Skip to main content
Top
Published in:
Cover of the book

2017 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

1. Valuing Environmental Goods and Services: An Economic Perspective

Author : Kathleen Segerson

Published in: A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation

Publisher: Springer Netherlands

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Nonmarket valuation, i.e., valuing environmental goods and services that are not traded in a market, has been increasingly used in a variety of policy and decision-making contexts. This is one (but not the only) way that researchers and practitioners have sought to define and measure the values that individuals assign to environmental goods and services. The idea of putting a dollar value on protecting the environment has been controversial, but often because the economic approach to valuation has not been well-understood. This chapter provides a nontechnical overview of and rationale for the economic approach to valuation, starting from a broad conceptualization of values versus valuation. It summarizes the economic concept of value and its key features. It then discusses the use of economic valuation in decision making, followed by an overview of the steps involved in the valuation process and important issues that arise in implementing that process. Finally, it identifies and briefly summarizes the principal non-market valuation methods used by economists. In doing so, it sets the stage for the more detailed chapters on theory and methods that follow.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 390 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe




 

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
The reasons that markets do not exist can vary. In many cases, the market failure arises because the environmental good or service is a public good. For example, air quality in a city is a pure public good because all individuals living in the city will benefit from an improvement in the city’s air quality and no one in the city can be excluded from enjoying the benefits of the improvement. Public goods suffer from the “free-rider” problem, which can impede the development of a market for the good. Markets can fail to exist for other reasons as well, including ill-defined property rights, information asymmetries, and difficulty in defining and monitoring tradable units.
 
2
Most theoretical discussions of economic values and nonmarket valuation methods focus on valuing a single change (e.g., a change in ambient air quality). However, most real-world valuation contexts involve changes in multiple environmental goods or services and multiple impacts on human well-being. The need to consider multiple changes or impacts raises questions about interconnectedness and aggregation and clearly complicates the valuation process. See National Research Council (2005, Chapter 5) for a useful discussion of valuing changes in multiple ecosystem services.
 
3
An important research question is whether alternative ways to define and measure assigned values yield consistent information about underlying preferences. The limited evidence that exists on this is mixed. See, for example, Cooper et al. (2004) and Spash (2006).
 
4
See Chap. 2 for a more formal definition.
 
5
Because people regularly use money to buy things and accept money when they sell things, the idea of trading money for goods and services is familiar to them (although they may never have traded for the specific good or service being valued). Nonetheless, some individuals may feel that certain things, such as changes in health or environmental quality, should not be “commodified” and sold in markets. This does not, however, mean that providing those things does not involve trade-offs. As emphasized, economic values are fundamentally about the trade-offs individuals would be willing to make. Even individuals who object to the idea of buying or selling nature exhibit a willingness to make trade-offs related to health and the environment in their everyday lives (for example, every time they travel by car).
 
6
In contrast, some psychologists believe that preferences are constructed through the elicitation process. See, for example, Lichtenstein and Slovic (2006).
 
7
However, see Common et al. (1997) for evidence suggesting that the assumption of substitutability that underlies the economic notion of existence value may not hold in all contexts.
 
8
Under some conditions, it is possible to value a change in output by aggregating the payments to the owners of the inputs used to produce the additional output. For example, with perfectly competitive markets and constant returns to scale, the value of additional agricultural output can be measured as the sum of the payments to the laborers, landowner, fertilizer producers, etc., who supply the inputs used to increase production. In this case, the income paid to farm workers can be used as part of the measure of benefits. However, including both the payments to the inputs and the revenue from the sale of the additional output as measures of benefits would be double counting. Benefits can be measured as the value of the inputs or the value of the output but not both.
 
9
The theoretical foundations of benefit-cost analysis as a basis for public policy are well established and described in detail in Just et al. (2004).
 
10
For an example of nonmarket valuation in this context, see Johnston et al. (2011).
 
11
For more detailed discussions of these and related issues, see, for example, Freeman et al. (2014).
 
12
As an alternative, preferences could be aggregated across individuals simply by counting the number of individuals who prefer one option to another. This approach underlies decision rules based on standard voting procedures. A key drawback to using votes as a means of aggregating preferences to determine outcomes is that the resulting decisions do not reflect the intensity of individual preferences for one option over another. For example, in a three-person vote, an option that is only slightly preferred by two individuals would win over an option that is strongly preferred by the third individual.
 
13
Occasionally, a weighted sum will be used in an effort to incorporate distributional concerns, i.e., to give more weight to the benefits that accrue to one group of individuals than to another (see, for example, Johannsen-Stenman 2005). However, most economists do not advocate the use of a weighted average as a means to incorporate distributional concerns; rather, they advocate providing decision-makers with an unweighted measure of total benefits along with information about the distribution of benefits across relevant subpopulations. See, for example, Arrow et al. (1996).
 
14
This is based on the compensation principle that underlies benefit-cost analysis. For a detailed discussion, see Just et al. (2004).
 
15
Note, however, that maximizing aggregate net benefits or aggregate income is not generally equivalent to maximizing the sum of utility across all individuals. The two will be the same if coupled with a redistribution of income that equates the marginal utility of income across all individuals. Absent that redistribution, a change for which benefits exceed costs could actually reduce aggregate utility. To see this, consider a choice x, where an increase in x generates an increase in income (i.e., a benefit) for Person 1 and a decrease in income (i.e., a cost) for Person 2. Let \(Y_{i} (x)\) be income for Person i (where i = 1 or 2) and let \(u_{i} (Y_{i} (x))\) be i’s utility. Then, if \(\frac{{\partial u_{1} }}{{\partial Y_{1} }} < \frac{{\partial u_{2} }}{{\partial Y_{2} }}\) and there is no actual compensation, it is possible to have \(\frac{{\partial Y_{1} }}{\partial x} + \frac{{\partial Y_{2} }}{\partial x} > 0\) (i.e., the gain to person 1 exceeds the loss to person 2) even though \(\frac{{\partial u_{1} }}{{\partial Y_{1} }}\frac{{\partial Y_{1} }}{\partial x} + \frac{{\partial u_{2} }}{{\partial Y_{2} }}\frac{{\partial Y_{2} }}{\partial x} < 0\) (i.e., aggregate utility decreases). While it might be reasonable to assume that direct mechanisms (such as taxes) are available to address income distribution within a given generation, this assumption is much more questionable for income redistribution across generations. For this reason, differences in the marginal utility of income across individuals are often not explicitly considered when aggregating benefits and costs at a given point in time, while differences in the marginal utility of consumption across generations play an important role in aggregation across time (see discussion in Sect. 1.8.3).
 
16
However, to the extent that current decisions affect future generations, the individuals in those generations are not around today to express the values they would assign to the relevant changes. Thus, in practice it is the current generation that must express values on behalf of future generations.
 
17
A simple example illustrating this result is provided in Cropper (2012). A declining discount rate is also consistent with some forms of nonstandard preferences, such as those that exhibit hyperbolic or quasi-hyperbolic discounting. See, for example, the discussion and references in Benhabib et al. (2010).
 
18
A negative discount rate might arise, for example, in the context of ecosystem services where those services are becoming scarcer (rather than more abundant) over time. See, for example, Heal (2005, 2009) and National Research Council (2005).
 
19
Although some authors distinguish between “risk” and “uncertainty” based on whether the probabilities of the possible outcomes can be quantified, in economics, the two terms are typically used interchangeably. We follow this convention here. For example, when talking about either the uncertainty associated with future preferences or the health risks from exposure to pollution, we assume that all possibilities can be identified and each can be assigned an objective (or possibly subjective) probability of occurring.
 
20
Such estimates are often expressed in terms of the “value of a statistical life” (VSL). However, this terminology has led to confusion and unnecessary controversy about the concept being measured, prompting some to argue that the term VSL should not be used (e.g., Cameron 2010).
 
21
For example, the U.S. Office of Management and Budget’s Circular A-4, which governs federal regulatory impact analyses, explicitly states: “Other things equal, you should prefer revealed preference data over stated preference data because revealed preference data are based on actual decisions, where market participants enjoy or suffer the consequences of their decisions”. See OMB Circular A-4, Section E (September 17, 2003), available at http://​www.​whitehouse.​gov/​omb/​circulars_​a004_​a-4#e.
 
Literature
go back to reference Adamowicz, W. (2004). What’s it worth? An examination of historical trends and future directions in environmental valuation. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 48, 419-443. Adamowicz, W. (2004). What’s it worth? An examination of historical trends and future directions in environmental valuation. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, 48, 419-443.
go back to reference Adamowicz, W., Louviere, J. & Williams, M. (1994). Combining revealed and stated preference methods for valuing environmental amenities. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 271-292. Adamowicz, W., Louviere, J. & Williams, M. (1994). Combining revealed and stated preference methods for valuing environmental amenities. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 26, 271-292.
go back to reference Agarwal, N., Banternghansa, C. & Bui, L. T. M. (2010). Toxic exposure in America: Estimating fetal and infant health outcomes from 14 years of TRI reporting. Journal of Health Economics, 29, 557-574. Agarwal, N., Banternghansa, C. & Bui, L. T. M. (2010). Toxic exposure in America: Estimating fetal and infant health outcomes from 14 years of TRI reporting. Journal of Health Economics, 29, 557-574.
go back to reference Arrow, K. J., Cropper, M. L., Eads, G. C., Hahn, R. W., Lave, L. B., Noll, R. G., et al. (1996). Is there a role for benefit-cost analysis in environmental, health, and safety regulation? Science, 272 (April), 221-222. Arrow, K. J., Cropper, M. L., Eads, G. C., Hahn, R. W., Lave, L. B., Noll, R. G., et al. (1996). Is there a role for benefit-cost analysis in environmental, health, and safety regulation? Science, 272 (April), 221-222.
go back to reference Benhabib, J., Bisin, A. & Schotter, A. (2010). Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69, 205-223. Benhabib, J., Bisin, A. & Schotter, A. (2010). Present-bias, quasi-hyperbolic discounting, and fixed costs. Games and Economic Behavior, 69, 205-223.
go back to reference Bockstael, N. E., Freeman, A. M. III, Kopp, R. J., Portney, P. R. & Smith, V. K. (2000). On measuring economic values for nature. Environmental Science and Technology, 34, 1384-1389. Bockstael, N. E., Freeman, A. M. III, Kopp, R. J., Portney, P. R. & Smith, V. K. (2000). On measuring economic values for nature. Environmental Science and Technology, 34, 1384-1389.
go back to reference Brookshire, D. S., Eubanks, L. S. & Randall, A. (1983). Estimating option prices and existence values for wildlife resources. Land Economics, 59, 1-15. Brookshire, D. S., Eubanks, L. S. & Randall, A. (1983). Estimating option prices and existence values for wildlife resources. Land Economics, 59, 1-15.
go back to reference Brown, T. C. (1984). The concept of value in resource allocation. Land Economics, 60, 231-246. Brown, T. C. (1984). The concept of value in resource allocation. Land Economics, 60, 231-246.
go back to reference Brown, T. C., Bergstrom, J. C. & Loomis, J. B. (2007). Defining, valuing, and providing ecosystem goods and services. Natural Resources Journal, 47, 329-376. Brown, T. C., Bergstrom, J. C. & Loomis, J. B. (2007). Defining, valuing, and providing ecosystem goods and services. Natural Resources Journal, 47, 329-376.
go back to reference Cameron, T. A. (2010). Euthanizing the value of a statistical life. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4, 161-178. Cameron, T. A. (2010). Euthanizing the value of a statistical life. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 4, 161-178.
go back to reference Cameron, T. A. & DeShazo, J. R. (2013). Demand for health risk reductions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 65, 87-109. Cameron, T. A. & DeShazo, J. R. (2013). Demand for health risk reductions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 65, 87-109.
go back to reference Carpenter, S., Defries, R., Dietz, T., Mooney, H. A., Polasky, S., Reid, W. V., et al. (2006). Millennium ecosystem assessment: Research needs. Science, 314, 257-258. Carpenter, S., Defries, R., Dietz, T., Mooney, H. A., Polasky, S., Reid, W. V., et al. (2006). Millennium ecosystem assessment: Research needs. Science, 314, 257-258.
go back to reference Carson, R. T. (2012). Contingent valuation: A comprehensive bibliography and history. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing. Carson, R. T. (2012). Contingent valuation: A comprehensive bibliography and history. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing.
go back to reference Cerda, C., Barkmann, J. & Marggraf, R. (2013). Application of choice experiments to quantify existence value of an endemic moss: A case study in Chile. Environment and Development Economics, 18, 207-224. Cerda, C., Barkmann, J. & Marggraf, R. (2013). Application of choice experiments to quantify existence value of an endemic moss: A case study in Chile. Environment and Development Economics, 18, 207-224.
go back to reference Common, M., Reid, I. & Blamey, R. (1997). Do existence values for cost benefit analysis exist? Environmental and Resource Economics, 9, 225-238. Common, M., Reid, I. & Blamey, R. (1997). Do existence values for cost benefit analysis exist? Environmental and Resource Economics, 9, 225-238.
go back to reference Cooper, P., Poe, G. L. & Bateman, I. J. (2004). The structure of motivation for contingent values: A case study of lake water quality improvement. Ecological Economics, 50, 69-82. Cooper, P., Poe, G. L. & Bateman, I. J. (2004). The structure of motivation for contingent values: A case study of lake water quality improvement. Ecological Economics, 50, 69-82.
go back to reference Costanza, R., d’Arge, R., de Groot, R., Farber, S. & Grasso, M., Hannon, et al. (1997). The value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature, 387, 253-260. Costanza, R., d’Arge, R., de Groot, R., Farber, S. & Grasso, M., Hannon, et al. (1997). The value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Nature, 387, 253-260.
go back to reference Cropper, M. L. (2012). How should benefits and costs be discounted in an intergenerational context? Resource for the Future Discussion Paper, RFF DP 12-42, Washington, DC. Cropper, M. L. (2012). How should benefits and costs be discounted in an intergenerational context? Resource for the Future Discussion Paper, RFF DP 12-42, Washington, DC.
go back to reference Currie, J. & Neidell, M. (2005). Air pollution and infant health: What can we learn from California’s recent experience? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1003-1030. Currie, J. & Neidell, M. (2005). Air pollution and infant health: What can we learn from California’s recent experience? The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 1003-1030.
go back to reference Daily, G. C. (Ed.) (1997). Nature’s services: Societal dependence on natural ecosystems. Washington, DC: Island Press. Daily, G. C. (Ed.) (1997). Nature’s services: Societal dependence on natural ecosystems. Washington, DC: Island Press.
go back to reference Daily, G. & Ellison, K. (2002). The new economy of nature: The quest to make conservation profitable. Washington, DC: Island Press. Daily, G. & Ellison, K. (2002). The new economy of nature: The quest to make conservation profitable. Washington, DC: Island Press.
go back to reference Dietz, T., Fitzgerald, A. & Shwom, R. (2005). Environmental values. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 30, 335-372. Dietz, T., Fitzgerald, A. & Shwom, R. (2005). Environmental values. Annual Review of Environment and Resources, 30, 335-372.
go back to reference Freeman, A. M. III., Herriges, J.A. & Kling, C.L. (2014). The measurement of environmental and resource values: Theory and methods (3rd ed.). Washington, DC: RFF Press. Freeman, A. M. III., Herriges, J.A. & Kling, C.L. (2014). The measurement of environmental and resource values: Theory and methods (3rd ed.). Washington, DC: RFF Press.
go back to reference Hausman, J. (2012). Contingent valuation: From dubious to hopeless. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26 (4), 43-56. Hausman, J. (2012). Contingent valuation: From dubious to hopeless. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26 (4), 43-56.
go back to reference Heal, G. (2000). Nature and the marketplace: Capturing the value of ecosystem services. Washington, DC: Island Press. Heal, G. (2000). Nature and the marketplace: Capturing the value of ecosystem services. Washington, DC: Island Press.
go back to reference Heal, G. (2005). Intertemporal welfare economics and the environment. In K.-G. Mäler & J. Vincent (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics, Vol. 3: Economywide and international environmental issues (pp. 1105-1145). Amsterdam: Elsevier. Heal, G. (2005). Intertemporal welfare economics and the environment. In K.-G. Mäler & J. Vincent (Eds.), Handbook of environmental economics, Vol. 3: Economywide and international environmental issues (pp. 1105-1145). Amsterdam: Elsevier.
go back to reference Heal, G. (2009). Climate economics: A meta-review and some suggestions for future research. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 3, 4-21. Heal, G. (2009). Climate economics: A meta-review and some suggestions for future research. Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, 3, 4-21.
go back to reference Johansson-Stenman, O. (2005). Distributional weights in cost-benefit analysis: Should we forget about them? Land Economics, 81, 337-352. Johansson-Stenman, O. (2005). Distributional weights in cost-benefit analysis: Should we forget about them? Land Economics, 81, 337-352.
go back to reference Johnston, R. J., Segerson, K., Schultz, E. T., Besedin, E. Y. & Ramachandran, M. (2011). Indices of biotic integrity in stated preference valuation of aquatic ecosystem services. Ecological Economics, 70, 1946-1956. Johnston, R. J., Segerson, K., Schultz, E. T., Besedin, E. Y. & Ramachandran, M. (2011). Indices of biotic integrity in stated preference valuation of aquatic ecosystem services. Ecological Economics, 70, 1946-1956.
go back to reference Just, R. E., Hueth, D. L. & Schmitz, A. (2004). The welfare economics of public policy: A practical approach to project and policy evaluation. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing. Just, R. E., Hueth, D. L. & Schmitz, A. (2004). The welfare economics of public policy: A practical approach to project and policy evaluation. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar Publishing.
go back to reference Kling, C. L., Phaneuf, D. J. & Zhao, J. (2012). From Exxon to BP: Has some number become better than no number? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26 (4), 3-26. Kling, C. L., Phaneuf, D. J. & Zhao, J. (2012). From Exxon to BP: Has some number become better than no number? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 26 (4), 3-26.
go back to reference Kopp, R. J. & Smith, V. K. (Eds.) (1993). Valuing natural assets: The economics of natural resource damage assessment. Washington, DC: RFF Press. Kopp, R. J. & Smith, V. K. (Eds.) (1993). Valuing natural assets: The economics of natural resource damage assessment. Washington, DC: RFF Press.
go back to reference Lichtenstein, S. & Slovic, P. (Eds.) (2006). The construction of preferences. New York: Cambridge University Press. Lichtenstein, S. & Slovic, P. (Eds.) (2006). The construction of preferences. New York: Cambridge University Press.
go back to reference McVittie, A. & Moran, D. (2010). Valuing the non-use benefits of marine conservation zones: An application to the UK Marine Bill. Ecological Economics, 70, 413-424. McVittie, A. & Moran, D. (2010). Valuing the non-use benefits of marine conservation zones: An application to the UK Marine Bill. Ecological Economics, 70, 413-424.
go back to reference Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: A framework for assessment. Washington, DC: Island Press. Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. (2005). Ecosystems and human well-being: A framework for assessment. Washington, DC: Island Press.
go back to reference National Research Council. (2005). Valuing ecosystem services: Toward better environmental decision-making. Washington, DC: National Academies Press. National Research Council. (2005). Valuing ecosystem services: Toward better environmental decision-making. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.
go back to reference Polasky, S. & Segerson, K. (2009). Integrating ecology and economics in the study of ecosystem services: Some lessons learned. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 1, 409-434. Polasky, S. & Segerson, K. (2009). Integrating ecology and economics in the study of ecosystem services: Some lessons learned. Annual Review of Resource Economics, 1, 409-434.
go back to reference Portney, P. R. (1994). The contingent valuation debate: Why economists should care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (4), 3-17. Portney, P. R. (1994). The contingent valuation debate: Why economists should care. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8 (4), 3-17.
go back to reference Smith, V. K. (Ed.) (1984). Environmental policy under Reagan’s executive order: The role of benefit-cost analysis. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. Smith, V. K. (Ed.) (1984). Environmental policy under Reagan’s executive order: The role of benefit-cost analysis. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
go back to reference Smith, V. K. (1993). Nonmarket valuation of environmental resources: An interpretive appraisal. Land Economics, 69, 1-26. Smith, V. K. (1993). Nonmarket valuation of environmental resources: An interpretive appraisal. Land Economics, 69, 1-26.
go back to reference Spash, C. L. (2006). Non-economic motivation for contingent values: Rights and attitudinal beliefs in the willingness to pay for environmental improvements. Land Economics, 82, 602-622. Spash, C. L. (2006). Non-economic motivation for contingent values: Rights and attitudinal beliefs in the willingness to pay for environmental improvements. Land Economics, 82, 602-622.
go back to reference Toman, M. (1998). Why not to calculate the value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Ecological Economics, 25, 57-60. Toman, M. (1998). Why not to calculate the value of the world’s ecosystem services and natural capital. Ecological Economics, 25, 57-60.
go back to reference U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (2009). Valuing the protection of ecological systems and services: A report of the EPA Science Advisory Board. EPA-SAB-09-012, Washington, DC. U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. (2009). Valuing the protection of ecological systems and services: A report of the EPA Science Advisory Board. EPA-SAB-09-012, Washington, DC.
go back to reference Viscusi, W. K. (2009). Valuing risks of death from terrorism and natural disasters. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 38, 191-213. Viscusi, W. K. (2009). Valuing risks of death from terrorism and natural disasters. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 38, 191-213.
go back to reference Zhao, J. & Kling, C. L. (2009). Welfare measures when agents can learn: A unifying theory. The Economic Journal, 119, 1560-1585. Zhao, J. & Kling, C. L. (2009). Welfare measures when agents can learn: A unifying theory. The Economic Journal, 119, 1560-1585.
Metadata
Title
Valuing Environmental Goods and Services: An Economic Perspective
Author
Kathleen Segerson
Copyright Year
2017
Publisher
Springer Netherlands
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-94-007-7104-8_1