Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Empirical Economics 4/2015

01-06-2015

The effect of life expectancy on education and population dynamics

Authors: Matteo Cervellati, Uwe Sunde

Published in: Empirical Economics | Issue 4/2015

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

The demographic transition represents a critical turning point for population dynamics and economic development. As a consequence, the effects of life expectancy on education and population dynamics are expected to change across different stages of demographic development. This paper tests this hypothesis empirically by exploiting exogenous within-country reductions in mortality as a result of the epidemiological transition after 1940 that have been applied in recent studies on the causal effects of life expectancy for income growth. The results document a pronounced heterogeneity, and relevant non-linearities, of the effects of life expectancy on schooling and population dynamics at different stages of the demographic transition.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
This figure replicates the corresponding figures from Chesnais (1992) and Livi-Bacci (1992), see also, Cervellati and Sunde (2011). See also Kirk (1996), Caldwell (2006), Dyson (2010), and Canning (2011) for a discussion of the literature on the demographic transition.
 
2
As discussed in more details below, the instrumentation strategy builds on the work by Acemoglu and Johnson (2007).
 
3
Technically, modeling this effect requires considering that parents with non-homothetic preferences derive utility only from children that survive to adulthood. This channel should be expected to be at work in the context of mortality affecting young adults rather than for child and infant mortality, because replacing children is easier than replacing adult offsprings.
 
4
Some complementary mechanisms might also reinforce this link. Most notably, delayed child birth can be related to increased education enrolments, see Bhrolchain and Beaujouan (2012), the higher labor force participation of women, see Bloom et al. (2009b), or the increase in capital endowments and consumption, see Lee and Mason (2010).
 
5
This has been pointed out already by Kalemli-Ozcan (2003) and Doepke (2005) for the precautionary demand motive for fertility. See also Soares (2005) for the analysis of the role of child mortality and adults longevity for the quantity–quality framework and Cervellati and Sunde (2014) for a more extensive more extensive discussion of this issue.
 
6
The effect of life expectancy on growth may also pass through other channels like, e.g., savings, dependency rates, or production of knowledge which are not investigated in this paper.
 
7
Their results also document that the different findings in the literature are not due to the different instrumentation strategies, but are largely due to the use of linear regression frameworks. The heterogeneity of effects implies that sample composition in terms of the relative number of countries before and after the transition is, however, crucial for estimates obtained with linear models.
 
8
The specification of preferences essentially follows Galor and Weil (2000), where the second component generates a link between generations that can be interpreted as a warm glow type of altruistic preferences. Given homothetic preferences, the optimal decisions are unaffected when assuming that utility depends on (planned) fertility rather than the number of surviving offspring or realized gross fertility. Also, it is implicitly assumed that individuals can perfectly smooth consumption as well as the utility from children over their lifetime, but crucially, they cannot perfectly substitute utility from their own consumption with utility derived from their offspring.
 
9
The simple formulation adopted here reflects a partial equilibrium setting with exogenous (and normalized) wages. This setting is consistent with the more general treatment in Cervellati and Sunde (2005, 2014), where investments in human capital depend on life expectancy, as well as on wages that are determined in general equilibrium, and where different types of human capital involve a different opportunity cost of raising children.
 
10
To ensure that parents with higher education have fewer children as the opportunity cost of fertility increases in the education investment, one can assume that \(\eta \gamma >x\left( 1-\gamma \right) \). This parametric restriction implies that the returns to investments in education are large enough to compensate for the increasing (opportunity) cost of raising children. In the literature the returns to education, here summarized by \(\eta \), have been related endogenously to skill-biased technological change, which would eventually make education profitable. In this paper we abstract from technological dynamics to concentrate on the main testable predictions. Also, notice that the acquisition of one’s own education would further reinforce the fertility reduction in a quantity–quality framework a laSoares (2005) if educated parents are more effective in producing educated (high quality) children.
 
11
In light of the literature, this is consistent with differential fertility across different education groups.
 
12
This mechanism would be at work before the demographic transition also if subsistence levels in consumption were considered, see, e.g., Galor and Weil (2000) or Croix and Licandro (2013).
 
13
Recall that the, GRR is the average number of daughters that would be born to the representative woman if she survived at least to the end of her reproductive life (given the age-specific fertility rate of each age). The TFR is similarly defined as the GRR but it refers to the average number of children (and not daughters). Abstracting from differences in birth rates between sexes, and since our model is asexual it holds that TFR = 2 \(\cdot \) GRR. Interpreting n to the be the planned GRR implies TFR \(=\) 2 \(\cdot \) GRR \(=\) 2 \(\cdot \) n.
 
14
The NRR is defined the same way as the GRR, but in addition to the age-specific fertility rates, it also accounts for the age-specific mortality rates.
 
15
In the theory presented in the previous section, we followed the typical assumptions in the long-run growth literature and abstracted from life cycle considerations and age-specific mortality rates, consistent with the conditions of a stable population model.
 
16
An alternative strategy would involve estimating the model on the pooled sample and allow the parameter \(\alpha \) to vary across pre-transitional and post-transitional countries. Compared to the estimation using split samples, this partial interaction approach would force the time effects to be the same across the two sub-samples, rather than allowing all parameters, even those not linked to life expectancy, to vary, as in the fully interacted model (with split samples). The analysis below presents results for the split sample estimation because it is more flexible.
 
17
See (Preston et al. (2001), pp. 158–159). In terms of population growth the only difference with respect to the predictions for \(\mathrm{{NRR}}_t\) derived above is that \(\lambda \equiv \lambda _1+\lambda _2>0\) may depend on both the long term component (reduced mortality in childbearing ages reflected by \(\lambda _1\)) and a temporary component (due to the higher survival of individuals at each point in time \(\lambda _2\)).
 
18
Age 25 is considered to concentrate attention to individuals with completed education. For robustness, the results have also been replicated with alternative measures such as the population share aged 15 and older without formal schooling, with qualitatively similar results that are available upon request.
 
19
Alternatively, we used average years of schooling of the entire population above 15, or average years of secondary schooling, with similar results. The effect of life expectancy might also affect the acquisition of human capital through channels alternative to formal schooling (like parents increasing the investment in quality at home, etc). However, the lack of comparable cross-panel data on alternative measures over a long period of time prevented us from investigating this possibility.
 
20
It should be noticed, however, that the measure of life expectancy at age 20 constitutes a very conservative and potentially overly restrictive measure for several reasons. First, the theoretical predictions are not restricted to life expectancy above the age of 20, but also apply to younger ages. Second, and most importantly, data availability is limited for life expectancy at later ages, and the data are of lower quality and inferior reliability. See also (Zhang and Zhang (2005), p. 53) for a discussion of this issue.
 
21
See also Acemoglu and Johnson (2007) for a discussion of this issue.
 
22
Ideally, one would take into account the exact time when the mortality reduction treatment is applied to a country and whether the country is pre-transitional or post-transitional at the time of treatment. In principle, the available data on fertility and realized mortality do allow for a fairly precise identification of the onset of the demographic transition within a range of about 10 years. However, the data on the predicted mortality instrument only contain country-specific information for the predicted change in mortality over the full period. See also the discussion on this issue in Cervellati and Sunde (2011).
 
23
To verify the second requirement we follow Reher (2004) and consider a country to be post-transitional if it has entered the falling trend in terms of the 5-year averages of crude birth rates by the year 1935. His definition of a sustained decline in fertility refers to the beginning of the first quinquennium after a peak, where fertility declines by at least 8 % over two quinquennia and never increases again to the levels of the original take-off point, ignoring one-time events (Reher 2004, p. 21). In robustness checks, we also considered the threshold of crude birth rates of 25/1,000 which, however, is more restrictive and fragile to short term fluctuations in birth rates like, e.g., the baby boom. Likewise, we also considered a less restrictive threshold of 35/1,000. All results are qualitatively identical.
 
24
In the case of Greece the problem is the lack of reliable data before 1950. Ireland and New Zealand display a very flat profile of crude birth rates around 30/1,000 after 1940 and a clear drop only in 1980 and 1960, respectively.
 
25
Robustness checks available upon request reveal qualitatively and quantitatively similar results when coding these countries as post-transitional.
 
26
We report +20 as reflecting the expected age at death to be comparable to life expectancy at birth.
 
27
Similar findings emerge when looking at the changes in the share of population with no schooling aged 15 and above. In this case the effect of life expectancy is positive and even slightly significant, although the effect is still substantially smaller in size than the effect obtained for post-transitional countries. This is to be expected since this measure further includes individuals aged 15–25 by 2000, which are the cohorts most likely affected by the reduction in fertility in countries that had not undergone the demographic transition by 1940, but underwent the fertility drop during the 1960s and 1970s. The results are available upon request.
 
28
Detailed results are available upon request.
 
29
Differently from education data this conjecture cannot be directly tested, however, since TFRs for the younger cohorts are not yet available.
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu D, Johnson S (2007) Disease and development: the effect of life expectancy on economic growth. J Polit Econ 115(6):925–985CrossRef Acemoglu D, Johnson S (2007) Disease and development: the effect of life expectancy on economic growth. J Polit Econ 115(6):925–985CrossRef
go back to reference Aghion P, Howitt P, Murtin F (2011) The relationship between health and growth: when Lucas meets Nelson–Phelps. Rev Econ Inst 2(1):1–24 Aghion P, Howitt P, Murtin F (2011) The relationship between health and growth: when Lucas meets Nelson–Phelps. Rev Econ Inst 2(1):1–24
go back to reference Barro RJ, Lee J (2001) International data on educational attainment: updates and implications. Oxf Econ Papers 53(3):541–563CrossRef Barro RJ, Lee J (2001) International data on educational attainment: updates and implications. Oxf Econ Papers 53(3):541–563CrossRef
go back to reference Bhrolchain NN, Beaujouan E (2012) Fertility postponement is largely due to rising educational enrolment. Popul Stud 66(3):311–327CrossRef Bhrolchain NN, Beaujouan E (2012) Fertility postponement is largely due to rising educational enrolment. Popul Stud 66(3):311–327CrossRef
go back to reference Blackburn K, Cipriani GP (2002) A model of longevity fertility and growth. J Econ Dyn Control 26:187–204CrossRef Blackburn K, Cipriani GP (2002) A model of longevity fertility and growth. J Econ Dyn Control 26:187–204CrossRef
go back to reference Bloom DE, Canning D, Fink G (2009a) Disease and development revisited. NBER Working Paper, 15137 Bloom DE, Canning D, Fink G (2009a) Disease and development revisited. NBER Working Paper, 15137
go back to reference Bloom DE, Canning D, Fink G, Finlay JE (2009b) Fertility, female labor force participation, and the demographic dividend. J Econ Growth 14(1):71–101 Bloom DE, Canning D, Fink G, Finlay JE (2009b) Fertility, female labor force participation, and the demographic dividend. J Econ Growth 14(1):71–101
go back to reference Bongaarts J (2003) Completing the fertility transition in the developing world: the role of educational differences and fertility preferences. Popul Stud 57(3):321–336CrossRef Bongaarts J (2003) Completing the fertility transition in the developing world: the role of educational differences and fertility preferences. Popul Stud 57(3):321–336CrossRef
go back to reference Boucekkine R, de la Croix D, Licandro O (2003) Early mortality declines at the dawn of modern growth. Scand J Econ 105:401–418CrossRef Boucekkine R, de la Croix D, Licandro O (2003) Early mortality declines at the dawn of modern growth. Scand J Econ 105:401–418CrossRef
go back to reference Caldwell JC (2006) Demographic transition theory. Springer, New York Caldwell JC (2006) Demographic transition theory. Springer, New York
go back to reference Canning D (2011) The causes and consequences of demographic transition. Popul Stud 65(3):353–361CrossRef Canning D (2011) The causes and consequences of demographic transition. Popul Stud 65(3):353–361CrossRef
go back to reference Cervellati M, Sunde U (2005) Human capital, life expectancy, and the process of development. Am Econ Rev 95(5):1653–1672CrossRef Cervellati M, Sunde U (2005) Human capital, life expectancy, and the process of development. Am Econ Rev 95(5):1653–1672CrossRef
go back to reference Cervellati M, Sunde U (2011) Life expectancy and economic growth: the role of the demographic transition. J Econ Growth 16:99–133CrossRef Cervellati M, Sunde U (2011) Life expectancy and economic growth: the role of the demographic transition. J Econ Growth 16:99–133CrossRef
go back to reference Cervellati M, Sunde U (2014) The economic and demographic transition, mortality, and comparative development. Am Econ J Macro (forthcoming) Cervellati M, Sunde U (2014) The economic and demographic transition, mortality, and comparative development. Am Econ J Macro (forthcoming)
go back to reference Cervellati M, Sunde U (2013) Life expectancy, schooling, and lifetime labor supply: theory and evidence revisited. Econometrica 81(5):2055–2086 Cervellati M, Sunde U (2013) Life expectancy, schooling, and lifetime labor supply: theory and evidence revisited. Econometrica 81(5):2055–2086
go back to reference Chesnais JC (1992) The demographic transition: stages, patterns and economic implications. A longitudinal study of sixty-seven countries covering the period 1720–1984. Clarendon Press, Oxford Chesnais JC (1992) The demographic transition: stages, patterns and economic implications. A longitudinal study of sixty-seven countries covering the period 1720–1984. Clarendon Press, Oxford
go back to reference Cohen D, Soto M (2007) Growth and human capital: good data, good results. J Econ Growth 12(1):51–76 Cohen D, Soto M (2007) Growth and human capital: good data, good results. J Econ Growth 12(1):51–76
go back to reference De La Croix D, Doepke M (2003) Inequality and growth: why differential fertility matters. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1091–1113CrossRef De La Croix D, Doepke M (2003) Inequality and growth: why differential fertility matters. Am Econ Rev 93(4):1091–1113CrossRef
go back to reference De La Croix D, Licandro O (2013) The child is father of the man: implications for the demographic transition. Econ J 123(567):236–261CrossRef De La Croix D, Licandro O (2013) The child is father of the man: implications for the demographic transition. Econ J 123(567):236–261CrossRef
go back to reference Doepke M (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: does the Barro–Becker model fit the facts? J Popul Econ 17(2):337–366CrossRef Doepke M (2005) Child mortality and fertility decline: does the Barro–Becker model fit the facts? J Popul Econ 17(2):337–366CrossRef
go back to reference Dyson T (2010) Population and development: the demographic transition. Zed Books, London Dyson T (2010) Population and development: the demographic transition. Zed Books, London
go back to reference Galor O (2005) From stagnation to growth: unified growth theory, chap. 4. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam Galor O (2005) From stagnation to growth: unified growth theory, chap. 4. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier Science, Amsterdam
go back to reference Galor O (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton Galor O (2011) Unified growth theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton
go back to reference Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90(4):807–828CrossRef Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90(4):807–828CrossRef
go back to reference Hazan M (2009) Longevity and lifetime labour supply: evidence and implications. Econometrica 77(6):1829–1863CrossRef Hazan M (2009) Longevity and lifetime labour supply: evidence and implications. Econometrica 77(6):1829–1863CrossRef
go back to reference Hazan M, Zoabi H (2006) Does longevity cause growth? A theoretical critique. J Econ Growth 11(4): 363–376 Hazan M, Zoabi H (2006) Does longevity cause growth? A theoretical critique. J Econ Growth 11(4): 363–376
go back to reference Hongbin L, Zhang J, Zhang J (2007) Effects of longevity and dependency rates on saving and growth: evidence from a panel of cross countries. J Dev Econ 84(1):138–154CrossRef Hongbin L, Zhang J, Zhang J (2007) Effects of longevity and dependency rates on saving and growth: evidence from a panel of cross countries. J Dev Econ 84(1):138–154CrossRef
go back to reference Kalemli-Ozcan S (2003) A stochastic model of mortality, fertility, and human capital investment. J Dev Econ 70(1):103–118CrossRef Kalemli-Ozcan S (2003) A stochastic model of mortality, fertility, and human capital investment. J Dev Econ 70(1):103–118CrossRef
go back to reference Kalemli-Ozcan S (2009) The uncertain lifetime and the timing of human capital investment. J Popul Econ 21(4):557–572 Kalemli-Ozcan S (2009) The uncertain lifetime and the timing of human capital investment. J Popul Econ 21(4):557–572
go back to reference Kalemli-Ozcan S, Ryder HE, Weil DN (2000) Mortality decline human capital investment, and economic growth. J Dev Econ 62:1–23CrossRef Kalemli-Ozcan S, Ryder HE, Weil DN (2000) Mortality decline human capital investment, and economic growth. J Dev Econ 62:1–23CrossRef
go back to reference Kögel T, Prskawetz A (2001) Agricultural productivity growth and the escape from Malthusian trap. J Econ Growth 6:337–357CrossRef Kögel T, Prskawetz A (2001) Agricultural productivity growth and the escape from Malthusian trap. J Econ Growth 6:337–357CrossRef
go back to reference Lagerlöf NP (2003) From Malthus to modern growth: can epidemics explain the three regimes? Int Econ Rev 44(2):755–777CrossRef Lagerlöf NP (2003) From Malthus to modern growth: can epidemics explain the three regimes? Int Econ Rev 44(2):755–777CrossRef
go back to reference Lee R, Mason A (2010) Fertility human capital, and economic growth over the demographic transition. Eur J Popul 16:159–182CrossRef Lee R, Mason A (2010) Fertility human capital, and economic growth over the demographic transition. Eur J Popul 16:159–182CrossRef
go back to reference Livi-Bacci M (1992) A concise history of world population. Blackwell, Oxford Livi-Bacci M (1992) A concise history of world population. Blackwell, Oxford
go back to reference Lorentzen P, McMillan J, Wacziarg R (2008) Death and development. J Econ Growth 13(2):81–124CrossRef Lorentzen P, McMillan J, Wacziarg R (2008) Death and development. J Econ Growth 13(2):81–124CrossRef
go back to reference Lutz W, Goujon A, Sanderson W (2007) Reconstruction of population by age, sex, and level of education attainment of 120 countries for 1970–2000, Vienna yearbook of population research. IAASA, Vienna, pp 193–235 Lutz W, Goujon A, Sanderson W (2007) Reconstruction of population by age, sex, and level of education attainment of 120 countries for 1970–2000, Vienna yearbook of population research. IAASA, Vienna, pp 193–235
go back to reference Maddison A (2003) The world economy: historical statistics. OECD Development Centre, ParisCrossRef Maddison A (2003) The world economy: historical statistics. OECD Development Centre, ParisCrossRef
go back to reference Moav O (2005) Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Econ J 115:88–110CrossRef Moav O (2005) Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Econ J 115:88–110CrossRef
go back to reference Murtin F (2013) Long-term determinants of the demographic transition 1870–2000. Rev Econ Stat 95(2):617–631CrossRef Murtin F (2013) Long-term determinants of the demographic transition 1870–2000. Rev Econ Stat 95(2):617–631CrossRef
go back to reference Preston SH, Heuveline P, Guillot M (2001) Demography: measuring and modeling population processes. Blackwell, Oxford Preston SH, Heuveline P, Guillot M (2001) Demography: measuring and modeling population processes. Blackwell, Oxford
go back to reference Reher DS (2004) The demographic transition revisited as a global process. Popul Space Place 10(1):19–41CrossRef Reher DS (2004) The demographic transition revisited as a global process. Popul Space Place 10(1):19–41CrossRef
go back to reference Skirbekk V (2008) Fertility trends by social status. Demogr Res 18:145–180CrossRef Skirbekk V (2008) Fertility trends by social status. Demogr Res 18:145–180CrossRef
go back to reference Soares R (2005) Mortality reductions, educational attainment, and fertility choice. Am Econ Rev 95 (3):580–601 Soares R (2005) Mortality reductions, educational attainment, and fertility choice. Am Econ Rev 95 (3):580–601
go back to reference Zhang J, Zhang J (2005) The effect of life expectancy on fertility, saving, schooling and economic growth: theory and evidence. Scand J Econ 107(1):45–66CrossRef Zhang J, Zhang J (2005) The effect of life expectancy on fertility, saving, schooling and economic growth: theory and evidence. Scand J Econ 107(1):45–66CrossRef
Metadata
Title
The effect of life expectancy on education and population dynamics
Authors
Matteo Cervellati
Uwe Sunde
Publication date
01-06-2015
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Empirical Economics / Issue 4/2015
Print ISSN: 0377-7332
Electronic ISSN: 1435-8921
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0830-x

Other articles of this Issue 4/2015

Empirical Economics 4/2015 Go to the issue