ 68(2):401–411CrossRef
go back to reference Gersbach H, Ponta O (2017) Unraveling short- and farsightedness in politics. Public Choice 170(3–4):289–321CrossRef Gersbach H, Ponta O (2017) Unraveling short- and farsightedness in politics. Public Choice 170(3–4):289–321CrossRef
go back to reference González-Ricoy I, Gosseries A (2016) Institutions for future generations. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef González-Ricoy I, Gosseries A (2016) Institutions for future generations. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
go back to reference Gordon SC, D., L. (2009) Do the advantages of incumbency advantage incumbents? J Polit 71(4):1481–1498 Gordon SC, D., L. (2009) Do the advantages of incumbency advantage incumbents? J Polit 71(4):1481–1498
go back to reference Grembi V, Nannicini T, Troiano U (2016) Do fiscal rules matter? Am Econ J Appl Econ 8(3):1–30CrossRef Grembi V, Nannicini T, Troiano U (2016) Do fiscal rules matter? Am Econ J Appl Econ 8(3):1–30CrossRef
go back to reference Hall A, Snyder J (2015) How much of the incumbency advantage is due to scare-off? Polit Sci Res Methods 3(3):493–514CrossRef Hall A, Snyder J (2015) How much of the incumbency advantage is due to scare-off? Polit Sci Res Methods 3(3):493–514CrossRef
go back to reference Hirano S, Snyder J (2009) Using multimember district elections to estimate the sources of the incumbency advantage. Am J Polit Sci 53(2):292–306CrossRef Hirano S, Snyder J (2009) Using multimember district elections to estimate the sources of the incumbency advantage. Am J Polit Sci 53(2):292–306CrossRef
go back to reference Inman R, Rubinfeld D (2020) Democratic federalism: the economics, politics, and law of federal governance. Princeton University Press, PrincetonCrossRef Inman R, Rubinfeld D (2020) Democratic federalism: the economics, politics, and law of federal governance. Princeton University Press, PrincetonCrossRef
go back to reference Jacobs A (2011) Governing for the long term: democracy and the politics of investment. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Jacobs A (2011) Governing for the long term: democracy and the politics of investment. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
go back to reference Jacobs A (2016) Policymaking for the long term in advanced democracies. Annu Rev Polit Sci 19:433–454CrossRef Jacobs A (2016) Policymaking for the long term in advanced democracies. Annu Rev Polit Sci 19:433–454CrossRef
go back to reference Jacobs A, Matthews JS (2012) Why do citizens discount the future? Public opinion and the timing of policy consequences. Br J Polit Sci 42(4):903–935CrossRef Jacobs A, Matthews JS (2012) Why do citizens discount the future? Public opinion and the timing of policy consequences. Br J Polit Sci 42(4):903–935CrossRef
go back to reference Jacobs A, Matthews JS (2017) Policy attitudes in institutional context: rules, uncertainty, and the mass politics of public investment. Am J Polit Sci 61(1):194–207CrossRef Jacobs A, Matthews JS (2017) Policy attitudes in institutional context: rules, uncertainty, and the mass politics of public investment. Am J Polit Sci 61(1):194–207CrossRef
go back to reference Jacques O (2021) Austerity and the path of least resistance: how fiscal consolidations crowd out long-term investments. J Eur Publ Policy 28(4):551–570CrossRef Jacques O (2021) Austerity and the path of least resistance: how fiscal consolidations crowd out long-term investments. J Eur Publ Policy 28(4):551–570CrossRef
go back to reference Kiewiet DR (2000) Economic retrospective voting and incentives for policymaking. Elect Stud 19(2–3):427–444CrossRef Kiewiet DR (2000) Economic retrospective voting and incentives for policymaking. Elect Stud 19(2–3):427–444CrossRef
go back to reference Kincaid J (2010) Federalism and democracy: comparative empirical and theoretical perspectives. In: Burgess M, Gagnon A-G (eds) Federal democracies. Routledge, London, pp 299–324 Kincaid J (2010) Federalism and democracy: comparative empirical and theoretical perspectives. In: Burgess M, Gagnon A-G (eds) Federal democracies. Routledge, London, pp 299–324
go back to reference Koethenbuerger M (2011) How do local governments decide on public policy in fiscal federalism? tax vs expenditure optimization. J Public Econ 95(11–12):1516–1522CrossRef Koethenbuerger M (2011) How do local governments decide on public policy in fiscal federalism? tax vs expenditure optimization. J Public Econ 95(11–12):1516–1522CrossRef
go back to reference Lane J, Ersson S (2005) The riddle of federalism: does federalism impact on democracy? Democratization 12(2):163–182CrossRef Lane J, Ersson S (2005) The riddle of federalism: does federalism impact on democracy? Democratization 12(2):163–182CrossRef
go back to reference Lee N, Nyhan B, Reifler J, Flynn DJ (2021) More accurate, but no less polarized: comparing the factual beliefs of government officials and the public. Br J Polit Sci 51(3):1323–1323CrossRef Lee N, Nyhan B, Reifler J, Flynn DJ (2021) More accurate, but no less polarized: comparing the factual beliefs of government officials and the public. Br J Polit Sci 51(3):1323–1323CrossRef
go back to reference Leigh A (2009) Does the world economy swing national elections? Oxford Bull Econ Stat 71(2):163–181CrossRef Leigh A (2009) Does the world economy swing national elections? Oxford Bull Econ Stat 71(2):163–181CrossRef
go back to reference Lewis-Beck MS (1986) Comparative economic voting: Britain, France, Germany, Italy. Am J Polit Sci 30(2):315–346CrossRef Lewis-Beck MS (1986) Comparative economic voting: Britain, France, Germany, Italy. Am J Polit Sci 30(2):315–346CrossRef
go back to reference Liessem V (2008) Electoral competition, incentive contracts for politicians and unknown preferences. Soc Choice Welf 30(1):13–41CrossRef Liessem V (2008) Electoral competition, incentive contracts for politicians and unknown preferences. Soc Choice Welf 30(1):13–41CrossRef
go back to reference Linhart E (2013) Does an appropriate coalition theory exist for Germany? An overview of recent office- and policy-oriented coalition theories. German Polit 22(3):288–313CrossRef Linhart E (2013) Does an appropriate coalition theory exist for Germany? An overview of recent office- and policy-oriented coalition theories. German Polit 22(3):288–313CrossRef
go back to reference MacKenzie MK (2016) Institutional design and sources of short-termism. In: González-Ricoy I, Gosseries A (eds) Institutions for future generations. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 24–45CrossRef MacKenzie MK (2016) Institutional design and sources of short-termism. In: González-Ricoy I, Gosseries A (eds) Institutions for future generations. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 24–45CrossRef
go back to reference Maestas CD, Fulton S, Maisel LS, Stone WJ (2006) When to risk it? institutions, ambitions and the decision to run for the us house. Am Polit Sci Rev 100(2):195–208CrossRef Maestas CD, Fulton S, Maisel LS, Stone WJ (2006) When to risk it? institutions, ambitions and the decision to run for the us house. Am Polit Sci Rev 100(2):195–208CrossRef
go back to reference Manacorda M, Miguel E, Vigorito A (2011) Government transfers and political support. Am Econ J Appl Econ 3(3):1–28CrossRef Manacorda M, Miguel E, Vigorito A (2011) Government transfers and political support. Am Econ J Appl Econ 3(3):1–28CrossRef
go back to reference Mattozzi A, Merlo A (2008) Political careers or career politicians? J Public Econ 92(3):597–608CrossRef Mattozzi A, Merlo A (2008) Political careers or career politicians? J Public Econ 92(3):597–608CrossRef
go back to reference McPike JD (2011) Merit pay and pain: linking congressional pay to performance. Indiana Law J 86(1):7 McPike JD (2011) Merit pay and pain: linking congressional pay to performance. Indiana Law J 86(1):7
go back to reference Meirowitz A (2008) Electoral contests, incumbency advantages, and campaign finance. J Polit 70(3):681–699CrossRef Meirowitz A (2008) Electoral contests, incumbency advantages, and campaign finance. J Polit 70(3):681–699CrossRef
go back to reference Morel N, Palier B, Palme J (2011) Towards a social investment welfare state? ideas, policies and challenges. Bristol University Press, BristolCrossRef Morel N, Palier B, Palme J (2011) Towards a social investment welfare state? ideas, policies and challenges. Bristol University Press, BristolCrossRef
go back to reference Mudde C, Rovira Kaltwasser C (2017) Populism: a very short introduction. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef Mudde C, Rovira Kaltwasser C (2017) Populism: a very short introduction. Oxford University Press, OxfordCrossRef
go back to reference Mudde C, Rovira Kaltwasser C (2018) Studying populism in comparative perspective: reflections on the contemporary and future research agenda. Comp Pol Stud 51(3):1667–1693CrossRef Mudde C, Rovira Kaltwasser C (2018) Studying populism in comparative perspective: reflections on the contemporary and future research agenda. Comp Pol Stud 51(3):1667–1693CrossRef
go back to reference Müller M (2007) Motivation of politicians and long-term policies. Public Choice 132(3–4):273–289CrossRef Müller M (2007) Motivation of politicians and long-term policies. Public Choice 132(3–4):273–289CrossRef
go back to reference Naff KC, Crum J (1999) Working for America: does public service motivation make a difference? Rev Public Personn Admin 19(3):5–16CrossRef Naff KC, Crum J (1999) Working for America: does public service motivation make a difference? Rev Public Personn Admin 19(3):5–16CrossRef
go back to reference Oates WE (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York Oates WE (1972) Fiscal federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New York
go back to reference Oates WE (1999) An essay on fiscal federalism. J Econ Liter 37(3):1120–1149CrossRef Oates WE (1999) An essay on fiscal federalism. J Econ Liter 37(3):1120–1149CrossRef
go back to reference Perry JL, Wise LR (1990) The motivational bases of public service. Public Adm Rev 50(3):367–73CrossRef Perry JL, Wise LR (1990) The motivational bases of public service. Public Adm Rev 50(3):367–73CrossRef
go back to reference Pierson P (1995) Fragmented welfare states: federal institutions and the development of social policy. Governance 8(4):449–478CrossRef Pierson P (1995) Fragmented welfare states: federal institutions and the development of social policy. Governance 8(4):449–478CrossRef
go back to reference Qian Y, Roland G (1998) Federalism and the soft budget constraint. Am Econ Rev 88(5):1143–1162 Qian Y, Roland G (1998) Federalism and the soft budget constraint. Am Econ Rev 88(5):1143–1162
go back to reference Redlawsk D (2006) Motivated reasoning, affect, and the role of memory in voter decision making. In: Redlawsk DP (ed) Feeling politics. Palgrave, New York, pp 87–107CrossRef Redlawsk D (2006) Motivated reasoning, affect, and the role of memory in voter decision making. In: Redlawsk DP (ed) Feeling politics. Palgrave, New York, pp 87–107CrossRef
go back to reference Richard L, Redlawsk D (2006) How voters decide: information processing during elections campaigns. Cambridge University Press, New York Richard L, Redlawsk D (2006) How voters decide: information processing during elections campaigns. Cambridge University Press, New York
go back to reference Rogoff K (1990) Equilibrium political budget cycles. Am Econ Rev 80(1):21–36 Rogoff K (1990) Equilibrium political budget cycles. Am Econ Rev 80(1):21–36
go back to reference Rohde DW (1979) Risk-bearing and progressive ambition: the case of members of the united states house of representative. Am J Polit Sci 23(1):1–26CrossRef Rohde DW (1979) Risk-bearing and progressive ambition: the case of members of the united states house of representative. Am J Polit Sci 23(1):1–26CrossRef
go back to reference Ross D (2007) Economic theory and cognitive science. MIT Press, Cambridge Ross D (2007) Economic theory and cognitive science. MIT Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Rovira Kaltwasser C (2009) Populism and the economy: an ambivalent relationship. International Policy Analysis. Friedrich Ebert Stiftung, Bonn Rovira Kaltwasser C (2009) Populism and the economy: an ambivalent relationship. International Policy Analysis. Friedrich Ebert Stiftung, Bonn
go back to reference Shieh S, Pan WH (2010) Individual campaign contributions in a downsian model: expressive and instrumental motives. Public Choice 145(3/4):405–416CrossRef Shieh S, Pan WH (2010) Individual campaign contributions in a downsian model: expressive and instrumental motives. Public Choice 145(3/4):405–416CrossRef
go back to reference Shin G (2019) Welfare, innovation capacity, and economic performance: evidence from American federalism. Public Policy Adm 34(3):349–381 Shin G (2019) Welfare, innovation capacity, and economic performance: evidence from American federalism. Public Policy Adm 34(3):349–381
go back to reference Smart M, Strum D (2004) Paying politicians: is more always better? University of Munich, Mimeo Smart M, Strum D (2004) Paying politicians: is more always better? University of Munich, Mimeo
go back to reference Stansel D (2005) Local decentralization and local economic growth: a cross-sectional examination of U.S. metropolitan areas. J Urban Econ 57(1):55–72CrossRef Stansel D (2005) Local decentralization and local economic growth: a cross-sectional examination of U.S. metropolitan areas. J Urban Econ 57(1):55–72CrossRef
go back to reference Tiebout CM (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. J Polit Econ 64(5):416–424CrossRef Tiebout CM (1956) A pure theory of local expenditures. J Polit Econ 64(5):416–424CrossRef
go back to reference Urminsky O, Zauberman G (2015) The psychology of intertemporal preferences. In: Gideon K, George W (eds) The Wiley Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making, ii. Wiley, Chichester, pp 141–181CrossRef Urminsky O, Zauberman G (2015) The psychology of intertemporal preferences. In: Gideon K, George W (eds) The Wiley Blackwell handbook of judgment and decision making, ii. Wiley, Chichester, pp 141–181CrossRef
go back to reference Vandenabeele W (2009) The mediating effect of job satisfaction and organizational commitment on selfreported performance: more robust evidence of the psm-performance relationship. Rev Adm Sci 75(1):53–78 Vandenabeele W (2009) The mediating effect of job satisfaction and organizational commitment on selfreported performance: more robust evidence of the psm-performance relationship. Rev Adm Sci 75(1):53–78
go back to reference Wagner M, Meyer T (2014) Which issues do parties emphasise? salience strategies and party organisation in multiparty systems. West Eur Polit 37(5):1019–1045CrossRef Wagner M, Meyer T (2014) Which issues do parties emphasise? salience strategies and party organisation in multiparty systems. West Eur Polit 37(5):1019–1045CrossRef
go back to reference Warwick P (2005) Do policy horizons structure the formation of parliamentary governments?: the evidence from an expert survey. Am J Polit Sci 49(2):373–387CrossRef Warwick P (2005) Do policy horizons structure the formation of parliamentary governments?: the evidence from an expert survey. Am J Polit Sci 49(2):373–387CrossRef
go back to reference Weaver RK (1986) The politics of blame avoidance. J Publ Policy 6(4):371–398CrossRef Weaver RK (1986) The politics of blame avoidance. J Publ Policy 6(4):371–398CrossRef
go back to reference Weingast BR (1995) The economic role of political institutions: market preserving federalism and economic development. J Law Econ Organ 11(1):1–31 Weingast BR (1995) The economic role of political institutions: market preserving federalism and economic development. J Law Econ Organ 11(1):1–31
go back to reference Werner A (2019) What voters want from their parties: testing the promise keeping assumption. Elect Stud 57:186–195CrossRef Werner A (2019) What voters want from their parties: testing the promise keeping assumption. Elect Stud 57:186–195CrossRef
Metadata
Title
On the optimality of policy choices in the face of biased beliefs, retrospective voting and the down-up problem
Authors
Carlos Seixas
Diogo Lourenço
Publication date
24-06-2024
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Social Choice and Welfare / Issue 2/2024
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Electronic ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-024-01533-2

Premium Partner