2.1 Automation and job risk
Humans have always developed new and superior products and production technologies to satisfy new wants and needs and to produce greater economic output with less human effort. This is what is meant broadly by technological change, and it is a significant catalyst of long run economic growth (Romer
1990; Schumpeter
1942). In this context, the idea of computerisation, where job automation is by means of computer-controlled equipment (Frey and Osborne,
2017), is not new. New technologies (like computerisation) and new markets have replaced and generated new and more productive jobs and will continue to do so in the future (OECD
2018). Automation technologies have a long history, with inventions like the steam engine, electricity, mechanised weaving looms, industrial robots, or automated teller machines and more recently with information technologies (Acemoglu and Restrepo
2018). From this perspective, robots have been around for a long time.
As far back as Simon (
1965), the decline of routine jobs was predicted, where computers were argued to hold the comparative advantage in ‘routine’ rule-based activities which are easy to specify in computer code. Autor et al. (
2003) presented a simple model, referred to as the ALM model, of how the rapid adoption of computerisation by firms is changing the tasks performed by workers at their jobs, which in turn changes the market demand for human skills. For them, robots (machines) are substituting ‘routine’ tasks but will not substitute non-routine tasks that involve problem-solving, complex social and emotional communication activities and tacit knowledge. Non-routine tasks that cannot be substituted by automation are generally complemented by it (Autor
2015). Routine tasks are tasks that can follow explicit computerised code rules, and by way of simple contrast, non-routine tasks cannot be specified in a computer code (Frey and Osborne
2017). Autor (
2015) argues that the tasks that can be automatable are bounded by the limits of human knowledge and what he refers to as Polanyi’s paradox: Since humans ‘know more than they know they know’ (i.e. know things that are difficult to explain as a matter of codified, programmable steps), there are limits to the substitutability of human tasks. Consequently, there will always be a division of ‘human tasks’ and ‘machine tasks’.
Susskind and Susskind (
2015) have identified key weaknesses of the theoretical ALM model, where tasks that were considered ‘non-routine’ in the ALM task-based literature have already become ‘routine’, due to technological changes leading to the likelihood of a more dramatic job displacement reality, from current modern computerised technologies. Big data and artificial intelligence are progressing at incredible speed. Susskind and Susskind (
2015) observations pre-empted the findings of Frey and Osborne (
2017), who identified the scope of jobs that could be automatable in the future. Frey and Osborne (
2017) identified that 47% of jobs in the USA are susceptible to automation, at some unspecified time in the future. They argue their estimate also aligns closely to the extent of job displacement that has happened in the past. For instance, in 1900, 40% of the US workforce was employed in agriculture. Now it is less than 2%.
In general, the grave concern of technological unemployment from theorists such as Keynes (
2010) has been unfounded. The process of creative destruction has led to as many new jobs being created in new sectors, as destroyed in traditional sectors. Hence, jobs lost were replaced, with often better paid, more highly skilled jobs in their place. Despite the unfounded unemployment concerns of the past, automation still created widespread disruption with a greater polarisation in jobs and incomes, as technologies (robots and algorithms) replaced, middle-skilled (in particular) people based-routines (OECD
2018). And future disruption is predicted. Schwab (
2016) reflecting on the fourth industrial revolution, at the economic summit in Davos stated ‘We stand on the brink of a technological revolution that will fundamentally alter the way we live, work, and relate to one another. In its scale, scope, and complexity, the transformation will be unlike anything humankind has experienced before’.
2.2 The economic geography of job risk and automation
Job polarisation and technological unemployment are often the most discussed adjustment concerns raised around automation and the rise of artificial intelligence. But an often-overlooked implication and, possibly a greater problem, is the displacement to places created by technological change. The past century has resulted in a large migration of people from rural to urban areas. By 2050, Eurostat (
2016) predicts that about 80 per cent of the European population will be living in urban areas.
Urban theorists argue that agglomerations are intellectual breeding grounds for new ideas and innovations (Jacobs
1969; Marshall
1890). The geographical proximity between economic actors helps foster, facilitate and nurture face to face interaction, the flow of local knowledge, ideas and innovations (McCann and Shefer
2005: 302). In theoretical approaches to knowledge flows and innovation, it is assumed that it is easier for knowledge to transfer over shorter distances than longer distances, or as Glaeser et al. (
1992: 1126) put it, ‘intellectual breakthroughs must cross hallways and streets more easily than oceans and continents’. Given the spikey distribution of prosperity around the world, between countries and within countries, the importance of ‘place’ in contributing to economic growth has been a central research topic (Florida
2005).
From the literature, it is apparent that urban areas play a critical role as creative and intellectual spaces (Frank et al.
2018). The ‘tolerant’ and ‘bohemian’ nature (Florida
2005); the creative spill-overs that are ‘in the air’ (Marshall
1890); dense diversity (Jacobs
1969); and the creative ‘buzz’ (Storper and Venables
2004) in urban areas drive innovation resulting in ‘swarms of creative clusters’ to emerge in global and capital cities (Chapain et al.
2010). Florida’s thesis outlines that the disparity in the creative class across cities is driving the disparity in innovation and productivity outcomes across space. Educated, creative, more highly skilled people are migrating to urban areas to exploit amenities, higher wages and employment opportunities in favourable business environments (Moretti
2012; Florida et al.
2011; Marlet and van Woerkens
2007). Patterns of human capital accumulation are following a self-propelling process, where well-educated individuals are attracted to areas that already are concentrated with well-educated individuals (Waldorf
2009). Consequently, ‘superstar’ agglomerations are providing an enhanced ecosystem to drive novel combinations of knowledge and ideas which are further compounding previous geographical divides between regions (Iammarino et al.
2018) and urban and rural areas (Moretti
2012; Rosenthal and Strange
2004) through time.
The shift from manufacturing to predominantly service driven economies has made geographical proximity matter more, resulting in increased divergence between places (Moretti
2012). There is also strong evidence that digital technologies are resulting in greater divisions between large and small urban areas (Muro
2019; Frank et al.
2018). In general, urban areas with a more critical mass are more productive (Melo et al.
2017; Coulibaly et al.
2008), more innovative (Carlino et al. 2007), more accessible to industries and anchor institutions (Hamidi and Zandiatashbar
2019) offer more job opportunities (Hendrickson et al.
2018) and higher wages (Wang
2016; Echeverri-Carroll and Ayala
2011).
But it is also not just a story of ‘large’ versus ‘small’ and ‘leaders’ versus ‘laggards’—a much more complex geographical landscape is emerging with brain hubs, declining manufacturing cities and a number of cities that could thrive or decline (Moretti
2012). The reality of shrinking urban areas is not a recent phenomenon (O’Driscoll et al.
2022; Wolff and Wiechmann
2018). It is suggested that economic stagnation resulting from a decline of economic and social opportunities in smaller cities, declining regions and rural areas, was the force behind recent populist voting patterns in the USA (Hendrickson et al.
2018; Frey et al.
2017; Shearer
2016), in France, Germany and the UK (Rodríguez-Pose
2018; Dijkstra et al.
2018; Ballas et al.
2017). In response, many are calling for new frameworks, strategies and policies to tackle the concerns of lagging areas (Rodríguez-Pose
2018; Shambaugh and Nunn
2018; Storper
2018; Iammarino et al.
2018).
This regional disparity may be exacerbated and intensified by an uneven spread of automation risk. Indeed, the aggregate number of jobs at high risk of automation at a national level hides the sub-national regional variation of job exposure. Automation is predicted to have a different impact across regions (OECD
2019). The share of jobs at high risk of automation across OECD defined territorial level 2 regions varies considerably from a low of 4% to a high of 40% (OECD
2018). It is also predicted that automation will result in improved welfare (particularly for better educated workers) in leading regions, and losses in welfare (particularly for lower educated workers) in lagging regions, as production will shift to locations with higher wages and skills, due to more efficient capital over time (Lecca et al.
2018). Indeed, Okamoto (
2019) identified that individuals relocate to states with more automation in skilled occupations and less automation in unskilled occupations, demonstrating that automation has a complementary effect on skilled occupations and a substitution effect on unskilled occupations. In effect, if the adoption of present and future automated technologies is rapid, and new firms in new technological industries follow the similar past trends of high knowledge-based firms, by spatial clustering, by locating around successful cities, talent and centres of learning and research (Florida et al.
2011; Venables
2010; Berry and Glaeser
2005; Florida
2005), then it is inevitable that future automation disruptions will further exacerbate regional and local disparities. Present trends in the area of artificial intelligence suggest that the industry is already following a clustering and localised co-location pattern (Klinger et al.
2018). Barzotto and De Propris (
2021) identified that firms which collaborate with local suppliers of enabling technologies linked to industry 4.0 have improved levels of performance.
So far, the extent of the automation job risk literature has focused on the level of national exposure (Frey and Osborne
2017), European regional territorial level 2 exposure (Crowley et al.
2021; OECD
2018; Arntz et al.
2016) or US county and city-level exposure (Muro
2019; Frank et al.
2018). While the OECD (
2018) and Crowley et al. (
2021) papers are significant steps in assessing the job exposure to automation across different regions, such (regional territorial level 2) defined boundaries are unlikely to identify deeper local labour market areas in the European case (Coombes
1995). It is common across countries for development plans and policies to transcend across many different levels of government, and it is typical to have a combination of local, regional and/or national intervention programmes for economic development (OECD
2016a,
2018). Consequently, it is important to have a competent empirical understanding of local labour market dynamics (Leigh and Kraft
2018). This paper focuses specifically on ensuring a deeper disaggregated regionalisation of automation job exposure to urban settlements in Ireland to get a better understanding of the localised automated job risk exposure across Ireland.