Skip to main content
Top
Published in: The Review of International Organizations 4/2020

01-05-2019

Social standards in trade agreements and free trade preferences: An empirical investigation

Authors: Ida Bastiaens, Evgeny Postnikov

Published in: The Review of International Organizations | Issue 4/2020

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Free trade generates macroeconomic gains but also creates winners and losers. Historically, to reconcile this tension, governments compensated globalization losers with social spending in exchange for support for free trade, known as the embedded liberalism compromise. In the neoliberal era, what other policies can governments pursue to strengthen support for globalization? We assess the effect of social standards in preferential trade agreements (PTAs) on individual preferences for free trade. We analyze data from an original survey experiment and find that respondents in advanced industrialized countries have greater support for free trade when PTAs include social standards. Differences do exist in how these social standards are perceived: while we do find evidence of an embedded liberalism compromise recast, fair trade norms have the most salience. An external validity check using the PEW global attitudes survey confirms the hypothesis. Our analysis has serious implications for the legitimacy of the global trading system suffering from neo-mercantilist creep.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See, for example, Abrams and Sattar (2017); Fox (2016); Naidu-Ghelani (2015).
 
2
The race to the bottom logic dictates that countries loosen taxes, regulations, and social protections to be competitive under conditions of mobile capital. This race to the bottom is taken for granted by the public, organized businesses, and governments, despite mixed evidence of it actually happening (Drezner 2000; Mosley 2005; Rudra 2008).
 
3
Social standards are rarely included in South-South PTAs and remain non-enforceable when they are. Conversely, the fear of social dislocation is lower in North-North agreements which are centered on regulatory coordination and easing intra-industry trade. While North-North agreements also include social standards, they rarely generate as much contestation among constituents (e.g. the US-Australia FTA). The recent example of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership (TTIP) (increasingly unlikely to materialize) is a unique case. TTIP controversies over labor and environmental issues largely reflect public concerns over the degree of potential regulatory convergence as both the EU and the US already include (and implement) strict social standards in their respective PTAs and in their local policy arenas.
 
4
See Milewicz et al. (2016) for various reasons behind the inclusion of non-trade issues in PTAs.
 
5
Legal mechanisms of dispute resolution are similar across EU and US PTAs, although the enforcement method differs. In EU agreements, for example, expert panel rulings (rendered in cases of non-compliance) are implemented through inter-state dialogue and meetings.
 
6
PTAs with social standards increase foreign direct investment in green and high-skilled labor industries while decreasing it in polluting and low-skilled labor ones (Lechner 2018).
 
7
Evidence points to the factoral model as suited best to explain individual attitudes towards trade both in the US and globally (Scheve and Slaughter 2001; Jäckel and Smolka 2013). Mansfield and Mutz (2009) argue for sociotropic macroeconomic factors.
 
8
We use OECD membership to distinguish the Global North and South.
 
9
Some scholars argue that the previous embedded liberalism compact has been eroded with the advancement of neoliberalism (e.g. Abdelal and Ruggie 2009; Glatzer and Rueschemeyer 2005).
 
10
1500 US organizations signed a letter opposing the TPP because it did not provide sufficient protection for labor and the environment (Citizens Trade Campaign 2016).
 
11
The 2007 US Bipartisan Trade Deal mandates the inclusion of enforceable labor and environmental provisions in all US PTAs and is the direct result of lobbying by American labor and environmentalists (Postnikov 2019).
 
12
Low-skilled workers working in the service sector also have an incentive to level the playing field. Rosenblum et al. (2000) highlight that the service sector is a significant component of overall US emissions, waste, and energy consumption (in part because it is such a large part of the US economy). Transportation, electricity, and sanitation pollutants are central to the service industry.
 
13
As previously discussed, North-South PTAs induce change in the Southern partner, the Northern state already meets (and typically exceeds) the social standard requirements.
 
14
More educated individuals have greater support for trade (Hiscox and Hainmueller 2006) and high-skilled individuals feel less economically insecure than low-skilled ones (Walter 2017).
 
15
MTurk is an online platform that recruits and compensates individuals for performing tasks.
 
16
We excluded defunct agreements. See Milewicz et al. (2016) for another dataset on PTAs.
 
17
Trade agreement texts are available on: bilaterals.​org; trade.​ec.​europe.​eu; ustr.​gov.
 
18
All supplementary material (Appendices A-E) is available at the Review of International Organizations’ webpage.
 
19
MTurk is widely used in political science (Berinsky et al. 2012), yet we remain cautious as it does not have representative samples of national populations.
 
20
We consider members of the OECD to be developed countries. Despite an overall diversity of countries listed, respondents from the United States dominate the survey sample. Results are robust to excluding the United States as well as estimating our models on respondents from the United States only (see Appendix A.1 and A.2).
 
21
This framing is conservative due to the inherent skepticism about social standards.
 
22
We use the most recent data available (year of 2010) for industrial employment for the United States to reduce missing observations.
 
23
Mexico and Turkey are OECD members, but not high-income countries. Bahrain, Croatia, Cyprus, Kuwait, Lithuania, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, Trinidad and Tobago, and the United Arab Emirates are high-income countries, but not OECD members.
 
24
PTAs with labor provisions are 0.8 correlated with PTAs with environmental provisions.
 
25
We attribute this result in the developed world to limited variation in access to water.
 
26
Results are robust to controlling for national sentiment: “Are you satisfied or dissatisfied with the way things are going in our country today.”
 
27
Operationalizing the winners and losers using income (whereby the losers are below the average income in the sample) is also robust in showing support for the positive relationship between social standards and free trade among both winners and losers (results available upon request).
 
28
In addition, low income people have been shown to have stronger perceptions of long-term environmental risks as they are potentially more threatened by climate change which means even greater material insecurity (Lo 2014).
 
29
The definition of fair trade by the World Trade Organization and various fair trade organizations also emphasizes the working conditions of farmers, poverty, and ethical business practices.
 
30
Developing countries oppose linking trade with labor and environmental standards at the multilateral level (Kolben 2006). Yet, developing countries do increasingly sign PTAs with developed states containing such clauses. This is because bilaterally developed countries have larger bargaining power and developing countries need to compete for access to their lucrative markets (Chan and Ross 2003).
 
31
Our findings are robust to a sample of respondents from India only or a sample excluding respondents from India, controlling for union membership, political ideology, and government spending and excluding individuals with prior awareness of social standards.
 
32
The PEW developing country sample and the descriptive statistics on each country’s North-South PTAs are listed in Appendix E.10.
 
Literature
go back to reference Aaronson, S. A., & Zimmerman, J. M. (2007). Trade imbalance: The struggle to weigh human rights concerns in trade policymaking. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Aaronson, S. A., & Zimmerman, J. M. (2007). Trade imbalance: The struggle to weigh human rights concerns in trade policymaking. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Abdelal, R., & Ruggie, J. G. (2009). The Principles of Embedded Liberalism: Social Legitimacy and Global Capitalism. In D. Moss & J. Cisternino (Eds.), New Perspectives on Regulation. Cambridge: Tobin Project. Abdelal, R., & Ruggie, J. G. (2009). The Principles of Embedded Liberalism: Social Legitimacy and Global Capitalism. In D. Moss & J. Cisternino (Eds.), New Perspectives on Regulation. Cambridge: Tobin Project.
go back to reference Baccini, L., & Urpelainen, J. (2014). Cutting the Gordian knot of economic reform: When and how international institutions help. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Baccini, L., & Urpelainen, J. (2014). Cutting the Gordian knot of economic reform: When and how international institutions help. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Bailey, M. (2001). Quiet influence: The representation of diffuse interests on trade policy, 1983–94. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 26(1), 45–80.CrossRef Bailey, M. (2001). Quiet influence: The representation of diffuse interests on trade policy, 1983–94. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 26(1), 45–80.CrossRef
go back to reference Bastiaens, I., & Postnikov, E. (2017). Greening up: The effects of environmental standards in EU and US trade agreements. Environmental Politics., 26(5), 847–869.CrossRef Bastiaens, I., & Postnikov, E. (2017). Greening up: The effects of environmental standards in EU and US trade agreements. Environmental Politics., 26(5), 847–869.CrossRef
go back to reference Berinsky, A. J., Huber, G. A., & Lenz, G. S. (2012). Evaluating online labor Markets for Experimental Research: Amazon.com’s mechanical Turk. Political Analysis, 20(3), 351–368.CrossRef Berinsky, A. J., Huber, G. A., & Lenz, G. S. (2012). Evaluating online labor Markets for Experimental Research: Amazon.com’s mechanical Turk. Political Analysis, 20(3), 351–368.CrossRef
go back to reference Bernauer, T., & Nguyen, Q. (2015). Free trade and/or environmental protection. Global Environmental Politics, 15(4), 105–129.CrossRef Bernauer, T., & Nguyen, Q. (2015). Free trade and/or environmental protection. Global Environmental Politics, 15(4), 105–129.CrossRef
go back to reference Bhagwati, J. (1995). Trade liberalization and ‘fair trade’ demands: Addressing the environmental and labour standards issues. The World Economy., 18(6), 745–759.CrossRef Bhagwati, J. (1995). Trade liberalization and ‘fair trade’ demands: Addressing the environmental and labour standards issues. The World Economy., 18(6), 745–759.CrossRef
go back to reference Bullard, Robert. (1999). “Leveling the Playing Field through Environmental Justice.” 23 Vt. L. Rev. 453. Bullard, Robert. (1999). “Leveling the Playing Field through Environmental Justice.” 23 Vt. L. Rev. 453.
go back to reference Cameron, D. R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. American Political Science Review., 72(4), 1243–1261.CrossRef Cameron, D. R. (1978). The expansion of the public economy: A comparative analysis. American Political Science Review., 72(4), 1243–1261.CrossRef
go back to reference Chan, A., & Ross, R. J. S. (2003). Racing to the bottom: International trade without a social clause. Third World Quarterly, 24(6), 1011–1028.CrossRef Chan, A., & Ross, R. J. S. (2003). Racing to the bottom: International trade without a social clause. Third World Quarterly, 24(6), 1011–1028.CrossRef
go back to reference Charnovitz, S. (1992). Environmental and labour standards in terade. The World Economy., 15(3), 335–356.CrossRef Charnovitz, S. (1992). Environmental and labour standards in terade. The World Economy., 15(3), 335–356.CrossRef
go back to reference Dreher, A., Sturm, J.-E., & Ursprung, H. W. (2008). The impact of globalization on the composition of government expenditures: Evidence from panel data. Public Choice, 134(3/4), 263–292.CrossRef Dreher, A., Sturm, J.-E., & Ursprung, H. W. (2008). The impact of globalization on the composition of government expenditures: Evidence from panel data. Public Choice, 134(3/4), 263–292.CrossRef
go back to reference Dür, A., Baccini, L., & Elsig, M. (2014). The Design of International Trade Agreements: Introducing a new dataset. The Review of International Organizations., 9(3), 353–375.CrossRef Dür, A., Baccini, L., & Elsig, M. (2014). The Design of International Trade Agreements: Introducing a new dataset. The Review of International Organizations., 9(3), 353–375.CrossRef
go back to reference Eckhardt, J., & Arlo, P. (2016). “The Politics of Global Value Chains: Import-Dependent Firms and EU-Asia Trade Agreements.” Journal of European Public Policy. 23(10), 1543–1562. Eckhardt, J., & Arlo, P. (2016). “The Politics of Global Value Chains: Import-Dependent Firms and EU-Asia Trade Agreements.” Journal of European Public Policy. 23(10), 1543–1562.
go back to reference Ehrlich, S. D. (2010). The fair trade challenge to embedded liberalism. International Studies Quarterly., 54(4), 1013–1033.CrossRef Ehrlich, S. D. (2010). The fair trade challenge to embedded liberalism. International Studies Quarterly., 54(4), 1013–1033.CrossRef
go back to reference Ehrlich, S. D. (2018). The politics of fair trade: Moving beyond free trade and protection. New York: Oxford University Press. Ehrlich, S. D. (2018). The politics of fair trade: Moving beyond free trade and protection. New York: Oxford University Press.
go back to reference Ehrlich, S. D., & Hearn, E. (2014). Does compensating the losers increase support for trade? An experimental test of the embedded liberalism compromise thesis. Foreign Policy Analysis., 10(2), 149–164.CrossRef Ehrlich, S. D., & Hearn, E. (2014). Does compensating the losers increase support for trade? An experimental test of the embedded liberalism compromise thesis. Foreign Policy Analysis., 10(2), 149–164.CrossRef
go back to reference Gabel. (1998). Interests and integration: Market liberalization, public opinion, and European Union. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef Gabel. (1998). Interests and integration: Market liberalization, public opinion, and European Union. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Glatzer, M., & Rueschemeyer, D. (Eds.). (2005). Globalization and the future of welfare states. Pittsburgh: Pittsburgh University Press. Glatzer, M., & Rueschemeyer, D. (Eds.). (2005). Globalization and the future of welfare states. Pittsburgh: Pittsburgh University Press.
go back to reference Gregson, N., Crang, M., Botticello, J., Calestani, M., & Krzywoszynska, A. (2016). Doing the ‘dirty work’ of the green economy: Resource recovery and migrant labour in the EU. European Urban and Regional Studies., 23(4), 541–555.CrossRef Gregson, N., Crang, M., Botticello, J., Calestani, M., & Krzywoszynska, A. (2016). Doing the ‘dirty work’ of the green economy: Resource recovery and migrant labour in the EU. European Urban and Regional Studies., 23(4), 541–555.CrossRef
go back to reference Gresser, E. (2010). Labor and environment in trade since NAFTA. Activists have achieved less, and more, than they realize. Wake Forest Law Review, 45(2), 491–525. Gresser, E. (2010). Labor and environment in trade since NAFTA. Activists have achieved less, and more, than they realize. Wake Forest Law Review, 45(2), 491–525.
go back to reference Guisinger, A. (2009). Determining trade policy: Do voters hold politicians accountable? International Organization, 63, 533–557.CrossRef Guisinger, A. (2009). Determining trade policy: Do voters hold politicians accountable? International Organization, 63, 533–557.CrossRef
go back to reference Hafner-Burton, E. M. (2009). Forced to be good: Why trade agreements boost human rights. Ithaca: Cornell University Press. Hafner-Burton, E. M. (2009). Forced to be good: Why trade agreements boost human rights. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
go back to reference Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., Layna Mosley, and Robert Galantucci. (2018). “Protecting Workers Abroad and Industries at Home: Rights-Based Conditionality in Trade Preference Programs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. 1–30. Hafner-Burton, Emilie M., Layna Mosley, and Robert Galantucci. (2018). “Protecting Workers Abroad and Industries at Home: Rights-Based Conditionality in Trade Preference Programs.” Journal of Conflict Resolution. 1–30.
go back to reference Haftel, Y. Z. (2011). Regional economic institutions and conflict mitigation: Design, implementation, and the promise of peace. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Haftel, Y. Z. (2011). Regional economic institutions and conflict mitigation: Design, implementation, and the promise of peace. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
go back to reference Hays, J. C., Ehrlich, S. D., & Peinhardt, C. (2005). Government spending and public support for trade in the OECD: An empirical test of the embedded liberalism compromise thesis. International Organization., 59(2), 473–494.CrossRef Hays, J. C., Ehrlich, S. D., & Peinhardt, C. (2005). Government spending and public support for trade in the OECD: An empirical test of the embedded liberalism compromise thesis. International Organization., 59(2), 473–494.CrossRef
go back to reference Hiscox, M. J. (2002). Commerce, coalitions, and factor mobility: Evidence from congressional votes on trade legislation. American Political Science Review, 96(3), 593–608.CrossRef Hiscox, M. J. (2002). Commerce, coalitions, and factor mobility: Evidence from congressional votes on trade legislation. American Political Science Review, 96(3), 593–608.CrossRef
go back to reference Hiscox, M. J. (2006). Through a glass and darkly: Attitudes toward international trade and the curious effects of issue framing. International Organization, 60(3), 755–780.CrossRef Hiscox, M. J. (2006). Through a glass and darkly: Attitudes toward international trade and the curious effects of issue framing. International Organization, 60(3), 755–780.CrossRef
go back to reference Hiscox, M., & Hainmueller, J. (2006). Learning to love globalization: The effects of education on individual attitudes towards international trade. International Organization, 60(2), 469–498. Hiscox, M., & Hainmueller, J. (2006). Learning to love globalization: The effects of education on individual attitudes towards international trade. International Organization, 60(2), 469–498.
go back to reference Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and Postmodernization: Cultural, economic, and political change in 43 societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Inglehart, R. (1997). Modernization and Postmodernization: Cultural, economic, and political change in 43 societies. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Jäckel, I. C., & Smolka, M. (2013). Individual attitudes towards trade: Stolper-Samuelson revisited. Open Economies Review, 24(4), 731–761.CrossRef Jäckel, I. C., & Smolka, M. (2013). Individual attitudes towards trade: Stolper-Samuelson revisited. Open Economies Review, 24(4), 731–761.CrossRef
go back to reference Jinnah, S., & Lindsay, A. (2016). Diffusion through issue linkage: Environmental norms in U.S. trade agreements. Global Environmental Politics, 16(3), 41–61.CrossRef Jinnah, S., & Lindsay, A. (2016). Diffusion through issue linkage: Environmental norms in U.S. trade agreements. Global Environmental Politics, 16(3), 41–61.CrossRef
go back to reference Jinnah, S., & Morgera, E. (2013). Environmental provisions in American and EU free trade agreements: A preliminary comparison and research agenda. Review of European Community and International Environmental Law., 22(3), 324–339.CrossRef Jinnah, S., & Morgera, E. (2013). Environmental provisions in American and EU free trade agreements: A preliminary comparison and research agenda. Review of European Community and International Environmental Law., 22(3), 324–339.CrossRef
go back to reference Kim, M. (2012). Ex ante due diligence: Formation of PTAs and protection of labor rights. International Studies Quarterly, 56(4), 704–719.CrossRef Kim, M. (2012). Ex ante due diligence: Formation of PTAs and protection of labor rights. International Studies Quarterly, 56(4), 704–719.CrossRef
go back to reference Kolben, K. (2006). The new politics of linkage: India's opposition to the Worker's rights clause. Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies, 13(1), 225–259.CrossRef Kolben, K. (2006). The new politics of linkage: India's opposition to the Worker's rights clause. Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies, 13(1), 225–259.CrossRef
go back to reference Krosnick, J. A. (1999). Survey research. Annual Review of Psychology., 50, 537–567.CrossRef Krosnick, J. A. (1999). Survey research. Annual Review of Psychology., 50, 537–567.CrossRef
go back to reference Kucik, J. (2012). The domestic politics of institutional design: Producer preferences over trade agreement rules. Economics and Politics, 24(2), 95–118.CrossRef Kucik, J. (2012). The domestic politics of institutional design: Producer preferences over trade agreement rules. Economics and Politics, 24(2), 95–118.CrossRef
go back to reference Mosley, L. (2005) Globalisation and the state: Still room to move?. New Political Economy 10 (3):355–362 Mosley, L. (2005) Globalisation and the state: Still room to move?. New Political Economy 10 (3):355–362
go back to reference Lechner, L. (2016). The domestic battle over the design of non-trade issues in preferential trade agreements. Review of International Political Economy., 23(5), 840–871.CrossRef Lechner, L. (2016). The domestic battle over the design of non-trade issues in preferential trade agreements. Review of International Political Economy., 23(5), 840–871.CrossRef
go back to reference Lechner, L. (2018). Good for some, bad for others: US investors and non-trade issues in preferential trade agreements. The Review of International Organizations., 13(2), 163–187.CrossRef Lechner, L. (2018). Good for some, bad for others: US investors and non-trade issues in preferential trade agreements. The Review of International Organizations., 13(2), 163–187.CrossRef
go back to reference Lo, A. Y. (2014). Negative income effect on perception of long-term environmental risk. Ecological Economics., 107, 51–58.CrossRef Lo, A. Y. (2014). Negative income effect on perception of long-term environmental risk. Ecological Economics., 107, 51–58.CrossRef
go back to reference Manger, M. (2009). Investing in protection: The politics of preferential trade agreements between north and south. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Manger, M. (2009). Investing in protection: The politics of preferential trade agreements between north and south. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Mansfield, E. D., & Mutz, D. C. (2009). Support for free trade: Self-interest, Sociotropic politics, and out-group anxiety. International Organization, 63(3), 425–457.CrossRef Mansfield, E. D., & Mutz, D. C. (2009). Support for free trade: Self-interest, Sociotropic politics, and out-group anxiety. International Organization, 63(3), 425–457.CrossRef
go back to reference Mayda, A. M., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Why are some people (and countries) more protectionist than others? European Economic Review, 49(6), 1393–1430.CrossRef Mayda, A. M., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Why are some people (and countries) more protectionist than others? European Economic Review, 49(6), 1393–1430.CrossRef
go back to reference McKibben, Heather and Timothy W. Taylor. (2014). “Let’s Talk About Trade: The Politicization and Framing of International Trade Policy.” APSA 2014 Annual meeting paper. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2452738. Accessed 5 July 2018 McKibben, Heather and Timothy W. Taylor. (2014). “Let’s Talk About Trade: The Politicization and Framing of International Trade Policy.” APSA 2014 Annual meeting paper. Available at SSRN: https://​ssrn.​com/​abstract=​2452738. Accessed 5 July 2018
go back to reference Medrano, J. D., & Braun, M. (2012). Uninformed citizens and support for free trade. Review of International Political Economy, 19(3), 448–476.CrossRef Medrano, J. D., & Braun, M. (2012). Uninformed citizens and support for free trade. Review of International Political Economy, 19(3), 448–476.CrossRef
go back to reference Milner, H., & Mansfield, E. D. (2012). Votes, vetoes, and the political economy of international trade agreements. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Milner, H., & Mansfield, E. D. (2012). Votes, vetoes, and the political economy of international trade agreements. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
go back to reference Morin, J.-F., & Rochette, M. (2017). Transatlantic convergence of preferential trade agreements environmental clauses. Business and Politics., 19(4), 621–658.CrossRef Morin, J.-F., & Rochette, M. (2017). Transatlantic convergence of preferential trade agreements environmental clauses. Business and Politics., 19(4), 621–658.CrossRef
go back to reference Nooruddin, I., & Rudra, N. (2014). Are developing countries really defying the embedded liberalism compact? World Politics, 66(4), 603–640.CrossRef Nooruddin, I., & Rudra, N. (2014). Are developing countries really defying the embedded liberalism compact? World Politics, 66(4), 603–640.CrossRef
go back to reference Nooruddin, I., & Simmons, J. W. (2009). Openness, uncertainty, and social spending: Implications for the globalization-welfare state debate. International Studies Quarterly., 53(3), 841–866.CrossRef Nooruddin, I., & Simmons, J. W. (2009). Openness, uncertainty, and social spending: Implications for the globalization-welfare state debate. International Studies Quarterly., 53(3), 841–866.CrossRef
go back to reference Oehri, M. (2015). Comparing EU and US labour governance ‘near and far’ – Hierarchy vs network. Journal of European Public Policy, 22(5), 731–749.CrossRef Oehri, M. (2015). Comparing EU and US labour governance ‘near and far’ – Hierarchy vs network. Journal of European Public Policy, 22(5), 731–749.CrossRef
go back to reference Pew Research Center. (2014). Faith and skepticism about trade. Foreign: Investment. Pew Research Center. (2014). Faith and skepticism about trade. Foreign: Investment.
go back to reference Pitruzello, S. (2004). “Trade globalization, economic performance, and social protection: Nineteenth-Century British Laissez-Faire and Post-World War II U.S.-Embedded Liberalism.” International Organization, 58(4), 705–744. Pitruzello, S. (2004). “Trade globalization, economic performance, and social protection: Nineteenth-Century British Laissez-Faire and Post-World War II U.S.-Embedded Liberalism.” International Organization, 58(4), 705–744.
go back to reference Polanyi, K. (2001). The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time (2nd ed.). Boston: Beacon Press. Polanyi, K. (2001). The great transformation: The political and economic origins of our time (2nd ed.). Boston: Beacon Press.
go back to reference Postnikov, E. (2019). Unraveling the puzzle of social standards design in EU and US trade agreements. New Political Economy., 24 (2): 181–196. Postnikov, E. (2019). Unraveling the puzzle of social standards design in EU and US trade agreements. New Political Economy., 24 (2): 181–196.
go back to reference Postnikov, E., & Bastiaens, I. (2014). Does dialogue work? The effectiveness of labor standards in EU preferential trade agreements. Journal of European Public Policy., 21(6), 923–940.CrossRef Postnikov, E., & Bastiaens, I. (2014). Does dialogue work? The effectiveness of labor standards in EU preferential trade agreements. Journal of European Public Policy., 21(6), 923–940.CrossRef
go back to reference Raess, D., Dür, A., & Sari, D. (2018). Protecting labor rights in preferential trade agreements: The role of trade unions, left governments, and skilled labor. Review of International Organizations., 13, 143–162.CrossRef Raess, D., Dür, A., & Sari, D. (2018). Protecting labor rights in preferential trade agreements: The role of trade unions, left governments, and skilled labor. Review of International Organizations., 13, 143–162.CrossRef
go back to reference Rosenblum, J., Horvath, A., & Hendrickson, C. (2000). Environmental implications of service industries. Policy Analysis, 34(22), 4669–4676. Rosenblum, J., Horvath, A., & Hendrickson, C. (2000). Environmental implications of service industries. Policy Analysis, 34(22), 4669–4676.
go back to reference Rudra, N. (2008). Globalization and the race to the bottom in developing countries: Who really gets hurt? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Rudra, N. (2008). Globalization and the race to the bottom in developing countries: Who really gets hurt? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
go back to reference Rudra, N., & Haggard, S. (2005). Globalization, democracy, and effective welfare spending in the developing world. Comparative Political Studies., 38(9), 1015–1049.CrossRef Rudra, N., & Haggard, S. (2005). Globalization, democracy, and effective welfare spending in the developing world. Comparative Political Studies., 38(9), 1015–1049.CrossRef
go back to reference Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.CrossRef Ruggie, J. G. (1982). International regimes, transactions, and change: Embedded liberalism in the postwar economic order. International Organization, 36(2), 379–415.CrossRef
go back to reference Scheve, K. F., & Slaughter, M. J. (2001). What determines individual trade-policy preferences. Journal of International Economics, 54(2), 267–292.CrossRef Scheve, K. F., & Slaughter, M. J. (2001). What determines individual trade-policy preferences. Journal of International Economics, 54(2), 267–292.CrossRef
go back to reference Scott, B., & Bergstrand, J. (2007). Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 72–95.CrossRef Scott, B., & Bergstrand, J. (2007). Journal of International Economics, 71(1), 72–95.CrossRef
go back to reference Stolper, W. F., & Samuelson, P. A. (1941). Protection and real wages. Review of Economic Studies, 9, 58–73.CrossRef Stolper, W. F., & Samuelson, P. A. (1941). Protection and real wages. Review of Economic Studies, 9, 58–73.CrossRef
go back to reference Taylor, T. W. (2015). The electoral salience of trade policy: Experimental evidence on the effects of welfare and complexity. International Interactions, 41(1), 84–109.CrossRef Taylor, T. W. (2015). The electoral salience of trade policy: Experimental evidence on the effects of welfare and complexity. International Interactions, 41(1), 84–109.CrossRef
go back to reference Walter, S. (2010). Globalization and the welfare state: Testing the microfoundations of the compensation hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2), 403–426.CrossRef Walter, S. (2010). Globalization and the welfare state: Testing the microfoundations of the compensation hypothesis. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2), 403–426.CrossRef
go back to reference Walter, S. (2017). Globalization and the demand side of politics: How globalization shapes labor market risk perceptions and policy preferences. Political Science Research and Methods, 5(1), 55–80.CrossRef Walter, S. (2017). Globalization and the demand side of politics: How globalization shapes labor market risk perceptions and policy preferences. Political Science Research and Methods, 5(1), 55–80.CrossRef
go back to reference Zaracostas, J. (1992). Developing Nations Fear Trade-Pollution Link. Journal of Commerce. May 28. Zaracostas, J. (1992). Developing Nations Fear Trade-Pollution Link. Journal of Commerce. May 28.
Metadata
Title
Social standards in trade agreements and free trade preferences: An empirical investigation
Authors
Ida Bastiaens
Evgeny Postnikov
Publication date
01-05-2019
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
The Review of International Organizations / Issue 4/2020
Print ISSN: 1559-7431
Electronic ISSN: 1559-744X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11558-019-09356-y

Other articles of this Issue 4/2020

The Review of International Organizations 4/2020 Go to the issue