Skip to main content
Top
Published in: Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 3/2023

03-02-2023 | Regular Article

Wage claim detracts reciprocity in labor relations: experimental study of gift exchange games

Authors: Tetsuo Yamamori, Kazuyuki Iwata

Published in: Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination | Issue 3/2023

Log in

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Although workers’ wage claims are common in the workplace, the literature has failed to statistically examine their impact on the reciprocal relationships between workers and managers. We overcome this issue by conducting laboratory experiments based on a one-shot gift exchange game in the context of firm–worker relationships. Our design accepts two types of voice by workers regarding the contract wage with their firm, both defined as cheap talk. One voice communicates only the desirable wage for the workers, whereas the second voice additionally communicates their future efforts. We find that both types of voice do not increase firms’ offers but instead reduce agreement contract rates. Furthermore, they undermine workers’ reciprocity regardless of the wage levels offered by the firm, thus reducing the effort levels post-agreement in an incomplete employment contract. Additional experiments revealed that the voice’s adverse effects persist even for repeated interactions. However, workers’ voices, including future efforts, lead to higher wage offers, which outweigh the adverse effect on workers’ reciprocal behaviors; that is, it increases the effort level after the agreements.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Appendix
Available only for authorised users
Footnotes
1
The tendency of individuals to conflate what is fair with their self-interests is known as self-serving bias, which is an important factor in the bargaining impasse (e.g., Babcock and Loewenstein 1997).
 
2
For example, Klaas (1989) argued that after filing a grievance associated with a feeling of inequality, an employee might unconsciously attempt to justify this action by making cognitive adjustments that result in a heightened sense of inequity.
 
3
Such experiments using a cover story, confederates, and deception are common in psychology to ensure that the subjects behave as they would in a real-world situation, that is, enhancing external validity. Meanwhile, experimental economists avoid deceiving subjects since deception will reduce the subjects’ ability to make informed choices about game rules and incentives. See, for example, Ariely and Norton (2007) or Madsen and Stenheim (2015) for a comparison of the experimental methods of psychologists and economists.
 
4
Roth (1995) noted that face-to-face interaction might have many confounding and uncontrolled effects.
 
5
See Crawford (1998) and Farrell and Rabin (1996) for a detailed review.
 
6
While most of these studies have focused on cheap talk as a means to facilitate coordination or improve efficiency in social dilemmas, some researchers have focused on the shortcomings of cheap talk, such as being a tool for deception (e.g., Wilson and Sell 1997; Croson et al. 2003). We will argue later about what this shortcoming of cheap talk implies in our experiment.
 
7
In Gächter and Falk (2002), the firm’s wage offer is an integer, taking values from 20 to 120.
 
8
See Gächter and Fehr (2002) for a survey.
 
9
Instructions for the IT and practice problems are shown in Appendix A in the supplementary materials.
 
10
Preference for mathematics is measured on a 5-point scale, with 1 meaning very favorable and 5 very unfavorable. For monthly income, we use six dummy variables. Each dummy variable is 1 if the income is less than 9,999 yen, between 10,000 yen and 29,999 yen, 30,000 yen and 49,999 yen, 70,000 yen and 89,999 yen, and more than 90,000 yen.
 
11
This result is consistent with the results of the dictator game experiment in Yamamori et al. (2008), in which dictators reduce their offers to greedy recipients.
 
12
One may wonder why we do not consider the intention-based reciprocity models (e.g., Charness and Rabin 2002; Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger 2004; Falk and Fischbacher 2006; Rabin 1993) rather than the models of distributional preferences (e.g., Andreoni and Miller 2002; Bolton and Ockenfels 2000), which rely only on the outcomes, such as Fehr and Schmidt’s model. The intention-based reciprocity models can also explain the worker’s reciprocal behavior in a gift exchange game. However, our estimation’s aim is neither to find the best-fit model to explain our data nor to elicit the preference of subjects (which should be defined on a broader domain, including the other parts of the game form, i.e., context-dependence). To achieve these goals, we need more elaborate experiments designed for them (See Weibull (2004) for an argument for the difficulty of eliciting preference). Instead, the purpose is to examine whether workers’ ranking on the payoff distributions was biased toward more self-interest or self-serving, which cannot be verified by only observing descriptive statistics of the effort schedules. Capturing the impact of workers’ voices on the parameters of the inequality aversion model is a simple way to achieve this goal.
 
13
Our estimation follows the method described in Chapter 16 of Moffatt (2016).
 
14
For example, see Breitmoser and Tan (2013) for more sophisticated models on reference-dependent social preferences.
 
15
This does not mean that the use of deceptive messages will be eliminated in repeated interactions. For example, Wilson and Sell (1997) showed, in their public goods experiment with a pre-announcement that repeats multiple times in a group of the same six people, that the subjects rarely contribute at the levels they announce.
 
16
Some experimental studies on gift exchange games indicate that repeated interactions improve efficiency relative to the one-shot situation through the so-called “repeated game effect” (Falk et al. 1999; Gächter and Falk 2002). We do not focus on this repeated game effect to address inefficiency but rather due to its ability to make messages credible.
 
17
Note that reservation wages and effort schedules are no longer proxies for their preferences on the outcomes of the underlying game in the repeated situation since they would be influenced by strategic considerations.
 
Literature
go back to reference Compte O, Jehiel P (2007) Bargaining with reference dependent preferences. Levine’s bibliography 122247000000001552, UCLA Department of Economics Compte O, Jehiel P (2007) Bargaining with reference dependent preferences. Levine’s bibliography 122247000000001552, UCLA Department of Economics
go back to reference Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Do incentive contracts crowd out voluntary cooperation? IEW, Working Papers 034, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics. University of Zürich Fehr E, Gächter S (2002) Do incentive contracts crowd out voluntary cooperation? IEW, Working Papers 034, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics. University of Zürich
go back to reference Feuille P, Delaney J (1992) The individual pursuit of organizational justice: grievance procedures in nonunion workplace. Res Pers Hum Resour Manag 10:187–232 Feuille P, Delaney J (1992) The individual pursuit of organizational justice: grievance procedures in nonunion workplace. Res Pers Hum Resour Manag 10:187–232
go back to reference Freeman RB, Medoff JL (1984) What do unions do? Basic Books, New York Freeman RB, Medoff JL (1984) What do unions do? Basic Books, New York
go back to reference Gächter S, Fehr A (2002) Fairness in the labour market—a survey of experimental results. In: Bolle F, Lehmann-Waffenschmidt M (eds) Surveys in experimental economics: bargaining, cooperation and election stock markets. Physica Verlag, pp 95–132 Gächter S, Fehr A (2002) Fairness in the labour market—a survey of experimental results. In: Bolle F, Lehmann-Waffenschmidt M (eds) Surveys in experimental economics: bargaining, cooperation and election stock markets. Physica Verlag, pp 95–132
go back to reference Hirschman AO (1970) Exit, voice, and loyalty: responses to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Hirschman AO (1970) Exit, voice, and loyalty: responses to decline in firms, organizations, and states. Harvard University Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Lewin D, Peterson RB (1988) The modern grievance procedure in the United States. Quorum, Westport Lewin D, Peterson RB (1988) The modern grievance procedure in the United States. Quorum, Westport
go back to reference Lind EA, Tyler TR (1988) The social psychology of procedural justice. Plenum Press, New YorkCrossRef Lind EA, Tyler TR (1988) The social psychology of procedural justice. Plenum Press, New YorkCrossRef
go back to reference Milgrom P, Roberts J (1992) Economics, organization and management. Prentice Hall International, Englewood Cliffs Milgrom P, Roberts J (1992) Economics, organization and management. Prentice Hall International, Englewood Cliffs
go back to reference Moffatt PG (2016) Experimetrics: econometrics for experimental economics. Palgrave MacMillan, London Moffatt PG (2016) Experimetrics: econometrics for experimental economics. Palgrave MacMillan, London
go back to reference Neale MA, Bazerman M (1991) Cognition and rationality in negotiation. Free Press, New York Neale MA, Bazerman M (1991) Cognition and rationality in negotiation. Free Press, New York
go back to reference Rabin M (1993) Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. Am Econ Rev 83(5):1281–1302 Rabin M (1993) Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. Am Econ Rev 83(5):1281–1302
go back to reference Roth AE (1995) Bargaining experiment. In: Kagel JH, Roth AE (eds) Handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 253–348 Roth AE (1995) Bargaining experiment. In: Kagel JH, Roth AE (eds) Handbook of experimental economics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 253–348
go back to reference Sheppard BH, Lewicki RJ, Minton JW (1992) Organizational justice: the search for fairness in the workplace. Lexington Books, New York Sheppard BH, Lewicki RJ, Minton JW (1992) Organizational justice: the search for fairness in the workplace. Lexington Books, New York
go back to reference Weibull JW (2004) Testing game theory. In: Huck S (ed) Advances in understanding strategic behaviour: game theory, experiments and bounded rationality. Palgrave MacMillan, London Weibull JW (2004) Testing game theory. In: Huck S (ed) Advances in understanding strategic behaviour: game theory, experiments and bounded rationality. Palgrave MacMillan, London
Metadata
Title
Wage claim detracts reciprocity in labor relations: experimental study of gift exchange games
Authors
Tetsuo Yamamori
Kazuyuki Iwata
Publication date
03-02-2023
Publisher
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Published in
Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination / Issue 3/2023
Print ISSN: 1860-711X
Electronic ISSN: 1860-7128
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11403-023-00378-9

Other articles of this Issue 3/2023

Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 3/2023 Go to the issue