Skip to main content
Top

2010 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

4. The Struggling Masses

Perfect Competition at Two Places

Author : John R. Miron

Published in: The Geography of Competition

Publisher: Springer New York

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Two places, in isolation from the rest of the world, each meet the requirements of a perfectly competitive market. In Model 4A, the unit shipping cost is prohibitive. Each place is in autarky. Price locally reflects only local demand and local supply. However, if the unit shipping cost is low, arbitrageurs purchase where price is low for resale at the other place. In Model 4B, unit shipping cost is zero everywhere, and there is a common equilibrium price at the two places. A change in any parameter of local demand or local supply at either place can affect this price. In Model 4C, shipping cost is neither prohibitive nor zero. Here, shipping occurs up the price gradient. Because of the actions of arbitrageurs, the price difference between the two places shrinks to the unit shipping cost. Corner solutions—in which either demand or supply drops to zero in one or the other of the two places—are solved and interpreted. The models in this chapter are the competitive market equivalent of the models of a monopolist in Chapter 2. However, as in Chapter 3, congestion in production means that unit cost rises the more output the industry produces. Usually, we imagine that competition causes excess profit to disappear. However, the notion of congestion (an upward sloped supply curve) here in Chapter 4 means that some producers are less efficient than others. More efficient suppliers earn a monopoly profit even in competitive markets. In this chapter, localization of production, prices (one for each place), and excess profit (for all but the marginal producer) are joint outcomes of a competitive market.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
In a region, the supply of a product by firms from local production. Local supply does not include supply offered by arbitrageurs importing from another region.
 
2
An attribute of a market wherein each supplier and each demander is a price taker.
 
3
A schedule showing the marginal cost to an industry (usually over the longer run where capital invested adjusts as needed) as a function of the quantity to be supplied. The market supply curve is thought to be the same as the industry marginal cost curve. We can measure the industry marginal cost curve over either the short run (no additional competitors or factories) or the long run (additional competitors and/or factories possible).
 
4
In the case of multiple places, a condition in which arbitrageurs have no further incentive to purchase in a low-price market for resale in a high-price market.
 
5
See Cournot (1960, chap 10).
 
6
Early writers in the field also mention an unpublished paper by William Baumol—dated 1952 and entitled Spatial Equilibrium With Supply Points Separated From Markets and Supplies Predetermined—that might be similar to Samuelson (1952).
 
7
A supply function is generally expressed as a schedule of quantity supplied (Q) at various prices (P): i.e., \(Q = g[ P ]\). An inverse demand function rearranges this as the price needed by suppliers at the margin in order to ensure that a given quantity is supplied to the market: i.e., \(P = g^{-1} [ Q ]\).
 
8
See (4.1.2) for Place 1.
 
9
Over the short term, the firm is not able to adjust its capital stock. In the short term, therefore, the firm’s marginal cost rises as it attempts to increase the level of production, as the firm encounters congestion and capacity limitations. Of course, this is not what happens in Chapter 2 where I assumed marginal cost is constant; the unlimited wellspring assumption allowed us to ignore questions about the relationship between output and capital stock.
 
10
A condition under which a market participant (supplier or demander) is unable to affect the price they receive or pay for a unit of the product by varying the quantity that they supply or demand. The supplier (demander) sees the demand (supply) for its product as horizontal: i.e., infinitely elastic at the given market price.
 
11
This is different from the case of the monopolist in Chapter 2 where, in the case of a single market, price was not affected by market size: see (2.1.5).
 
12
Here, I can approximate the condition of constant marginal costs by letting δ 1 approach zero. In that case as noted above, (3.2.3) implies P 1 approaches C 1, and market size indeed no longer affects price in a perfectly competitive market.
 
13
To the extent that population adjusts so as enable each resident to be best off, N 1 may also be shaped by prices. I do not pursue that idea further here. See Chapters 11 and 12.
 
14
See Anderson and Ginsburgh (1999) for an analysis of the case where the cost of arbitrage is different between firms and consumers.
 
15
A condition of two places arising when the cost of shipping product from one market to the other is zero.
 
16
In a market at a given price P, excess supply is the amount if any by which local supply exceeds local demand. Local here excludes demand or supply by arbitrageurs.
 
17
In a market at a given price P, excess demand is the amount, if any, by which local demand exceeds local supply. Local here excludes demand or supply by arbitrageurs.
 
18
As in Chapter 2, I assume here no congestion over the shipping network. The firm can ship as much, or as little, as it likes for the same unit cost sx.
 
19
In a two-region model of trade, the Price Difference Curve shows the amount of the good shipped from the lower priced to the higher priced region that would result in a given difference in prices between the two regions. Calculated as the vertical difference between the excess supply curve in the lower price region and the excess demand curve in the higher price region. In this text, I refer to this derivation as the Samuelson Model. There are variants of this approach that are essentially the same: see Siebert (1969, pp. 85–87) or Takayama and Judge (1971, pp. 135–137).
 
20
Early writers largely ignored this. Enke (1951, p. 42), for example, assumes that excess supply will always be linear in price, not piecewise linear as argued here. Samuelson (1952, pp. 286 and 288) draws excess supply curves and a price difference curve that are also kinked. However, Samuelson also draws local demand and supply curves that are kinked without any explanation and does not draw the kinks in the excess supply curves or price difference curves to correspond to situations, where either local demand or local supply have been driven to zero. Takayama and Judge (1971, p. 135) do incorporate corner solutions that arise because of kinks, but refer to such solutions as irregular.
 
Metadata
Title
The Struggling Masses
Author
John R. Miron
Copyright Year
2010
Publisher
Springer New York
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-4419-5626-2_4