Skip to main content
Top
Published in: International Tax and Public Finance 5/2017

31-12-2016

Tax evasion in a Cournot oligopoly with endogenous entry

Author: Laszlo Goerke

Published in: International Tax and Public Finance | Issue 5/2017

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

If an additional competitor reduces output per firm in a homogenous Cournot oligopoly, market entry will be excessive. Taxes can correct the so-called business stealing externality. We investigate how evading a tax on operating profits affects the excessive entry prediction. Tax evasion raises the number of firms in market equilibrium and can alter their welfare-maximising number. In consequence, evasion can aggravate or mitigate excessive entry. Which of these outcomes prevails is determined by the direct welfare consequences of tax evasion and the relationship between evasion and the tax base. We also determine conditions which imply that overall welfare declines with tax evasion.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
See, for example, Cremer and Gahvari (1993) and Besfamille et al. (2009, 2013) for similar approaches. In contrast to these contributions, we do not assume \(S_{1}(0, \pi _j) = 0\) to also allow for the possibility that no evasion constitutes optimal behaviour.
 
2
See Slemrod (2001) and Grubert and Slemrod (1998) for models of personal or corporate income tax avoidance which are based on assumptions which are tantamount to \(S_{12} < 0\).
 
3
Note that the costs of evasion could also be specified as increasing with the tax rate, \(\tau \). For a given tax rate, such modification would not alter the main findings because the alteration would primarily affect the impact of the tax rate on evasion activities (see “Impact of higher tax rate” section of Appendix).
 
4
It could be argued that tax evasion is easily detectable because all firms are ex-post identical and evade the same amount. Accordingly, authorities could eradicate evasion by auditing all firms. Such an outcome will not occur if either proving evasion activities is required and sufficiently costly to tax authorities such that they cannot establish illegal activities for all firms. Alternatively, one could assume that operating profits are given by \((P(X) - c)x - k\), where k varies across firms. If authorities do not know the value of k, a given tax payment does no longer indicate illegal behaviour. Since the inclusion of such firm-specific operational costs would considerably extend the notation without yielding additional insights, we refrain from doing so.
 
5
Besley (1989) considers a unit tax on output in a Cournot oligopoly in the absence of tax evasion. He shows for a setting with constant unit costs that output per firm rises with the tax rate if \(\eta > 0\), while the number of firms declines with the tax rate if \(2 + \eta > 0\), while aggregate output unambiguously falls. Delipalla and Keen (1992) provide comparable predictions and, furthermore, show that the consequences of a higher ad valorem tax are more ambiguous because this tax also reduces marginal revenues and, thus, mitigates the product market imperfection (see also Stern 1987; Hamilton 1999).
 
6
The positive impact of the tax rate on tax evasion is a common prediction in models of tax evasion by firms which maximise (expected) profits (see, for example, Cremer and Gahvari 1993). If the objective is defined in terms of utility, risk aversion also plays a role (cf. Yaniv 1995, inter alia), as it is the case with regard to income taxes paid by individuals.
 
7
von Weizsäcker (1980) and Suzumura and Kiyono (1987), for example, also compare the market outcome to the first-best.
 
8
Combining (13a) and (16), the tax rate which ensures the second-best optimal number of firms, \(n^{0,\hbox {opt}}\), can be calculated. It is implicitly defined by \(\tau - (n^{0,\hbox {opt}}(\tau )+\eta )/(1 + n^{0,\hbox {opt}}(\tau )+\eta ) = 0\).
 
9
As in a framework without evasion, the tax rate which ensures the constrained-optimal number of firms can be calculated on the basis of Eqs. (7) and (17). For \(\beta = 1\), it is possible to show that the tax rate must satisfy \(\tau (1 - \alpha )- (n^{+,\hbox {opt}}(\tau )+\eta )/(1 + n^{+,\hbox {opt}}(\tau )+\eta ) < 0\), where \(n^{0,\hbox {opt}}(\tau ) = n^{+,\hbox {opt}}(\tau )\) for any given tax rate and \(\hbox {d}n/\hbox {d}\tau < 0\). Hence, the constrained-optimal effective tax rate \(\tau (1- \alpha )\) in the presence of evasion activities must be lower than the second-best optimal tax rate \(\tau \) in a world without evasion. This is the case because the costs of evasion deter entry, ceteris paribus. For \(\beta < 1\), the optimal number of firms generally depends on the extent of tax evasion.
 
10
A lower detection probability combines a fall in the absolute costs of tax evasion with a decrease in marginal costs. An increase in tax evasion activities would also come about if either only the marginal costs of evasion decline, while the cost level is held constant, or alternatively if the absolute costs of evasion rise, while marginal costs remain unchanged. In terms of the model, the first type of change would be equivalent to a reduction in the detection probability, q, and a rise in the fixed costs, \(c_\mathrm{fix}\), such that total costs \(T = q\pi (\alpha , \alpha ) + c_\mathrm{fix}\) remain the same. The second type of change would be tantamount to a rise in the fixed costs. We do not explicitly consider the consequences of such alterations in the costs of tax evasion because they are more difficult to implement than a combined decrease in marginal and absolute costs. The relevant derivations can be obtained from the author upon request and are used to some extent to provide intuition for the results relating to a change in q.
 
11
If \(E_{\pi } > 0\), higher profits imply that less evasion is needed to cover its costs, since the tax base rises. Accordingly, a fall in the absolute costs of evasion T, holding constant the marginal costs, \(T'\), results in less evasion.
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d\alpha }{dT_{|dT'=0}}=-E_n\frac{(P'(X)x)^2(2n+\eta )}{nD^+} \end{aligned}$$
At the same time, higher profits induce more firms to enter the market. This implies that a fall solely in the cost level reduces evasion and enhances entry.
 
12
I am very grateful to an anonymous referee for suggesting this illustration of the main results of the paper.
 
13
As profits exceed unity, as shown below, costs of evasion \(T(\alpha , 0) = q\alpha ^{2}\) are substantially lower than in the case of \(T(\alpha , \pi ) = q(\alpha \pi )^{2}\). Consequently, the fraction of taxes evaded will be noticeably higher in the former case, given the same detection probability, q.
 
Literature
go back to reference Amir, Rabah, & Burr, Chrystie. (2015). Corruption and socially optimal entry. Journal of Public Economics, 123, 30–41.CrossRef Amir, Rabah, & Burr, Chrystie. (2015). Corruption and socially optimal entry. Journal of Public Economics, 123, 30–41.CrossRef
go back to reference Amir, Rabah, De Castro, Luciano, & Koutsougeras, Leonidas. (2014). Free entry versus socially optimal entry. Journal of Economic Theory, 154, 112–125.CrossRef Amir, Rabah, De Castro, Luciano, & Koutsougeras, Leonidas. (2014). Free entry versus socially optimal entry. Journal of Economic Theory, 154, 112–125.CrossRef
go back to reference Becker, Gary S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.CrossRef Becker, Gary S. (1968). Crime and punishment: An economic approach. Journal of Political Economy, 76(2), 169–217.CrossRef
go back to reference Besfamille, Martin, Philippe, De Donder, & Lozachmeur, Jean Marie. (2009). Tax enforcement may decrease government revenue. Economics Bulletin, 29(4), 2665–2672. Besfamille, Martin, Philippe, De Donder, & Lozachmeur, Jean Marie. (2009). Tax enforcement may decrease government revenue. Economics Bulletin, 29(4), 2665–2672.
go back to reference Besfamille, Martin, Philippe, De Donder, & Lozachmeur, Jean Marie. (2013). The political economy of the (weak) tax enforcement of indirect taxes. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15(6), 856–883. Besfamille, Martin, Philippe, De Donder, & Lozachmeur, Jean Marie. (2013). The political economy of the (weak) tax enforcement of indirect taxes. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 15(6), 856–883.
go back to reference Besley, Timothy. (1989). Commodity taxation and imperfect competition—A note on the effects of entry. Journal of Public Economics, 40(3), 359–365.CrossRef Besley, Timothy. (1989). Commodity taxation and imperfect competition—A note on the effects of entry. Journal of Public Economics, 40(3), 359–365.CrossRef
go back to reference Cremer, Helmuth, & Gahvari, Firouz. (1993). Tax evasion and optimal commodity taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 50(2), 261–275.CrossRef Cremer, Helmuth, & Gahvari, Firouz. (1993). Tax evasion and optimal commodity taxation. Journal of Public Economics, 50(2), 261–275.CrossRef
go back to reference Delipalla, Sophia, & Keen, Michael. (1992). The comparison between ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition. Journal of Public Economics, 49(3), 351–367.CrossRef Delipalla, Sophia, & Keen, Michael. (1992). The comparison between ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition. Journal of Public Economics, 49(3), 351–367.CrossRef
go back to reference European Commission. (2016). Proposal for a council directive laying down the rules against tax avoidance practices that directly affect the functioning of the common market, COM(2016) 26 final. European Commission. (2016). Proposal for a council directive laying down the rules against tax avoidance practices that directly affect the functioning of the common market, COM(2016) 26 final.
go back to reference Goerke, Laszlo. (2012). The optimal structure of commodity taxation in a monopoly with tax avoidance or evasion. Public Finance Review, 40(4), 519–536.CrossRef Goerke, Laszlo. (2012). The optimal structure of commodity taxation in a monopoly with tax avoidance or evasion. Public Finance Review, 40(4), 519–536.CrossRef
go back to reference Goerke, Laszlo, & Runkel, Marco. (2006). Profit tax evasion under oligopoly with endogenous market structure. National Tax Journal, 59(4), 851–857.CrossRef Goerke, Laszlo, & Runkel, Marco. (2006). Profit tax evasion under oligopoly with endogenous market structure. National Tax Journal, 59(4), 851–857.CrossRef
go back to reference Goerke, Laszlo, & Runkel, Marco. (2011). Tax evasion and competition. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 58(5), 711–736.CrossRef Goerke, Laszlo, & Runkel, Marco. (2011). Tax evasion and competition. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 58(5), 711–736.CrossRef
go back to reference Grubert, Harry, & Slemrod, Joel. (1998). The effect of taxes on investment and income shifting to Puerto Rico. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(3), 365–373.CrossRef Grubert, Harry, & Slemrod, Joel. (1998). The effect of taxes on investment and income shifting to Puerto Rico. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(3), 365–373.CrossRef
go back to reference Hamilton, Stephen F. (1999). Tax incidence under oligopoly: A comparison of policy approaches. Journal of Public Economics, 71(2), 233–245.CrossRef Hamilton, Stephen F. (1999). Tax incidence under oligopoly: A comparison of policy approaches. Journal of Public Economics, 71(2), 233–245.CrossRef
go back to reference Haruna, Shoji, & Goel, Rajeev K. (2011). R&D free entry, and social inefficiency. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 20(1–2), 89–101.CrossRef Haruna, Shoji, & Goel, Rajeev K. (2011). R&D free entry, and social inefficiency. Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 20(1–2), 89–101.CrossRef
go back to reference Konishi, Hideki, Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, & Suzumura, Kotaro. (1990). Oligopolistic competition and economic welfare: A general equilibrium analysis of entry regulation and tax-subsidy schemes. Journal of Public Economics, 42(1), 67–88.CrossRef Konishi, Hideki, Okuno-Fujiwara, Masahiro, & Suzumura, Kotaro. (1990). Oligopolistic competition and economic welfare: A general equilibrium analysis of entry regulation and tax-subsidy schemes. Journal of Public Economics, 42(1), 67–88.CrossRef
go back to reference Mankiw, N. Gregory, & Whinston, Michael D. (1986). Free entry and social inefficiency. The Rand Journal of Economics, 17(1), 48–58.CrossRef Mankiw, N. Gregory, & Whinston, Michael D. (1986). Free entry and social inefficiency. The Rand Journal of Economics, 17(1), 48–58.CrossRef
go back to reference Mukherjee, Arijit. (2012). Endogenous cost asymmetry and insufficient entry in the absence of scale economies. Journal of Economics, 106(1), 75–82.CrossRef Mukherjee, Arijit. (2012). Endogenous cost asymmetry and insufficient entry in the absence of scale economies. Journal of Economics, 106(1), 75–82.CrossRef
go back to reference Ohkawa, Takao, & Okamura, Makoto. (2003). On the uniqueness of the welfare-maximizing number of firms under Cournot-oligopoly. Bulletin of Economic Research, 55(2), 209–222.CrossRef Ohkawa, Takao, & Okamura, Makoto. (2003). On the uniqueness of the welfare-maximizing number of firms under Cournot-oligopoly. Bulletin of Economic Research, 55(2), 209–222.CrossRef
go back to reference Perry, M. K. (1984). Scale economies, imperfect competition, and public policy. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 32(3), 313–333.CrossRef Perry, M. K. (1984). Scale economies, imperfect competition, and public policy. The Journal of Industrial Economics, 32(3), 313–333.CrossRef
go back to reference Roine, Jesper. (2006). The political economics of not paying taxes. Public Choice, 126(1–2), 107–134.CrossRef Roine, Jesper. (2006). The political economics of not paying taxes. Public Choice, 126(1–2), 107–134.CrossRef
go back to reference Seade, Jesus. (1980). On the effects of entry. Econometrica, 48(2), 479–489.CrossRef Seade, Jesus. (1980). On the effects of entry. Econometrica, 48(2), 479–489.CrossRef
go back to reference Seidel, A., & Thum, M. (2016). Tax evasion, corruption and market entry. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 63(4), 377–398. Seidel, A., & Thum, M. (2016). Tax evasion, corruption and market entry. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 63(4), 377–398.
go back to reference Slemrod, Joel. (2001). A general model of the behavioral response to taxation. International Tax and Public Finance, 8(2), 119–128.CrossRef Slemrod, Joel. (2001). A general model of the behavioral response to taxation. International Tax and Public Finance, 8(2), 119–128.CrossRef
go back to reference Stern, Nicholas. (1987). The effects of taxation, oligopoly and monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economics, 32, 133–158.CrossRef Stern, Nicholas. (1987). The effects of taxation, oligopoly and monopolistic competition. Journal of Public Economics, 32, 133–158.CrossRef
go back to reference Suzumura, Kotaro. (1995). Competition, commitment, and welfare. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Suzumura, Kotaro. (1995). Competition, commitment, and welfare. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
go back to reference Suzumura, Kotaro, & Kiyono, Kazuharu. (1987). Entry barriers and economic welfare. Review of Economic Studies, 54(1), 157–167.CrossRef Suzumura, Kotaro, & Kiyono, Kazuharu. (1987). Entry barriers and economic welfare. Review of Economic Studies, 54(1), 157–167.CrossRef
go back to reference Traxler, Christian. (2009). Voting over taxes: The case of tax evasion. Public Choice, 140(1), 43–58.CrossRef Traxler, Christian. (2009). Voting over taxes: The case of tax evasion. Public Choice, 140(1), 43–58.CrossRef
go back to reference Varian, Hal. (1995). Entry and cost reduction. Japan and the World Economy, 7(4), 399–410.CrossRef Varian, Hal. (1995). Entry and cost reduction. Japan and the World Economy, 7(4), 399–410.CrossRef
go back to reference von Weizsäcker, Carl Christian. (1980). A welfare analysis of barriers to entry. Bell Journal of Economics, 11(2), 399–420.CrossRef von Weizsäcker, Carl Christian. (1980). A welfare analysis of barriers to entry. Bell Journal of Economics, 11(2), 399–420.CrossRef
go back to reference Yaniv, Gideon. (1995). A note on the tax evading firm. National Tax Journal, 48(1), 113–120. Yaniv, Gideon. (1995). A note on the tax evading firm. National Tax Journal, 48(1), 113–120.
Metadata
Title
Tax evasion in a Cournot oligopoly with endogenous entry
Author
Laszlo Goerke
Publication date
31-12-2016
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
International Tax and Public Finance / Issue 5/2017
Print ISSN: 0927-5940
Electronic ISSN: 1573-6970
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-016-9434-z

Other articles of this Issue 5/2017

International Tax and Public Finance 5/2017 Go to the issue