Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Public Choice 1-2/2014

01-04-2014

The welfare state, migration, and voting rights

Author: Christine Fauvelle-Aymar

Published in: Public Choice | Issue 1-2/2014

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This paper proposes a political economic analysis of public opinion in European Union countries toward migrants from poor countries. By focusing on redistributive policy, the analysis sheds light on specific determinants of public opinion. The theoretical analysis, based on the median voter framework, shows that one of the key variables affecting public opinion is the voting rights of migrants. Where migrants do not have the right to vote, their presence negatively impacts the poorest natives. In countries where migrants enjoy voting rights, they are able to vote on redistributive policy; therefore, the impact of migration on natives’ welfare is fundamentally different. After the theoretical analysis, the paper proposes an empirical analysis of Europeans’ attitudes toward non-Western migrants in European Union countries. This empirical analysis confirms the decisive impact of migrants’ voting rights. It shows that, in EU countries, the more educated natives are significantly less favorable to migrants from poor countries when the latter have the right to vote.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
About 60 % of foreigners in Europe are citizens of non-Western countries (Vasileva 2011).
 
2
See Friedberg and Jennifer (1995), Kerr and Kerr (2011) and Okkerse (2008).
 
3
For a formal model of the determinant of opinion toward migrants based on this hypothesis, see Söllner (1999).
 
4
The impact of migrants on labor market is, however, not totally disregarded in this study since the characteristics of the labor market are introduced, as control variables, in the empirical analysis.
 
5
More generally, the literature on immigration policy is beyond the scope of this article. On this question, see, for instance, Thum (2004), Powell (2012) and Scheve and Slaughter (2001).
 
6
Many analyses demonstrate that migration may help to ease the financial constraints on the public pension schemes of ageing countries; see, for instance, Rother et al. (2003).
 
7
In 2000, nearly 80 % of migrants arriving in the EU did not have a tertiary level of education (Docquier et al. 2007). Moreover, even for a given skill level, the situation of migrants in the labor market is less favorable than that of natives, as a result of a combination of discriminatory practices and the current situation in the European labor market (Peracchi and Depalo 2006).
 
8
Practically, this direct effect is not immediate but comes when migrants have acquired the right to vote. Contrary to social rights, voting rights to non-EU citizens are not granted on arrival. More or less restrictive conditions involving length of residence apply in all countries before a migrant can enjoy voting rights.
 
9
For an interesting formal presentation, see Mayr (2007).
 
10
That was also the case during the transition to universal suffrage. See more on this issue below.
 
11
Along the highly debated Borjas’ welfare magnets hypothesis (Borjas 1999). On this debate, see, for instance, the survey by Nannestad (2007).
 
12
In this paper, I only consider the political influence that migrants can exercise through their voting rights. In reality, migrants can use other mechanisms to influence public decisions, such as participating in pressure groups and in particular trade unions. In any case, these actions can only increase their influence on public policies and thus amplify the consequences examined in this paper. For such an approach, see Mazza and Winden (1996).
 
13
This is the case only for citizens of the Commonwealth countries. Other migrants are not allowed to vote.
 
14
The survey used in the empirical study was conducted in 2002–2003 when there were 15 member states. Luxembourg has been excluded from the analysis for the reasons explained below.
 
15
These surveys have been conducted in the major European countries (members or not of the EU) since 2002. Funded by research programs of the European Commission and the “European Science Foundation”, they are presented on the website www.​europeansocialsu​rvey.​org.
 
16
The exact number depends on the country’s size and on the survey response rate.
 
17
As explained above, the value of the dependent variable is higher when people are more favorable to the arrival of migrants.
 
18
This issue is discussed above.
 
19
These other situations include logically the situation where the respondent is working but also all situations in which he/she does not belong to the labor force, owing, for instance, to being retired or pursuing additional years of schooling.
 
20
In order to calculate the exact number of migrants, we need to have the nationality at birth. The survey provides information on respondents’ nationality only at the time of the survey. Therefore migrants who have acquired the nationality of their host country since their arrival cannot be identified.
 
21
I refer here to the question of the transition to universal suffrage because there seems to be no theoretical analysis of the extension of voting rights to foreigners.
 
22
This argument is discussed by Acemoglu and Robinson (2000).
 
23
The source of the unemployment rate and of “the size of the foreign population” variable presented below is the Eurostat database available online.
 
24
The recent literature on ethnic conflicts suggests that violent conflicts are more likely to happen when a nation is divided into two groups of roughly equal size than when the nation is very diverse, unless one group is dominant (for a synthesis of the debate, see Basuchoudhary and Shughart 2010). Applied to the question of migration, this assumption suggests that an interesting control variable would be a measure of the heterogeneity within the migrant population. However, these data are not available for migrants in EU countries.
 
25
The sum of the coefficients in line (3a) is equal to 0.117, the value of the coefficient associated to the Educ variable in estimation 1 of the table.
 
26
The sums of the coefficients in lines (3b) and (3c) are not significantly different.
 
27
The standard error of the sums of the coefficients in lines (3b) and (3c) are, respectively, 0.006 and 0.005, yielding highly significant estimated coefficients.
 
28
We get exactly the same results if these variables are introduced separately in the regression.
 
29
We can see that the coefficient associated to Vote 2 is positive and significant in regression 2, where Vote 1 is the reference variable.
 
31
The results are not presented for reasons of space.
 
32
There is no routinized technique to identify influential observations in an ordered logit estimation. I chose here to estimate the model with ordinary least squares and calculated the value of the standardized residuals. I then re-estimated the ordered logit model, excluding from the sample observations whose absolute value of standardized residual was greater than 2 (i.e., 1 040 observations, or a little less than 5 % of the sample).
 
Literature
go back to reference Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1167–1199. CrossRef Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2000). Why did the West extend the franchise? Democracy, inequality, and growth in historical perspective. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(4), 1167–1199. CrossRef
go back to reference Andrès, H. (2007). Le droit de vote des étrangers—etat des lieux et fondements théoriques. Thèse pour le doctorat de sciences juridiques et politiques, Université de Paris 7. Andrès, H. (2007). Le droit de vote des étrangers—etat des lieux et fondements théoriques. Thèse pour le doctorat de sciences juridiques et politiques, Université de Paris 7.
go back to reference Bach, S., Blöchliger, H., & Wallau, D. (2009). The spending power of sub-central governments: a pilot study (Working Papers 705). OECD Economics Department. OECD Publishing, July. Bach, S., Blöchliger, H., & Wallau, D. (2009). The spending power of sub-central governments: a pilot study (Working Papers 705). OECD Economics Department. OECD Publishing, July.
go back to reference Basuchoudhary, A., & Shughart, W. F. (2010). On ethnic conflict and the origins of transnational terrorism. Defence and Peace Economics, 21(1), 65–87. CrossRef Basuchoudhary, A., & Shughart, W. F. (2010). On ethnic conflict and the origins of transnational terrorism. Defence and Peace Economics, 21(1), 65–87. CrossRef
go back to reference Bodvarsson, O. B., & Van den Berg, H. (2009). The economics of migration—theory and policy. Berlin: Springer. Bodvarsson, O. B., & Van den Berg, H. (2009). The economics of migration—theory and policy. Berlin: Springer.
go back to reference Boex, J., & Simatupang, R. R. (2008). Fiscal decentralisation and empowerment: evolving concepts and alternative measures. Fiscal Studies, 29(4), 435. CrossRef Boex, J., & Simatupang, R. R. (2008). Fiscal decentralisation and empowerment: evolving concepts and alternative measures. Fiscal Studies, 29(4), 435. CrossRef
go back to reference Borge, L.-E., Brueckner, J. K., & Rattsø, J. (2012). Partial fiscal decentralization and public-sector heterogeneity: theory and evidence from Norway (Technical report). Norwegian, University of Science and Technology Working Paper. Borge, L.-E., Brueckner, J. K., & Rattsø, J. (2012). Partial fiscal decentralization and public-sector heterogeneity: theory and evidence from Norway (Technical report). Norwegian, University of Science and Technology Working Paper.
go back to reference Borjas, G. J. (1999). Immigration and welfare magnets. Journal of Labor Economics, 17(4), 607–637. CrossRef Borjas, G. J. (1999). Immigration and welfare magnets. Journal of Labor Economics, 17(4), 607–637. CrossRef
go back to reference Citrin, J., Green, D. P., Muste, C., & Wong, C. (1997). Public opinion toward immigration reform: the role of economic motivations. The Journal of Politics, 59(03), 858–881. CrossRef Citrin, J., Green, D. P., Muste, C., & Wong, C. (1997). Public opinion toward immigration reform: the role of economic motivations. The Journal of Politics, 59(03), 858–881. CrossRef
go back to reference Cremer, H., & Pestieau, P. (1998). Social insurance, majority voting and labor mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 68(3), 397–420. CrossRef Cremer, H., & Pestieau, P. (1998). Social insurance, majority voting and labor mobility. Journal of Public Economics, 68(3), 397–420. CrossRef
go back to reference Docquier, F., Lohest, O., & Marfouk, A. (2007). Brain drain in developing countries. World Bank Economic Review, 21(2), 193–219. CrossRef Docquier, F., Lohest, O., & Marfouk, A. (2007). Brain drain in developing countries. World Bank Economic Review, 21(2), 193–219. CrossRef
go back to reference Dustmann, C., & Preston, I. (2001). Attitudes to ethnic minorities, ethnic context and location decisions. Economic Journal, 111(470), 353–373. CrossRef Dustmann, C., & Preston, I. (2001). Attitudes to ethnic minorities, ethnic context and location decisions. Economic Journal, 111(470), 353–373. CrossRef
go back to reference Epple, D., & Romer, T. (1991). Mobility and redistribution. Journal of Political Economy, 99(4), 828–858. CrossRef Epple, D., & Romer, T. (1991). Mobility and redistribution. Journal of Political Economy, 99(4), 828–858. CrossRef
go back to reference Facchini, G., & Mayda, A. M. (2006). Individual attitudes towards immigrants: welfare-state determinants across countries. SSRN eLibrary. Facchini, G., & Mayda, A. M. (2006). Individual attitudes towards immigrants: welfare-state determinants across countries. SSRN eLibrary.
go back to reference Facchini, G., & Mayda, A. M. (2009). Does the welfare state affect individual attitudes toward immigrants? Evidence across countries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(2), 295–314. CrossRef Facchini, G., & Mayda, A. M. (2009). Does the welfare state affect individual attitudes toward immigrants? Evidence across countries. Review of Economics and Statistics, 91(2), 295–314. CrossRef
go back to reference Friedberg, R. M., & Jennifer, H. (1995). The impact of immigrants on host country wages, employment and growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(2), 23–44. CrossRef Friedberg, R. M., & Jennifer, H. (1995). The impact of immigrants on host country wages, employment and growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(2), 23–44. CrossRef
go back to reference Hainmueller, J., & Hiscox, M. J. (2007). Educated preferences: explaining attitudes toward immigration in Europe. International Organization, 61(2), 399–442. CrossRef Hainmueller, J., & Hiscox, M. J. (2007). Educated preferences: explaining attitudes toward immigration in Europe. International Organization, 61(2), 399–442. CrossRef
go back to reference Hanson, G. H. (2008). The economic consequences of the international migration of labor (Working Paper 14490). National Bureau of Economic Research, November. Hanson, G. H. (2008). The economic consequences of the international migration of labor (Working Paper 14490). National Bureau of Economic Research, November.
go back to reference Haupt, A., & Peters, W. (1998). Public pensions and voting on immigration. Public Choice, 95(3), 403–413. CrossRef Haupt, A., & Peters, W. (1998). Public pensions and voting on immigration. Public Choice, 95(3), 403–413. CrossRef
go back to reference Kerr, S. P., & Kerr, W. R. (2011). Economic impacts of immigration: a survey (Working Paper 16736). National Bureau of Economic Research, January. Kerr, S. P., & Kerr, W. R. (2011). Economic impacts of immigration: a survey (Working Paper 16736). National Bureau of Economic Research, January.
go back to reference Le Maux, B., Rocaboy, Y., & Goodspeed, T. (2011). Political fragmentation, party ideology and public expenditures. Public Choice, 147(1), 43–67. CrossRef Le Maux, B., Rocaboy, Y., & Goodspeed, T. (2011). Political fragmentation, party ideology and public expenditures. Public Choice, 147(1), 43–67. CrossRef
go back to reference Mayda, A. M. (2006). Who is against immigration? A cross-country investigation of individual attitudes toward immigrants. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(3), 510–530. CrossRef Mayda, A. M. (2006). Who is against immigration? A cross-country investigation of individual attitudes toward immigrants. Review of Economics and Statistics, 88(3), 510–530. CrossRef
go back to reference Mayr, K. (2007). Immigration and income redistribution: a political economy analysis. Public Choice, 131(1), 101–116. CrossRef Mayr, K. (2007). Immigration and income redistribution: a political economy analysis. Public Choice, 131(1), 101–116. CrossRef
go back to reference Mazza, I., & Winden, F. (1996). A political economic analysis of labor migration and income redistribution. Public Choice, 88(3), 333–363. CrossRef Mazza, I., & Winden, F. (1996). A political economic analysis of labor migration and income redistribution. Public Choice, 88(3), 333–363. CrossRef
go back to reference Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 914–927. CrossRef Meltzer, A. H., & Richard, S. (1981). A rational theory of the size of government. Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 914–927. CrossRef
go back to reference Nannestad, P. (2007). Immigration and welfare states: a survey of 15 years of research. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(2), 512–532. CrossRef Nannestad, P. (2007). Immigration and welfare states: a survey of 15 years of research. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(2), 512–532. CrossRef
go back to reference Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149. CrossRef Oates, W. E. (1999). An essay on fiscal federalism. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(3), 1120–1149. CrossRef
go back to reference Okkerse, L. (2008). How to measure labour market effects of immigration: a review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 22(1), 1–30. CrossRef Okkerse, L. (2008). How to measure labour market effects of immigration: a review. Journal of Economic Surveys, 22(1), 1–30. CrossRef
go back to reference O’Rourke, K. H., & Sinnott, R. (2006). The determinants of individual attitudes towards immigration. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(4), 838–861. CrossRef O’Rourke, K. H., & Sinnott, R. (2006). The determinants of individual attitudes towards immigration. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(4), 838–861. CrossRef
go back to reference Peracchi, F., & Depalo, D. (2006). Labor market outcomes of natives and immigrants: evidence from the ECHP (Working Paper 615). The World Bank. Peracchi, F., & Depalo, D. (2006). Labor market outcomes of natives and immigrants: evidence from the ECHP (Working Paper 615). The World Bank.
go back to reference Powell, B. (2012). Coyote ugly: the deadweight cost of rent seeking for immigration policy. Public Choice, 150(1), 195–208. CrossRef Powell, B. (2012). Coyote ugly: the deadweight cost of rent seeking for immigration policy. Public Choice, 150(1), 195–208. CrossRef
go back to reference Razin, A., & Sadka, E. (2004). Welfare migration: is the net fiscal burden a good measure of its economic impact on the welfare of the native born population? (Working Paper 10682). National Bureau of Economic Research, August. Razin, A., & Sadka, E. (2004). Welfare migration: is the net fiscal burden a good measure of its economic impact on the welfare of the native born population? (Working Paper 10682). National Bureau of Economic Research, August.
go back to reference Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Swagel, P. (2002). Tax burden and migration: a political economy theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 85(2), 167–190. CrossRef Razin, A., Sadka, E., & Swagel, P. (2002). Tax burden and migration: a political economy theory and evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 85(2), 167–190. CrossRef
go back to reference Rother, P. C., Catenaro, M., & Schwab, G. (2003). Ageing and pensions in the Euro area survey and projection results (Social Protection Discussion Papers 25986). The World Bank. Rother, P. C., Catenaro, M., & Schwab, G. (2003). Ageing and pensions in the Euro area survey and projection results (Social Protection Discussion Papers 25986). The World Bank.
go back to reference Scheve, K. F., & Slaughter, M. J. (2001). Labor market competition and individual preferences over immigration policy. Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(1), 133–145. CrossRef Scheve, K. F., & Slaughter, M. J. (2001). Labor market competition and individual preferences over immigration policy. Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(1), 133–145. CrossRef
go back to reference Scholten, U., & Thum, M. (1996). Public pensions and immigration policy in a democracy. Public Choice, 87, 347–361. CrossRef Scholten, U., & Thum, M. (1996). Public pensions and immigration policy in a democracy. Public Choice, 87, 347–361. CrossRef
go back to reference Strudel, S. (2003). Polyrythmie européenne: le droit de suffrage municipal des étrangers au sein de l’Union, une règle électorale entre détournements et retardements. Revue Française de Science Politique, 53(1), 3–34. Strudel, S. (2003). Polyrythmie européenne: le droit de suffrage municipal des étrangers au sein de l’Union, une règle électorale entre détournements et retardements. Revue Française de Science Politique, 53(1), 3–34.
go back to reference Sénat (2005). Le droit de vote des étrangers aux élections locales. Etude de législation comparée, n∘218, 30 novembre 2011. Sénat (2005). Le droit de vote des étrangers aux élections locales. Etude de législation comparée, n218, 30 novembre 2011.
go back to reference Söllner, F. (1999). A note on the political economy of immigration. Public Choice, 100, 245–251. CrossRef Söllner, F. (1999). A note on the political economy of immigration. Public Choice, 100, 245–251. CrossRef
go back to reference Thum, M. (2004). Controlling migration in an open labor market. Public Choice, 119(3), 425–443. CrossRef Thum, M. (2004). Controlling migration in an open labor market. Public Choice, 119(3), 425–443. CrossRef
go back to reference Valenty, L. O., & Sylvia, R. D. (2004). Thresholds for tolerance: the impact of racial and ethnic population composition on the vote for California propositions 187 and 209. The Social Science Journal, 41(3), 433–446. CrossRef Valenty, L. O., & Sylvia, R. D. (2004). Thresholds for tolerance: the impact of racial and ethnic population composition on the vote for California propositions 187 and 209. The Social Science Journal, 41(3), 433–446. CrossRef
go back to reference Vasileva, K. (2011). 6.5 % of the EU population are foreigners and 9.4 % are born abroad. Population and social conditions—statistics in focus 34, Eurostat. Vasileva, K. (2011). 6.5 % of the EU population are foreigners and 9.4 % are born abroad. Population and social conditions—statistics in focus 34, Eurostat.
go back to reference White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817–838. CrossRef White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity. Econometrica, 48(4), 817–838. CrossRef
Metadata
Title
The welfare state, migration, and voting rights
Author
Christine Fauvelle-Aymar
Publication date
01-04-2014
Publisher
Springer US
Published in
Public Choice / Issue 1-2/2014
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Electronic ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-012-0024-z

Other articles of this Issue 1-2/2014

Public Choice 1-2/2014 Go to the issue