Skip to main content
Top

2018 | OriginalPaper | Chapter

Was Wilhelm Röpke Really a Proto-Keynesian?

Author : Raphaël Fèvre

Published in: Wilhelm Röpke (1899–1966)

Publisher: Springer International Publishing

Activate our intelligent search to find suitable subject content or patents.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Fèvre examines the difficulties of the commonly encountered qualification that Wilhelm Röpke’s early work is “proto-Keynesian.” By focusing on his 1936 Crises and Cycles and previous publications, Fèvre shows that Röpke attempted a synthesis by drawing upon various inspirations in business cycle theory. The major impulses stemmed from J.M. Keynes, with concepts from the period before his General Theory, and F.A. Hayek, both of whom in Fèvre’s assessment were equally important for Röpke regarding different phases of the business cycle. Röpke’s innovative approach to the secondary depression and “liberal interventionism” as a possible solution for this depression type receive further attention. Moreover, Röpke’s political insights from the same publications help to understand why Röpke’s latest works were characterized by such a virulent anti-Keynesianism.

Dont have a licence yet? Then find out more about our products and how to get one now:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Footnotes
1
Within a broader perspective, the study directed by Peter E. Hall (1989) on The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations showed how Western countries’ countercyclical fiscal policies combatting unemployment were developed primarily without any reference to Keynes. Franklin D. Roosevelt’s New Deal is an obvious example, but other examples can be found in Sweden, France, and Italy (see also Bateman, 2006, pp. 283–286).
 
2
Between 1932 and 1936, a series of publications—Röpke (1933, 1934, 1935a, 1936c, 1936d)—can be traced where he specified certain aspects of his business cycle theory.
 
3
For a recent account, see Hagemann (2013, pp. 45–47).
 
4
If Röpke “cannot help feeling deep sympathy with the general trend of ideas of the psychological school” of which Arthur C. Pigou is the main exponent (Röpke 1936a, p. 97), he rejected it as a proper explanation of the business cycle on the basis of two interrelated arguments. First, psychological factors do not concern the ultimate causes of the ups and downs of the cycle but constitute mere adjunction to oscillations. Second, the ultimate causes are to be found in fluctuations in “real facts of economic life” (such as the value of money, costs or prices, income structure, etc.) and the “real task consists in showing how these psychological events connect up as a whole” (Röpke 1936a, p. 96).
 
5
Röpke (1936c, p. 325) gave credit especially to John M. Clark (1917) for having developed this concept.
 
6
For the controversy between Hayek, Sraffa, and Keynes following the publication of Prices and Production, see Kurz (2000).
 
7
Röpke gave a good explanation of that plan in his “Trends in German Business Cycle Policy”: “What in effect the plan amounted to was that the most burdensome taxes (business taxes, turnover tax, etc.), while not actually abolished, were transformed into liquid assets. The whole system was rather complicated, but its meaning can be summed up by saying that in the place of certain taxes, a forced loan was instituted, the titles to which, thanks to the collaboration of the banking system, could be sold or employed as collateral. In other words, a certain amount of taxes were virtually abolished, but the financial burden of this abolition was temporarily shifted from the state to the banking system, which would expand credit to the corresponding extent. This assumed that business men would employ their Steuergutscheine, not for paying off or consolidating old debts—improving their own liquidity, as it were—but for making new investments in working or in fixed capital” (Röpke 1933, p. 432, emphasis in the original).
 
8
For the search for consensus in the business cycle theory in the 1930s, see Boianovsky and Trautwein (2006).
 
9
See also Ellis (1938).
 
Literature
go back to reference Backhaus JG (1985) Keynesianism in Germany. In: Lawson T, Pesaran H (eds) Keynes’ economics: methodological issues. Routledge, London, pp 209–253 Backhaus JG (1985) Keynesianism in Germany. In: Lawson T, Pesaran H (eds) Keynes’ economics: methodological issues. Routledge, London, pp 209–253
go back to reference Backhaus JG (1997) Keynes’ German contenders 1932–1944: on the sociology of multiple discovery in economics. Hist Econ Ideas 5(2):69–84 Backhaus JG (1997) Keynes’ German contenders 1932–1944: on the sociology of multiple discovery in economics. Hist Econ Ideas 5(2):69–84
go back to reference Bateman BW (2006) Keynes and Keynesianism. In: Backhouse RE, Bateman BW (eds) The Cambridge companion to Keynes. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 271–290CrossRef Bateman BW (2006) Keynes and Keynesianism. In: Backhouse RE, Bateman BW (eds) The Cambridge companion to Keynes. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 271–290CrossRef
go back to reference Blümle G, Goldschmidt N (2006) From economic stability to social order: The debate about business cycle theory in the 1920s and its relevance for the development of theories of social order by Lowe, Hayek and Eucken. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 13(4):543–570 Blümle G, Goldschmidt N (2006) From economic stability to social order: The debate about business cycle theory in the 1920s and its relevance for the development of theories of social order by Lowe, Hayek and Eucken. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 13(4):543–570
go back to reference Boianovsky M, Trautwein H-M (2006) Haberler, the League of Nations, and the quest for consensus in business cycle theory in the 1930s. Hist Polit Econ 38(1):45–89CrossRef Boianovsky M, Trautwein H-M (2006) Haberler, the League of Nations, and the quest for consensus in business cycle theory in the 1930s. Hist Polit Econ 38(1):45–89CrossRef
go back to reference Clark JM (1917) Business acceleration and the law of demand: a technical factor in economic cycles. J Polit Econ 25(3):217–235CrossRef Clark JM (1917) Business acceleration and the law of demand: a technical factor in economic cycles. J Polit Econ 25(3):217–235CrossRef
go back to reference Commun P (2014) German ordoliberalism: order vs. disorder in Röpke’s early works. Rivista i-lex 9(21):27–39 Commun P (2014) German ordoliberalism: order vs. disorder in Röpke’s early works. Rivista i-lex 9(21):27–39
go back to reference Dostaler G, Maris B (2009) Capitalisme et pulsion de mort. Albin Michel, Paris Dostaler G, Maris B (2009) Capitalisme et pulsion de mort. Albin Michel, Paris
go back to reference Ellis HS (1936) Review of crises and cycles, Wilhelm Röpke. Am Econ Rev 26(4):762–764 Ellis HS (1936) Review of crises and cycles, Wilhelm Röpke. Am Econ Rev 26(4):762–764
go back to reference Ellis HS (1938) Notes on recent business-cycle literature. Rev Econ Stat 20(3):111–119CrossRef Ellis HS (1938) Notes on recent business-cycle literature. Rev Econ Stat 20(3):111–119CrossRef
go back to reference Fèvre R (2015) Du libéralisme historique à la crise sociale du XXe siècle : la lecture de Wilhelm Röpke. Revue économique 66(5):901–932CrossRef Fèvre R (2015) Du libéralisme historique à la crise sociale du XXe siècle : la lecture de Wilhelm Röpke. Revue économique 66(5):901–932CrossRef
go back to reference Garvy G (1975) Keynes and the economic activists of pre-Hitler Germany. J Polit Econ 83(2):391–405CrossRef Garvy G (1975) Keynes and the economic activists of pre-Hitler Germany. J Polit Econ 83(2):391–405CrossRef
go back to reference Haberler G (1943) Prospérité et dépression: étude théorique des cycles économiques. Société des Nations Service d’études économiques, Geneva Haberler G (1943) Prospérité et dépression: étude théorique des cycles économiques. Société des Nations Service d’études économiques, Geneva
go back to reference Hagemann H (2013) Germany after World War II: Ordoliberalism, the Social Market Economy and Keynesianism. Hist Econ Thought Pol 1(1):37–51 Hagemann H (2013) Germany after World War II: Ordoliberalism, the Social Market Economy and Keynesianism. Hist Econ Thought Pol 1(1):37–51
go back to reference Hall PA (ed) (1989) The political power of economic ideas: Keynesianism across nations. Princeton University Press, Princeton Hall PA (ed) (1989) The political power of economic ideas: Keynesianism across nations. Princeton University Press, Princeton
go back to reference Hayek FA (1931) Prices and production. Routledge, London Hayek FA (1931) Prices and production. Routledge, London
go back to reference Hayek FA (1944) The road to serfdom, reprinted in: Caldwell BJ (ed) (2007) The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol 2. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Hayek FA (1944) The road to serfdom, reprinted in: Caldwell BJ (ed) (2007) The collected works of F. A. Hayek, vol 2. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
go back to reference Hudson M (1985) German economists and the depression of 1929–1933. Hist Polit Econ 17(1):35–50CrossRef Hudson M (1985) German economists and the depression of 1929–1933. Hist Polit Econ 17(1):35–50CrossRef
go back to reference Keynes JM (1930) A treatise on money: the applied theory of money. Reprinted in: Johnson E, Moggridge D (eds) (1973) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 6. Macmillan, London Keynes JM (1930) A treatise on money: the applied theory of money. Reprinted in: Johnson E, Moggridge D (eds) (1973) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 6. Macmillan, London
go back to reference Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Reprinted in: Johnson E, Moggridge D (eds) (1973) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 7. Macmillan, London Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Reprinted in: Johnson E, Moggridge D (eds) (1973) The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 7. Macmillan, London
go back to reference Klausinger H (1999) German anticipations of the Keynesian revolution?: The case of Lautenbach, Neisser and Röpke. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 6(3):378–403CrossRef Klausinger H (1999) German anticipations of the Keynesian revolution?: The case of Lautenbach, Neisser and Röpke. Eur J Hist Econ Thought 6(3):378–403CrossRef
go back to reference Kolev S (2010) F. A. Hayek as an ordo-liberal. HWWI Research Paper 5–11, Hamburg Institute of International Economics, Hamburg Kolev S (2010) F. A. Hayek as an ordo-liberal. HWWI Research Paper 5–11, Hamburg Institute of International Economics, Hamburg
go back to reference Kurz HD (2000) The Hayek-Keynes-Sraffa controversy reconsidered. In: Kurz HD (ed) Critical essays on Piero Sraffa’s legacy in economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 257–302CrossRef Kurz HD (2000) The Hayek-Keynes-Sraffa controversy reconsidered. In: Kurz HD (ed) Critical essays on Piero Sraffa’s legacy in economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 257–302CrossRef
go back to reference Magliulo A (2016) Hayek and the Great Depression of 1929: did he really change his mind? Eur J Hist Econ Thought 23(1):31–58CrossRef Magliulo A (2016) Hayek and the Great Depression of 1929: did he really change his mind? Eur J Hist Econ Thought 23(1):31–58CrossRef
go back to reference Meade JE (1936) Review of “Crises and Cycles” by Wilhelm Röpke. Econ J 46(184):694–695CrossRef Meade JE (1936) Review of “Crises and Cycles” by Wilhelm Röpke. Econ J 46(184):694–695CrossRef
go back to reference Olsen AH (2015) Wilhelm Röpke and Richard C. Koo on secondary deflations and balance sheet recessions. Econ Aff 35(2):215–224CrossRef Olsen AH (2015) Wilhelm Röpke and Richard C. Koo on secondary deflations and balance sheet recessions. Econ Aff 35(2):215–224CrossRef
go back to reference Peukert H (1992) Das sozialökonomische Werk Wilhelm Röpkes. Peter Lang, Frankfurt Peukert H (1992) Das sozialökonomische Werk Wilhelm Röpkes. Peter Lang, Frankfurt
go back to reference Robertson DH (1936) Review of “Crises and Cycles” by Wilhelm Röpke. Economica 3(12):476–478CrossRef Robertson DH (1936) Review of “Crises and Cycles” by Wilhelm Röpke. Economica 3(12):476–478CrossRef
go back to reference Röpke W (1932) Krise und Konjunktur. Quelle & Meyer, Leipzig Röpke W (1932) Krise und Konjunktur. Quelle & Meyer, Leipzig
go back to reference Röpke W (1933) Trends in German business cycle policy. Econ J 43(171):427–441CrossRef Röpke W (1933) Trends in German business cycle policy. Econ J 43(171):427–441CrossRef
go back to reference Röpke W (1934) Kapitalismus und Imperialismus. Zeitschrift für Schweizerische Statistik und Volkswirtschaft 70(4):370–386 Röpke W (1934) Kapitalismus und Imperialismus. Zeitschrift für Schweizerische Statistik und Volkswirtschaft 70(4):370–386
go back to reference Röpke W (1935b) Letter to L. Robbins, December 22 LSE Archive: ROBBINS/3/1/2 Röpke W (1935b) Letter to L. Robbins, December 22 LSE Archive: ROBBINS/3/1/2
go back to reference Röpke W (1936a) Crises and cycles. William Hodge, London Röpke W (1936a) Crises and cycles. William Hodge, London
go back to reference Röpke W (1936b) Letter to L. Robbins, May 6. LSE Archive: ROBBINS/3/1/2 Röpke W (1936b) Letter to L. Robbins, May 6. LSE Archive: ROBBINS/3/1/2
go back to reference Röpke W (1936c) Socialism, planning, and the business cycle. J Polit Econ 44(3):318–338CrossRef Röpke W (1936c) Socialism, planning, and the business cycle. J Polit Econ 44(3):318–338CrossRef
go back to reference Röpke W (1936d) Tendances actuelles de l’économie politique. Revue d’Économie Politique 50(4):1284–1307 Röpke W (1936d) Tendances actuelles de l’économie politique. Revue d’Économie Politique 50(4):1284–1307
go back to reference Röpke W (1937) Explanatory note on the review of Röpke’s “Crises and Cycles”. Am Econ Rev 27(1):108–109 Röpke W (1937) Explanatory note on the review of Röpke’s “Crises and Cycles”. Am Econ Rev 27(1):108–109
go back to reference Röpke W (1942) Die Gesellschaftskrisis der Gegenwart. Eugen Rentsch, Erlenbach-Zurich. English edition: Röpke W (1950) The social crisis of our time. University of Chicago Press, Chicago Röpke W (1942) Die Gesellschaftskrisis der Gegenwart. Eugen Rentsch, Erlenbach-Zurich. English edition: Röpke W (1950) The social crisis of our time. University of Chicago Press, Chicago
go back to reference Solchany J (2015) Wilhelm Röpke, l’autre Hayek. Aux origines du néolibéralisme. Publications de la Sorbonne, Paris Solchany J (2015) Wilhelm Röpke, l’autre Hayek. Aux origines du néolibéralisme. Publications de la Sorbonne, Paris
go back to reference Tooze JA (2001) Statistics and the German state, 1900–1945: the making of modern economic knowledge. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Tooze JA (2001) Statistics and the German state, 1900–1945: the making of modern economic knowledge. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
go back to reference Tribe K (1995) Strategies of economic order: German economic discourse, 1750–1950. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef Tribe K (1995) Strategies of economic order: German economic discourse, 1750–1950. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRef
Metadata
Title
Was Wilhelm Röpke Really a Proto-Keynesian?
Author
Raphaël Fèvre
Copyright Year
2018
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-68357-7_7