Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 3-4/2021

25-10-2019

The role of ECB communication in guiding markets

Authors: Marc Anderes, Alexander Rathke, Sina Streicher, Jan-Egbert Sturm

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 3-4/2021

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Economists and central bankers nowadays believe that forward guidance has become more important in a world in which key interest rates have hit their effective lower bounds (ELB). In the case of the European Central Bank (ECB), forward guidance should have increased the informational content of the introductory statements at the press conferences following ECB policy meetings. We examine whether such ECB communication adds information to a shadow interest rate that summarizes the overall policy stance as interpreted by financial markets. To measure communication, we use information based on ECB press releases distinguishing between topics like inflation, the real economy and monetary developments. We also look at the effect of communication on consensus expectations about key macroeconomic variables. The ECB’s assessment of the economy, i.e., communication related to economic growth, triggers movements in financial markets and thereby the shadow rate. Communication of the ECB through its press releases also causes professional forecasters to change their outlooks. Not only are their growth forecasts affected, but so are their expectations for M3 growth and inflation.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
In a survey conducted by Blinder et al. (2017), more than half of the responding central bank governors say that new communication measures have been adopted at their institution since the crisis. Moreover, the overwhelming majority (more than 80%) of central bankers and academic economists (more than 90%) stated that the role of central bank communication has intensified. Both the majority of central bankers (60%) and academic economists (75%) expect communication policy changes to remain in place, or to go even further (Blinder et al. 2017).
 
2
As stated by Hartmann and Smets (2018, p. 4), “the need for additional communication in a complex (non-standard) policy environment rose and forward guidance became an essential tool for easing policy in a low interest rate context”.
 
3
See, for instance, Jones (2014). For a critical view on unconventional policies, see Borio and Gambacorta (2017).
 
4
For a comprehensive treatment see, Hartmann and Smets (2018).
 
5
Regular longer-term refinancing operations (LTRO) have maturities of three months. The VLTROS had a maturity of 36 months and were conducted as fixed rate full allotment procedures. They were accompanied by a reduction in the required reserve ratio from 2 to 1% and an increase collateral availability by broadening the definition of eligible assets.
 
6
The idea dates back to Black (1995), who argued that when interest rates reach the zero lower bound, people would prefer to hold cash rather than financial instruments generating negative interest.
 
7
The data produced by Leo Krippner can be accessed through the website of the Reserve Bank of New Zealand: https://​www.​rbnz.​govt.​nz/​research-and-publications/​research-programme/​additional-research/​measures-of-the-stance-of-united-states-monetary-policy/​comparison-of-international-monetary-policy-measures. In order to cope with the non-linearity introduced by the option effect, Krippner applies an Iterated Extended Kalman Filter for the estimation. He uses German and French zero government bond rates and overnight indexed swap rates (once they become available for the euro area in 2008) with maturities of 0.25, 0.5, 1, 2, 3, 5, 10 and 30 years to approximate the euro yield curve. For comparison, Krippner sets the ELB to 12.5 basis points across all estimated currencies. McCoy and Clemens (2017) analyze the effect of the choice of the effective lower bound in Krippner’s shadow rate model estimation and give an illustrative example. They point out that, the higher the ELB is set, the more pronounced is the option effect, implying that the shadow yield curve (and, thus, the shadow rate) is shifted downwards. Hence, a trade-off exists between a meaningful monetary policy stance indicator and an economically relevant policy rate estimate. In our analysis, we use the shadow rate as a proxy for the stance of monetary policy and, therefore, are not concerned with the relatively high lower bound of 12.5 basis points.
 
8
The weight for the forecast of the current year is \( m/12 \) and the weight for the forecast of the following year is \( \left( {12 - m} \right)/12 \), where \( m \) denotes the number of remaining months in the current year. As the survey usually is published in the first half of the month, we assign the current month to the remaining months of the year.
 
9
Using nominal GDP weighted averages from the euro area member states to construct expectations that go back to January 1999 does not change the conclusions. However, as money growth expectations are not available at the member state level, we would lose information by going back that far.
 
10
The database can be accessed through https://​sdw.​ecb.​europa.​eu/​browse.​do?​node=​9689716. The first vintages of the for-us relevant variables published in that real-time database date from January 2001.
 
11
The benchmark revisions took place early March 2002, June 2002, March 2003, May 2005, March 2011 and March 2016.
 
12
The way in which our indicators are constructed very much follows the procedure underlying the so-called KOF Monetary Policy Communicator (MPC), as published by the KOF Swiss Economic Institute and used, e.g., by Sturm and de Haan (2011), Conrad and Lamla (2010), Lamla and Sturm (2013), Bulíř et al. (2013) and Neuenkirch (2013). The key difference is that the MPC is a leading indicator for monetary policy and therefore considers only forward-looking statements regarding prices.
 
13
While most of the data we use are proprietary and cannot be shared publicly, we are happy to provide our communication data upon request.
 
14
The Euribor 3-month futures contracts have expiry dates on the 3rd Wednesdays of each of the following six months and at quarterly frequencies for longer horizons. Each contract can be traded until two days before the expiry date, meaning we do not have a natural series of future prices. We use an end-of-day series that represents the future contract that expires next and can still be traded. That series may contain price jumps once a month, exactly two days prior to the expiry dates. Owing to the timing of the ECB Governing Council meeting days, those jumps do not affect our market surprise measure.
 
15
We have also experimented with the US dollar-euro exchange rate. The conclusions are not affected by that alternative.
 
16
The change in the shadow rate and the change in the main refinancing rate are not correlated in this table because it takes up to 6 days for the main refinancing rate effectively to be changed after having been announced publicly by the ECB. By that time, the shadow rate already has adapted.
 
17
The effective change in the MRR usually takes place six days after it was announced publicly. Since financial markets incorporate the announced change in the MRR immediately, we use the decided change in MRR in the subsequent analyses.
 
18
Including each of these communication variables separately does not change the conclusion: only communication on the economy is significant in explaining the change in the shadow rate. Given the low correlation between those indicators, that was to be expected (see Table 2).
 
19
All results in Table 3 are based upon those days in which a Governing Council meeting has taken place and a monetary policy press release has been published. If we move to a daily frequency, increasing the size of the sample to 5724 observations, the significance of the variables increases, while no significant changes in signs are recorded.
 
20
A general-to-specific methodology means dropping insignificant variables one at a time until all variables remaining in the model are significant.
 
21
We have furthermore carried out a placebo test in which the dependent variable has been moved to another arbitrary date and find that in general all variables become insignificant.
 
22
Standardized beta coefficients are shown in Table A.1 in the online appendix.
 
23
Hence, we use phase 2 as our baseline. As noted, phase 1, owing to data limitations, is not included in our sample. Similar analyses have been carried out for the other columns in Table 3. The conclusions are not affected.
 
24
This time, however, we are working with what boils down to a monthly frequency that did not change over time.
 
25
An illustration of the timing of the model can be found in Figure A.2 in the online appendix.
 
26
Note that it did not make much sense to include this variable in our first model when we looked at the changes between the day before and the day after the Governing Council meeting. In such a short time frame, including it always resulted in insignificant coefficient estimates.
 
27
Since the Great Financial Crisis, the variable takes on non-zero values. Hence, it covers only the last two monetary policy phases of our sample, i.e., 2008m9-2014m5 and 2014m6-2018m12.
 
28
The correlation between the residuals of the inflation and GDP growth equations is the highest and equals 0.27.
 
29
Table A.2 in the online appendix reports standardized coefficients of the results presented in Table 7, allowing for a direct comparison of the quantitative importances of each of the explanatory variables.
 
Literature
go back to reference Berger, H., de Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (2011). Does money matter in the ECB strategy? New evidence based on ECB communication. International Journal of Finance and Economics, 16, 16–31.CrossRef Berger, H., de Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (2011). Does money matter in the ECB strategy? New evidence based on ECB communication. International Journal of Finance and Economics, 16, 16–31.CrossRef
go back to reference Bernholz, P. (2015). Monetary regimes and inflation history, economic and political relationships (2nd ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Bernholz, P. (2015). Monetary regimes and inflation history, economic and political relationships (2nd ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
go back to reference Bernoth, K., & von Hagen, J. (2004). The Euribor futures market: Efficiency and the impact of ECB policy announcements. International Finance, 7(1), 1–24.CrossRef Bernoth, K., & von Hagen, J. (2004). The Euribor futures market: Efficiency and the impact of ECB policy announcements. International Finance, 7(1), 1–24.CrossRef
go back to reference Black, F. (1995). Interest rates as options. Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1371–1376.CrossRef Black, F. (1995). Interest rates as options. Journal of Finance, 50(5), 1371–1376.CrossRef
go back to reference Blinder, A., Ehrmann, M., Fratzscher, M., de Haan, J., & Jansen, D.-J. (2008). Central bank communication and monetary policy: A survey of theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(4), 910–945.CrossRef Blinder, A., Ehrmann, M., Fratzscher, M., de Haan, J., & Jansen, D.-J. (2008). Central bank communication and monetary policy: A survey of theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Literature, 46(4), 910–945.CrossRef
go back to reference Borio, C., & Gambacorta, L. (2017). Monetary policy and bank lending in a low interest rate environment: Diminishing effectiveness? Journal of Macroeconomics, 54, 217–231.CrossRef Borio, C., & Gambacorta, L. (2017). Monetary policy and bank lending in a low interest rate environment: Diminishing effectiveness? Journal of Macroeconomics, 54, 217–231.CrossRef
go back to reference Brand, C., Buncic, D., & Turunen, J. (2010). The impact of ECB monetary policy decisions and communication on the yield curve. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(6), 1266–1298.CrossRef Brand, C., Buncic, D., & Turunen, J. (2010). The impact of ECB monetary policy decisions and communication on the yield curve. Journal of the European Economic Association, 8(6), 1266–1298.CrossRef
go back to reference Bredin, D., Hyde, S., & Reilly, G. O. (2010). Monetary policy surprises and international bond markets. Journal of International Money and Finance, 29(6), 988–1002.CrossRef Bredin, D., Hyde, S., & Reilly, G. O. (2010). Monetary policy surprises and international bond markets. Journal of International Money and Finance, 29(6), 988–1002.CrossRef
go back to reference Bulíř, A., Čihák, M., & Jansen, D. J. (2013). What drives clarity of central bank communication about inflation? Open Economies Review, 24(1), 125–145.CrossRef Bulíř, A., Čihák, M., & Jansen, D. J. (2013). What drives clarity of central bank communication about inflation? Open Economies Review, 24(1), 125–145.CrossRef
go back to reference Cochrane, J. H., John, B. T., & Wieland V. (2019). Evaluating rules in the Fed’s report and measuring discretion. Mimeo. Cochrane, J. H., John, B. T., & Wieland V. (2019). Evaluating rules in the Fed’s report and measuring discretion. Mimeo.
go back to reference Coenen, G., Ehrmann, M., Gaballo, G., Hoffmann, P., Nakov, A., Nardelli, S., Persson, E., & Strasser, G. (2017). Communication of monetary policy in unconventional times. ECB Working Paper No. 2080. Coenen, G., Ehrmann, M., Gaballo, G., Hoffmann, P., Nakov, A., Nardelli, S., Persson, E., & Strasser, G. (2017). Communication of monetary policy in unconventional times. ECB Working Paper No. 2080.
go back to reference Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y., Kueng, L., & Silvia, J. (2017). Innocent bystanders? Monetary policy and inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 88, 70–89.CrossRef Coibion, O., Gorodnichenko, Y., Kueng, L., & Silvia, J. (2017). Innocent bystanders? Monetary policy and inequality. Journal of Monetary Economics, 88, 70–89.CrossRef
go back to reference Conrad, C., & Lamla, M. J. (2010). The high-frequency response of the EUR-USD exchange rate to ECB communication. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(7), 1391–1417.CrossRef Conrad, C., & Lamla, M. J. (2010). The high-frequency response of the EUR-USD exchange rate to ECB communication. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(7), 1391–1417.CrossRef
go back to reference Constâncio, V. (2018). Past and future of the ECB monetary policy. In Speech at the conference on “central banks in historical perspective: What changed after the financial crisis”, organised by the Central Bank of Malta, Valletta, 4 May 2018. Constâncio, V. (2018). Past and future of the ECB monetary policy. In Speech at the conference on “central banks in historical perspective: What changed after the financial crisis”, organised by the Central Bank of Malta, Valletta, 4 May 2018.
go back to reference De Haan, J. (2008). The effect of ECB communication on interest rates: An assessment. Review of International Organizations, 3(4), 375–398.CrossRef De Haan, J. (2008). The effect of ECB communication on interest rates: An assessment. Review of International Organizations, 3(4), 375–398.CrossRef
go back to reference De Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (2019). Central bank communication – how to manage expectations? In D. G. Mayes, P. L. Siklos, & J.-E. Sturm (Eds.) The Oxford handbook of the economics of central banking, (pp. 231–262). Oxford: Oxford University Press, Chapter 8 De Haan, J., & Sturm, J.-E. (2019). Central bank communication – how to manage expectations? In D. G. Mayes, P. L. Siklos, & J.-E. Sturm (Eds.) The Oxford handbook of the economics of central banking, (pp. 231–262). Oxford: Oxford University Press, Chapter 8
go back to reference Ehrmann, M., & Fratzscher, M. (2013). Dispersed communication by central bank committees and the predictability of monetary policy decisions. Public Choice, 157(1–2), 223–244.CrossRef Ehrmann, M., & Fratzscher, M. (2013). Dispersed communication by central bank committees and the predictability of monetary policy decisions. Public Choice, 157(1–2), 223–244.CrossRef
go back to reference Fausch, J., & Sigonius, M. (2018). The impact of ECB monetary policy surprises on the German stock market. Journal of Macroeconomics, 55, 46–63.CrossRef Fausch, J., & Sigonius, M. (2018). The impact of ECB monetary policy surprises on the German stock market. Journal of Macroeconomics, 55, 46–63.CrossRef
go back to reference Friedman, M. (1970). The counter-revolution in monetary theory. Institute of Economic Affairs Occasional Paper No 33, London. Friedman, M. (1970). The counter-revolution in monetary theory. Institute of Economic Affairs Occasional Paper No 33, London.
go back to reference Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. (1963). A monetary history of the United States. 1867–1960. Princeton University Press: Princeton. Friedman, M., & Schwartz, A. (1963). A monetary history of the United States. 1867–1960. Princeton University Press: Princeton.
go back to reference Galardo, M., & Guerrieri, C. (2017). The effects of central bank’s verbal guidance: evidence from the ECB. Bank of Italy Working Papers No. 1129, July 2017. Galardo, M., & Guerrieri, C. (2017). The effects of central bank’s verbal guidance: evidence from the ECB. Bank of Italy Working Papers No. 1129, July 2017.
go back to reference Grothe, M., & Meyler, A. (2015). Inflation forecasts: are marked-based and survey-based measures informative? ECB Working Paper No. 1865, November 2015. Grothe, M., & Meyler, A. (2015). Inflation forecasts: are marked-based and survey-based measures informative? ECB Working Paper No. 1865, November 2015.
go back to reference Hartmann, P., & Smets, F. (2018). The first twenty years of the European Central Bank: monetary policy. ECB Working Paper Series No 2219, December 2018. Hartmann, P., & Smets, F. (2018). The first twenty years of the European Central Bank: monetary policy. ECB Working Paper Series No 2219, December 2018.
go back to reference Inui, M., Sudo, N., & Yamada, T. (2017). Effects of monetary policy shocks on inequality in Japan. Bank of Japan Working Paper Series 17-E-3. Inui, M., Sudo, N., & Yamada, T. (2017). Effects of monetary policy shocks on inequality in Japan. Bank of Japan Working Paper Series 17-E-3.
go back to reference Krippner, L. (2013a). Measuring the stance of monetary policy in zero lower bound environments. Economics Letters, 118(1), 135–138.CrossRef Krippner, L. (2013a). Measuring the stance of monetary policy in zero lower bound environments. Economics Letters, 118(1), 135–138.CrossRef
go back to reference Krippner, L. (2013b). A tractable framework for zero lower bound Gaussian term structure models. CAMA Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Working Paper No. 49. Krippner, L. (2013b). A tractable framework for zero lower bound Gaussian term structure models. CAMA Centre for Applied Macroeconomic Analysis Working Paper No. 49.
go back to reference Krippner, L. (2015). Zero lower bound term structure modeling: A practitioner’s guide. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US.CrossRef Krippner, L. (2015). Zero lower bound term structure modeling: A practitioner’s guide. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US.CrossRef
go back to reference Lamla, M. L., & Sturm, J.-E. (2013). Interest rate expectations in the media and central bank communication. In Central Bank Communication, Decision Making, and Governance, editors P. L. Siklos and J.-E. Sturm, MIT Press, Chapter, 5, 101–111. Lamla, M. L., & Sturm, J.-E. (2013). Interest rate expectations in the media and central bank communication. In Central Bank Communication, Decision Making, and Governance, editors P. L. Siklos and J.-E. Sturm, MIT Press, Chapter, 5, 101–111.
go back to reference McCoy, E. and Clemens, U. (2017). A calibration of the shadow rate to the euro area using genetic algorithms. ECB Discussion Paper No. 51, July 2017. McCoy, E. and Clemens, U. (2017). A calibration of the shadow rate to the euro area using genetic algorithms. ECB Discussion Paper No. 51, July 2017.
go back to reference Mumtaz, M., & Theophilopoulou, A. (2017). The impact of monetary policy on inequality in the UK. An empirical analysis. European Economic Review, 98, 410–423.CrossRef Mumtaz, M., & Theophilopoulou, A. (2017). The impact of monetary policy on inequality in the UK. An empirical analysis. European Economic Review, 98, 410–423.CrossRef
go back to reference Neuenkirch, M. (2013). Monetary policy transmission in vector autoregressions: a new approach using central bank communication. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(11), 4278–4285.CrossRef Neuenkirch, M. (2013). Monetary policy transmission in vector autoregressions: a new approach using central bank communication. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(11), 4278–4285.CrossRef
go back to reference Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, A., Papell, D. H., & Prodan, R. (2014). Deviations from rulesbased policy and their effects. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 49, 4–17.CrossRef Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy, A., Papell, D. H., & Prodan, R. (2014). Deviations from rulesbased policy and their effects. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 49, 4–17.CrossRef
go back to reference Sturm, J.-E., & de Haan, J. (2011). Does central bank communication really lead to better forecasts of policy decisions? New evidence based on a Taylor rule model for the ECB. Review of World Economics, 147(1), 41–58.CrossRef Sturm, J.-E., & de Haan, J. (2011). Does central bank communication really lead to better forecasts of policy decisions? New evidence based on a Taylor rule model for the ECB. Review of World Economics, 147(1), 41–58.CrossRef
go back to reference Swanson, E.T. (2017). Measuring the effects of Federal Reserve forward guidance and asset purchases on financial markets. NBER Working Paper No. 23311. Swanson, E.T. (2017). Measuring the effects of Federal Reserve forward guidance and asset purchases on financial markets. NBER Working Paper No. 23311.
go back to reference Ullrich, K. (2008). Inflation expectations of experts and ECB communication. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 19(1), 93–108.CrossRef Ullrich, K. (2008). Inflation expectations of experts and ECB communication. The North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 19(1), 93–108.CrossRef
go back to reference Van der Cruijsen, C., & Demertzis, M. (2007). The impact of central bank transparency on inflation expectations. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(1), 51–66.CrossRef Van der Cruijsen, C., & Demertzis, M. (2007). The impact of central bank transparency on inflation expectations. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(1), 51–66.CrossRef
go back to reference Woodford, M. (2001). Monetary policy in the information economy. In Economic Policy for the Information Economy. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 297–370. Woodford, M. (2001). Monetary policy in the information economy. In Economic Policy for the Information Economy. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 297–370.
go back to reference Wu, J. C., & Xia, F. D. (2016). Measuring the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 48(2–3), 253–291.CrossRef Wu, J. C., & Xia, F. D. (2016). Measuring the macroeconomic impact of monetary policy at the zero lower bound. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 48(2–3), 253–291.CrossRef
Metadata
Title
The role of ECB communication in guiding markets
Authors
Marc Anderes
Alexander Rathke
Sina Streicher
Jan-Egbert Sturm
Publication date
25-10-2019
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 3-4/2021
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-019-00733-0

Other articles of this Issue 3-4/2021

Public Choice 3-4/2021 Go to the issue