Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 4/2021

02-01-2021

Profit-splitting rules and the taxation of multinational digital platforms

Authors: Francis Bloch, Gabrielle Demange

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 4/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper analyzes the strategy of a monopolistic digital platform serving users from two jurisdictions with different corporate tax rates. We consider two profit-splitting rules, Separate Accounting and Formula Apportionment based on the number of users in the two jurisdictions. We show that, even in the absence of transfer pricing, the platform shifts profit from the high-tax to the low-tax jurisdiction exploiting network externalities under Separate Accounting and manipulating the apportionment key under Formula Apportionment. In order to shift profit, the platform distorts prices and quantities. Under Separate Accounting, the direction of the distortions depends on the sign of the externalities. We use a numerical simulation to show that the ranking of fiscal revenues under the two regimes differs in the two jurisdictions: The high-tax jurisdiction prefers Separate Accounting to Formula Apportionment, whereas the low-tax jurisdiction prefers Formula Apportionment to Separate Accounting.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See the proposal in OECD (2019)
 
2
This is the case with France, which passed a law in July 2019 imposing a tax of 3% on the revenues based on intermediation and targeted advertising of 27 large digital platforms. Austria has passed a similar law in October 2019 imposing a tax of 5% on online advertising. Other countries, such as Turkey, UK, Belgium, Spain and the UK, have also declared their intention to introduce taxes on digital services (ranging from 2% in the UK to 7.5% in Turkey) in 2020. See “Why digital taxes are the new trade war flashpoint,” The Washington Post, December 10, 2019. However, to the best of our knowledge, none of the proposed taxes has actually been implemented yet.
 
3
In January 2016, Google and HM Treasury reached an agreement on the tax liability of Google in the UK. See “Google agrees to pay British authorities £130 m in back taxes,” The Guardian, January 23, 2016. In 2016, Facebook decided to stop declaring all its non-US profits in Ireland and agreed to submit profit declarations in all countries in which it operates a sales office.
 
4
We note that this manipulation under FA can happen even in the absence of network externalities across jurisdictions.
 
5
For the high-tax jurisdiction, the effect is ambiguous as the tax base is reduced when the gap increases, and the total effect depends on the elasticity of the tax base with respect to the tax rate.
 
6
The intuition underlying this result is easy to grasp: In order to shift profit assuming the number of users in the other jurisdiction fixed, when externalities are positive, the platform has an incentive to increase rather than decrease the number of users in the high-tax jurisdiction, as this increases demand in the low-tax jurisdiction. A similar reasoning shows that the number of users is reduced in the low-tax jurisdiction with positive externalities.
 
7
As we show in the paper, the direct and indirect effects may have opposite signs, making the total effect of an increase in the gap between the two corporate tax rates ambiguous. However, there are some simple cases—such as symmetric markets, or markets with one-sided externalities where the total effect can easily be signed.
 
8
See “Supreme Court Widens Reach of Sales Taxes for online Retailers,” The New York Times, June 21, 2018.
 
9
See Bibler et al. (2018) for a study of tax compliance by AirBnB hosts in cities with and without tax collection agreements.
 
10
See Weyl (2010) for a general argument, showing equivalence between price and user strategies for monopolistic platforms. This equivalence does not hold for competitive platforms where competition in prices (Bertrand) leads to different results than competition in quantities (Cournot). See Belleflamme and Toulemonde (2018) for a study of two platforms competing in prices.
 
11
In online appendix, we show how prices can be derived from a micro-founded model based on heterogeneous users in the two jurisdictions.
 
12
Gordon and Wilson (1986) were the first to note that FA generates distortions in the choice of the platform, albeit in a different model where firms are competitive whereas we consider a monopolistic firm.
 
13
As shown in online appendix, this number is perfectly correlated with user surplus, so that the number of users is also a measure of user welfare in the two jurisdictions.
 
14
In online appendix, we present the detailed computations in the linear model and numerical simulations with asymmetric jurisdictions and asymmetric externalities.
 
15
In online appendix, we compute the equilibrium tax rate in a symmetric model under SA. This tax rate is equal to \(t^* = 1 - (\frac{\alpha }{\sigma -\alpha })^2\), a level which is very high when externalities are small.
 
16
The finding that the low-tax country prefers FA and the high-tax country prefers SA holds true whenever externalities across jurisdictions are positive. If externalities from one jurisdiction are positive and from the other negative, as seen in online Appendix, the ranking between the two regimes may be different. It remains true, however, that the two countries always disagree on the optimal profit-splitting regime: If one gets higher tax revenues under SA, the other one gets higher tax revenues under FA.
 
17
The price functions are akin to inverse demand functions, with one caveat: Due to coordination issues, a given couple of prices \((p_A,p_B)\) could lead to different demands. In that case, we select the largest demands.
 
Literature
go back to reference Anand, B. N., & Sansing, R. (2000). The Weighting Game: Formula Apportionment as an instrument of public policy. National Tax Journal, 53(2), 183–199.CrossRef Anand, B. N., & Sansing, R. (2000). The Weighting Game: Formula Apportionment as an instrument of public policy. National Tax Journal, 53(2), 183–199.CrossRef
go back to reference Belleflamme, P., & Toulemonde, E. (2018). Tax incidence on competing two-sided platforms. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 9–21.CrossRef Belleflamme, P., & Toulemonde, E. (2018). Tax incidence on competing two-sided platforms. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 9–21.CrossRef
go back to reference Bibler, A. J., Teltser, K. F., & Tremblay, M. J. (2018). Inferring tax compliance from pass-through: Evidence from Airbnb tax enforcement agreements. Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming. Bibler, A. J., Teltser, K. F., & Tremblay, M. J. (2018). Inferring tax compliance from pass-through: Evidence from Airbnb tax enforcement agreements. Review of Economics and Statistics, forthcoming.
go back to reference Bourreau, M., Caillaud, B., & De Nijs, R. (2018). Taxation of a digital monopoly platform. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 40–51.CrossRef Bourreau, M., Caillaud, B., & De Nijs, R. (2018). Taxation of a digital monopoly platform. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 20(1), 40–51.CrossRef
go back to reference Gordon, R., & Wilson, J. D. (1986). An examination of multijurisdictional corporate income taxation under formula apportionment. Econometrica, 54(6), 1357–1373.CrossRef Gordon, R., & Wilson, J. D. (1986). An examination of multijurisdictional corporate income taxation under formula apportionment. Econometrica, 54(6), 1357–1373.CrossRef
go back to reference Goolsbee, A., & Maydew, E. L. (2000). Coveting thy neighbor’s manufacturing: The Dilemma of state income apportionment. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 125–143.CrossRef Goolsbee, A., & Maydew, E. L. (2000). Coveting thy neighbor’s manufacturing: The Dilemma of state income apportionment. Journal of Public Economics, 75(1), 125–143.CrossRef
go back to reference Gresik, T. A. (2010). Formula Apportionment vs. Separate Accounting: A private information perspective. European Economic Review, 54(1), 133–149.CrossRef Gresik, T. A. (2010). Formula Apportionment vs. Separate Accounting: A private information perspective. European Economic Review, 54(1), 133–149.CrossRef
go back to reference Kind, H. J., Midelfart, K. H., & Schjelderup, G. (2005). Corporate tax systems, multinational enterprises, and economic integration. Journal of International Economics, 65(2), 507–521.CrossRef Kind, H. J., Midelfart, K. H., & Schjelderup, G. (2005). Corporate tax systems, multinational enterprises, and economic integration. Journal of International Economics, 65(2), 507–521.CrossRef
go back to reference Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2008). Efficiency enhancing taxation in two-sided markets. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1531–1539.CrossRef Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2008). Efficiency enhancing taxation in two-sided markets. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5–6), 1531–1539.CrossRef
go back to reference Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2009). On revenue and welfare dominance of Ad Valorem Taxes in two-sided markets. Economics Letters, 104(2), 86–88.CrossRef Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2009). On revenue and welfare dominance of Ad Valorem Taxes in two-sided markets. Economics Letters, 104(2), 86–88.CrossRef
go back to reference Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2010). Tax responses in platform industries. Oxford Economic Papers, 62(4), 764–783.CrossRef Kind, H. J., Koethenbuerger, M., & Schjelderup, G. (2010). Tax responses in platform industries. Oxford Economic Papers, 62(4), 764–783.CrossRef
go back to reference Kind, H. J., Schjelderup, G., & Stähler, F. (2013). Newspaper differentiation and investments in journalism: The role of tax policy. Economica, 80(317), 131–148.CrossRef Kind, H. J., Schjelderup, G., & Stähler, F. (2013). Newspaper differentiation and investments in journalism: The role of tax policy. Economica, 80(317), 131–148.CrossRef
go back to reference Koethenbuerger, M. (2020) “Taxation of Digital Platforms,” EconPol Working Paper 41, Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich. Koethenbuerger, M. (2020) “Taxation of Digital Platforms,” EconPol Working Paper 41, Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich.
go back to reference Kotsogiannis, C., & Serfes, K. (2010). Public goods and tax competition in a two-sided market. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(2), 281–321.CrossRef Kotsogiannis, C., & Serfes, K. (2010). Public goods and tax competition in a two-sided market. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 12(2), 281–321.CrossRef
go back to reference Lassmann, A., Liberini, F., Russo, A., Cuevas, A., & Cuevas, R. (2020). “Taxation and Global Spillovers in the Digital Advertising Market. Theory and Evidence from Facebook,” CesIfo working paper 8149. Lassmann, A., Liberini, F., Russo, A., Cuevas, A., & Cuevas, R. (2020). “Taxation and Global Spillovers in the Digital Advertising Market. Theory and Evidence from Facebook,” CesIfo working paper 8149.
go back to reference Nielsen, S. B., Raimondos-Moller, P., & Schjelderup, G. (2003). Formula Apportionment and transfer pricing under Oligopolistic Competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 5(2), 419–437.CrossRef Nielsen, S. B., Raimondos-Moller, P., & Schjelderup, G. (2003). Formula Apportionment and transfer pricing under Oligopolistic Competition. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 5(2), 419–437.CrossRef
go back to reference Nielsen, S. B., Raimondos-Moller, P., & Schjelderup, G. (2010). Company taxation and tax spillovers: Separate Accounting versus Formula Apportionment. European Economic Review, 54(1), 121–132.CrossRef Nielsen, S. B., Raimondos-Moller, P., & Schjelderup, G. (2010). Company taxation and tax spillovers: Separate Accounting versus Formula Apportionment. European Economic Review, 54(1), 121–132.CrossRef
go back to reference Suarez Serrato, J. C., & Zidar, O. (2018). The structure of state corporate taxation and its impact on state tax revenues and economic activity. Journal of Public Economics, 167, 158–176.CrossRef Suarez Serrato, J. C., & Zidar, O. (2018). The structure of state corporate taxation and its impact on state tax revenues and economic activity. Journal of Public Economics, 167, 158–176.CrossRef
go back to reference Weyl, E. G. (2010). A price theory of multi-sided platforms. American Economic Review, 100(4), 1642–72.CrossRef Weyl, E. G. (2010). A price theory of multi-sided platforms. American Economic Review, 100(4), 1642–72.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
Profit-splitting rules and the taxation of multinational digital platforms
Authors
Francis Bloch
Gabrielle Demange
Publication date
02-01-2021
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 4/2021
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-020-09643-0

Other articles of this Issue 4/2021

International Tax and Public Finance 4/2021 Go to the issue