Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 3-4/2015

01-06-2015

Primaries: the unifying force

Authors: Rafael Hortala-Vallve, Hannes Mueller

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 3-4/2015

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We present a formal model of intra-party politics to explain candidate selection within political parties. We think of parties as heterogeneous groups of individuals who aim to implement a set of policies but who differ in their priorities. When party heterogeneity is too great, parties are in danger of splitting into smaller yet more homogeneous political groups. In this context we argue that primaries can have a unifying role if the party elite cannot commit to policy concessions. Our model shows how three factors interact to create incentives for the adoption of primary elections, namely (1) the alignment in the preferred policies of various factions within a party, (2) the relative weight of each of these factions and (3) the electoral system. We discuss the existing empirical literature and demonstrate how existing studies can be improved in light of our theoretical predictions to provide a new, structured perspective on the adoption of primary elections.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See, for example, Aldrich (1995), Besley (2005), Levy (2004), Roemer (2001).
 
2
See Adams and Merrill (2008), Serra (2011, 2013) or Aragon (2009). Mierowitz (2005) sees primaries as a mechanism that allows screening voters’ preferences rather than candidates’ qualities.
 
3
For an early discussion see, for example, North and Weingast (1989).
 
4
Boix and Svolik (2013) argue that institutionalized power-sharing within dictatorships could follow a similar logic.
 
5
Our model remains silent on other non-policy consequences of primaries, such as the electoral bonus of calling a primary (Carey and Polga-Hecimovich 2006) or the greater factionalization when calling a primary (Key 1949).
 
6
Lee et al. (2004) argue that citizen candidate models account better for what actually happens in elections than Downsian models. Put differently, parties select candidates that implement their own preferred policy instead of selecting policies that are implemented by their candidates.
 
7
The rationale behind this simplifying assumption is that, relative to other selection methods, primaries have the tendency to take power away from the party elite.
 
8
In Sect. 5 we show the robustness of our results when considering a one-dimensional policy space.
 
9
The probabilities of winning the election capture a large set of models we might have in mind. For example, it could be the case that when the party splits, its voters perfectly coordinate by voting for one of the factions in order to avoid a large gain by the opposing party.
 
10
A possible example is the presence of a non-democratically elected elite that has been in power for many years while the policy preference of the party’s core supporters has shifted. The socialist party in Spain (PSOE) was, until the last leadership change in July 2014, an example of such a situation.
 
11
In order to illustrate the proposition’s result, it is best to write the two conditions in terms of y. They read as follows: \(y\; < \;\frac{1 - \alpha x}{1 - x}\;and\;y\; < \;\frac{(\alpha - 1)x}{1 - x}.\)
 
12
Their measure of this divergence is the difference between the Berry state citizen ideology score (a weighted average of the Democrat and Republican representatives’ scores) and the Berry-based Democratic elite ideology score.
 
13
In their cross-country section, Kemahlioglu et al. (2009) code the thresholds for preventing runoff elections as zero, one and two respectively. A higher likelihood of a runoff can be interpreted as a lower α and our theory suggests a non-monotonic effect on the aggregate use of primaries. However, their empirical design treats the effect of this variable as monotonic and finds no significant impact on the use of primaries. Instead, they find a negative relationship when bunching the values of zero and one and comparing them with two. Our theory suggests that this finding should become stronger when comparing the values of one and two, and weaker or even opposite between zero and one.
 
14
For instance, see Obler (2009) for a discussion of primary elections in Belgium.
 
15
Empirically this seems to be the case; see Lee et al. (2004).
 
16
A future avenue of research could analyze further the institutionalization of primaries as a more irreversible change than a policy concession. This establishes an interesting link to the work of Levy (2004), who models parties as commitment devices.
 
17
See Acemoglu and Robinson (2005) for an analogous discussion.
 
18
That this effect is not unrealistic is shown by Obler (2009) in his analysis of the introduction of primaries in Belgium. Obler argues that the Christian Social Party did not adopt primaries when the elite perceived the likely winner of the primaries to be more extreme.
 
19
The fact that primaries are more likely when the dissenting faction is centrist is related to results in Gerber and Morton (1998) and Jackson et al. (2007) where we observe that more open selection induces more centrist policies.
 
20
See Tufte (1973). For an excellent review of this literature, see Taagepera and Shugart (1989).
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. (2005). Economic origins of dictatorship and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2008). Candidate and party strategies in two-stage elections beginning with a primary. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 344–359.CrossRef Adams, J., & Merrill, S. (2008). Candidate and party strategies in two-stage elections beginning with a primary. American Journal of Political Science, 52(2), 344–359.CrossRef
go back to reference Aldrich, J. (1995). Why parties? the origin and transformation of political parties in America (p. 1995). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef Aldrich, J. (1995). Why parties? the origin and transformation of political parties in America (p. 1995). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Ansolabehere, S., Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. (2006). What did the direct primary do to party loyalty in Congress? In D. Brady & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Process, party and policy making: Further new perspectives on the history of Congress. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Ansolabehere, S., Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. (2006). What did the direct primary do to party loyalty in Congress? In D. Brady & M. D. McCubbins (Eds.), Process, party and policy making: Further new perspectives on the history of Congress. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
go back to reference Aragon, F. (2009). Candidate nomination procedures and political selection: Evidence from Latin American parties, LSE STICERD Research Paper No. EOPP003. Aragon, F. (2009). Candidate nomination procedures and political selection: Evidence from Latin American parties, LSE STICERD Research Paper No. EOPP003.
go back to reference Besley, T. (2005). Political selection. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 43–60.CrossRef Besley, T. (2005). Political selection. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 19(3), 43–60.CrossRef
go back to reference Boix, C., & Svolik, M. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. Journal of Politics, 75, 300–316.CrossRef Boix, C., & Svolik, M. (2013). The foundations of limited authoritarian government: Institutions, commitment, and power-sharing in dictatorships. Journal of Politics, 75, 300–316.CrossRef
go back to reference Caillaud, B., & Tirole, J. (2002). Parties as political intermediaries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1453–1489.CrossRef Caillaud, B., & Tirole, J. (2002). Parties as political intermediaries. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4), 1453–1489.CrossRef
go back to reference Carey, J. (2003). Presidentialism and representative institutions in Latin America at the turn of the century. Baltimore, MD: The John Hopkins University Press. Carey, J. (2003). Presidentialism and representative institutions in Latin America at the turn of the century. Baltimore, MD: The John Hopkins University Press.
go back to reference Carey, J., & Polga-Hecimovich, J. (2006). Primary elections and candidate strength in Latin America. The Journal of Politics, 68(3), 530–543.CrossRef Carey, J., & Polga-Hecimovich, J. (2006). Primary elections and candidate strength in Latin America. The Journal of Politics, 68(3), 530–543.CrossRef
go back to reference Cox, G. (1997). Making Votes Count. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Cox, G. (1997). Making Votes Count. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference Crutzen, B., Castanheira, M., & Sahuguet, N. (2009). Party organization and electoral competition. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 26(2), 212–242.CrossRef Crutzen, B., Castanheira, M., & Sahuguet, N. (2009). Party organization and electoral competition. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 26(2), 212–242.CrossRef
go back to reference De Luca, M., Jones, P., & Tula, M. (2002). Back rooms or ballot boxes?: candidate nomination in Argentina. Comparative Political Studies, 35(4), 413–436.CrossRef De Luca, M., Jones, P., & Tula, M. (2002). Back rooms or ballot boxes?: candidate nomination in Argentina. Comparative Political Studies, 35(4), 413–436.CrossRef
go back to reference Folke, O., Persson, T., & Rickne, J. (2014). Preferential voting, accountability and promotions into political power: Evidence from Sweden. Huntingdon: Mimeo. Folke, O., Persson, T., & Rickne, J. (2014). Preferential voting, accountability and promotions into political power: Evidence from Sweden. Huntingdon: Mimeo.
go back to reference Gerber, E., & Morton, R. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 14, 304–324.CrossRef Gerber, E., & Morton, R. (1998). Primary election systems and representation. Journal of Law Economics and Organization, 14, 304–324.CrossRef
go back to reference Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). The decline of third-party voting in the United States. The Journal of Politics, 69(01), 1–16. Hirano, S., & Snyder, J. M. (2008). The decline of third-party voting in the United States. The Journal of Politics, 69(01), 1–16.
go back to reference Jackson, M., Mathevet, L. & Mattes, K. (2007). Nomination processes and policy outcomes. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2, 67–94. Jackson, M., Mathevet, L. & Mattes, K. (2007). Nomination processes and policy outcomes. Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 2, 67–94.
go back to reference Kemahlioglu, O., Weitz-Shapiro, R., & Hirano, S. (2009). Why primaries in Latin American presidential elections? The Journal of Politics, 71(01), 339–352.CrossRef Kemahlioglu, O., Weitz-Shapiro, R., & Hirano, S. (2009). Why primaries in Latin American presidential elections? The Journal of Politics, 71(01), 339–352.CrossRef
go back to reference Key, V. O. (1949). Southern politics in state and nation. New York: Knopf. Key, V. O. (1949). Southern politics in state and nation. New York: Knopf.
go back to reference Laver, M., & Sergenti, E. (2010). Party competition: an agent-based model. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Laver, M., & Sergenti, E. (2010). Party competition: an agent-based model. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Lee, D., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? evidence from the U. S. House. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 807–859.CrossRef Lee, D., Moretti, E., & Butler, M. (2004). Do voters affect or elect policies? evidence from the U. S. House. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 807–859.CrossRef
go back to reference Levy, G. (2004). A model of political parties. Journal of Economic Theory, 115(2), 250–277.CrossRef Levy, G. (2004). A model of political parties. Journal of Economic Theory, 115(2), 250–277.CrossRef
go back to reference Meinke, S., Staton, J., & Wuhs, S. (2010). State delegate selection rules for presidential nominations, 1972–2000. The Journal of Politics, 68(1), 180–193. Meinke, S., Staton, J., & Wuhs, S. (2010). State delegate selection rules for presidential nominations, 1972–2000. The Journal of Politics, 68(1), 180–193.
go back to reference Mutlu-Eren, H. (2011). Keeping the party together. Mimeo. Mutlu-Eren, H. (2011). Keeping the party together. Mimeo.
go back to reference North, D., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.CrossRef North, D., & Weingast, B. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: the evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.CrossRef
go back to reference Obler, J. (2009). Intraparty democracy and the selection of parliamentary candidates: the Belgian case. British Journal of Political Science, 4(02), 163–185.CrossRef Obler, J. (2009). Intraparty democracy and the selection of parliamentary candidates: the Belgian case. British Journal of Political Science, 4(02), 163–185.CrossRef
go back to reference Roemer, J. (2001). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67(1), 1–19.CrossRef Roemer, J. (2001). The democratic political economy of progressive income taxation. Econometrica, 67(1), 1–19.CrossRef
go back to reference Serra, G. (2011). Why primaries ? The party’s tradeoff between policy and valence. The Journal of Theoretical Politics, 23, 21–51.CrossRef Serra, G. (2011). Why primaries ? The party’s tradeoff between policy and valence. The Journal of Theoretical Politics, 23, 21–51.CrossRef
go back to reference Serra, G. (2013). when will incumbents avoid a primary challenge? Aggregation of partial information about candidates’ valence. In N. Schofield, G. Caballero, & D. Kselman (Eds.), Advances in Political Economy: Institutions, Modeling and Empirical Analysis (pp. 217–248). Heidelberg: Springer.CrossRef Serra, G. (2013). when will incumbents avoid a primary challenge? Aggregation of partial information about candidates’ valence. In N. Schofield, G. Caballero, & D. Kselman (Eds.), Advances in Political Economy: Institutions, Modeling and Empirical Analysis (pp. 217–248). Heidelberg: Springer.CrossRef
go back to reference Snyder, J., & Ting, M. (2011). Electoral selection with parties and primaries. American Journal of Political Science, 55, 781–795.CrossRef Snyder, J., & Ting, M. (2011). Electoral selection with parties and primaries. American Journal of Political Science, 55, 781–795.CrossRef
go back to reference Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 22, 875–876.CrossRef Taagepera, R., & Shugart, M. (1989). Seats and votes: The effects and determinants of electoral systems. Canadian Journal of Political Science, 22, 875–876.CrossRef
go back to reference Tufte, E. (1973). The relationship between seats and votes in two-party systems. The American Political Science Review, 67(2), 540–544.CrossRef Tufte, E. (1973). The relationship between seats and votes in two-party systems. The American Political Science Review, 67(2), 540–544.CrossRef
go back to reference Ware, A. (2002). The American direct primary: Party institutionalization and transformation in the North. New York: Cambridge University Press. Ware, A. (2002). The American direct primary: Party institutionalization and transformation in the North. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Metadata
Title
Primaries: the unifying force
Authors
Rafael Hortala-Vallve
Hannes Mueller
Publication date
01-06-2015
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 3-4/2015
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-015-0249-8

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2015

Public Choice 3-4/2015 Go to the issue