Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 1-2/2022

07.06.2022

Evolution, uncertainty, and the asymptotic efficiency of policy

verfasst von: Brian C. Albrecht, Joshua R. Hendrickson, Alexander William Salter

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 1-2/2022

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Politics, like any social system, involves selection mechanisms. This paper presents a model of politics as an evolutionary process. Our model yields three main results. First, the political process selects for efficient policies in the long run. We call that attribute asymptotic efficiency. Second, bargaining amongst interest groups bounds the inefficiencies that can exist in the short run. Potential inefficiency declines when organizing interest groups becomes less costly. Finally, policies that appear to be inefficient in a static analysis can be efficient once economists consider the dynamic nature of political decisions. We argue that viewing the political process as a selection mechanism allows political economists to use efficiency as a criterion for positive economic analysis. In our approach, applied political economy involves looking for relevant costs that make the policy efficient. However, our approach does not rob political economists of the ability to make meaningful normative statements; it only constrains the type of statements made.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
See IGM Forum (n.d.).
 
2
While many definitions of “efficiency” are possible and it is not always clear what individual authors have in mind, we mean Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, whereby an outcome is efficient if the benefits outweigh the costs and could, in principle, involve transfers to make the policy Pareto efficient, whether or not those who benefit actually compensate anyone. Buchanan (1959) discusses criticisms of Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, notably that side-payments (compensation) to those who lose from policy changes are almost always hypothetical. Without actual compensation, "the whole controversy over the appropriate tests [for welfare-enhancing policy] becomes meaningless" (Buchanan, 1959, p. 128). Our arguments extend Buchanan's insight. We discuss Buchanan's (1959) paradigm for doing welfare economics more fully in the Conclusion. However, in our model, compensation is paid, so the distinction does not matter: Kaldor-Hicks efficient policies are Pareto efficient.
 
3
By efficiency, we are referring to what we call “planner efficiency”. In doing so, we follow how most economists use the term, which implicitly ignores the political costs of implementing a policy. Our result that policies are efficient (in that sense) in the long run is stronger than saying that they are efficient once we account for all costs, a criterion adopted by Cheung (1998) and Leeson (2020), among others. We elaborate on the distinction in the next section.
 
4
We could similarly assume that political actors maximize some measure of “political success”, such as votes. However, for simplicity, we assume that they maximize wealth, since the rest of our analysis is framed in terms net of simple cost and benefits.
 
5
While it is referred to as the “Coase” theorem, the theorem is credited to George Stigler and bears little resemblance to Coase’s interpretation of his own paper. See, e.g., Medema (1994), McCloskey (1998) and Albrecht and Kogelmann (2020). On the application of the Coase theorem to politics, see Acemoglu (2003), Parisi (2003), and Munger (2019).
 
6
Note that we have assumed that \(\mu \ge 0\). If \(\mu <0\), then the net costs of the policy would have a negative drift over time and eventually would be insignificant without any action needed.
 
7
Multiplying both side of the discrete time representation by \(1+\rho \Delta t\) and rearranging yields.
$$\rho V\left(N\right)=\frac{1}{\Delta t}EdV,$$
where \(EdV:=EV(N{^{\prime}},t+\Delta t)-V(N,t)\). Taking the limit as \(\Delta t\) goes to zero yields the continuous time representation.
 
8
For recent work, see Brendon (2013), Lockwood and Weinzierl (2015), Lockwood and Weinzierl (2016), and Heathcote and Tsujiyama (2021).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652.CrossRef Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(4), 620–652.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611.CrossRef Aghion, P., Alesina, A., & Trebbi, F. (2004). Endogenous political institutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(2), 565–611.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221.CrossRef Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ashworth, S. (2012). Electoral accountability: Recent theoretical and empirical work. Annual Review of Political Science, 15(1), 183–201.CrossRef Ashworth, S. (2012). Electoral accountability: Recent theoretical and empirical work. Annual Review of Political Science, 15(1), 183–201.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barbera, S., & Jackson, M. O. (2004). Choosing how to choose: Self-stable majority rules and constitutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 1011–1048.CrossRef Barbera, S., & Jackson, M. O. (2004). Choosing how to choose: Self-stable majority rules and constitutions. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 1011–1048.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Baron, D. P. (1994). Electoral competition with informed and uniformed voters. The American Political Science Review, 88(1), 33–47.CrossRef Baron, D. P. (1994). Electoral competition with informed and uniformed voters. The American Political Science Review, 88(1), 33–47.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bassetto, M., & Sargent, T. J. (2006). Politics and efficiency of separating capital and ordinary government budgets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1167–1210. Bassetto, M., & Sargent, T. J. (2006). Politics and efficiency of separating capital and ordinary government budgets. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1167–1210.
Zurück zum Zitat Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.CrossRef Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3), 371–400.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). Saving government failure theory from itself: Recasting political economy from an Austrian perspective. Constitutional Political Economy, 18(2), 127–143.CrossRef Boettke, P. J., Coyne, C. J., & Leeson, P. T. (2007). Saving government failure theory from itself: Recasting political economy from an Austrian perspective. Constitutional Political Economy, 18(2), 127–143.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Breton, A. (1993). Toward a presumption of efficiency in politics. Public Choice, 77(1), 53–65.CrossRef Breton, A. (1993). Toward a presumption of efficiency in politics. Public Choice, 77(1), 53–65.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy, 57(6), 496–505.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M. (1949). The pure theory of government finance: A suggested approach. Journal of Political Economy, 57(6), 496–505.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. The Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M. (1959). Positive economics, welfare economics, and political economy. The Journal of Law and Economics, 2, 124–138.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1975). A contractarian paradigm for applying economic theory. The American Economic Review, 65(2), 225–230. Buchanan, J. M. (1975). A contractarian paradigm for applying economic theory. The American Economic Review, 65(2), 225–230.
Zurück zum Zitat Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. Science, 236(4807), 1433–1436.CrossRef Buchanan, J. M. (1987). The constitution of economic policy. Science, 236(4807), 1433–1436.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54(3), 607–622.CrossRef Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54(3), 607–622.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chetty, R., Hendren, N., & Katz, L. F. (2016). The effects of exposure to better neighborhoods on children: New evidence from the moving to opportunity experiment. American Economic Review, 106(4), 855–902.CrossRef Chetty, R., Hendren, N., & Katz, L. F. (2016). The effects of exposure to better neighborhoods on children: New evidence from the moving to opportunity experiment. American Economic Review, 106(4), 855–902.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheung, S. (1968). Private property rights and sharecropping. Journal of Political Economy, 76(6), 1107–1122.CrossRef Cheung, S. (1968). Private property rights and sharecropping. Journal of Political Economy, 76(6), 1107–1122.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheung, S. (1970). The structure of a contract and the theory of a non-exclusive resource. The Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), 49–70.CrossRef Cheung, S. (1970). The structure of a contract and the theory of a non-exclusive resource. The Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), 49–70.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheung, S. (1973). The fable of the bees: An economic investigation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 11–33.CrossRef Cheung, S. (1973). The fable of the bees: An economic investigation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 11–33.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cheung, S. (1998). The transaction costs paradigm. Economic Inquiry, 36(4), 514–521.CrossRef Cheung, S. (1998). The transaction costs paradigm. Economic Inquiry, 36(4), 514–521.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clemens, M. A. (2011). Economics and emigration: Trillion-dollar bills on the sidewalk? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 83–106.CrossRef Clemens, M. A. (2011). Economics and emigration: Trillion-dollar bills on the sidewalk? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 25(3), 83–106.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef Coase, R. H. (1960). The problem of social cost. The Journal of Law & Economics, 3, 1–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. The American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27. Diamond, P. A., & Mirrlees, J. A. (1971). Optimal taxation and public production I: Production efficiency. The American Economic Review, 61(1), 8–27.
Zurück zum Zitat Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Harper Collins. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. Harper Collins.
Zurück zum Zitat Duggan, J., & Martinelli, C. (2017). The political economy of dynamic elections: Accountability, commitment, and responsiveness. Journal of Economic Literature, 55(3), 916–984.CrossRef Duggan, J., & Martinelli, C. (2017). The political economy of dynamic elections: Accountability, commitment, and responsiveness. Journal of Economic Literature, 55(3), 916–984.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. Yale University Press. Fiorina, M. P. (1981). Retrospective voting in American national elections. Yale University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Fox, J. (2007). Government transparency and policymaking. Public Choice, 131(1/2), 23–44.CrossRef Fox, J. (2007). Government transparency and policymaking. Public Choice, 131(1/2), 23–44.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2007). The evolution of common law. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 43–68.CrossRef Gennaioli, N., & Shleifer, A. (2007). The evolution of common law. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 43–68.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. The Review of Economic Studies, 70(3), 569–587.CrossRef Golosov, M., Kocherlakota, N., & Tsyvinski, A. (2003). Optimal indirect and capital taxation. The Review of Economic Studies, 70(3), 569–587.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral competition and special interest politics. The Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 265–286.CrossRef Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral competition and special interest politics. The Review of Economic Studies, 63(2), 265–286.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Heathcote, J., & Tsujiyama, H. (2021). Optimal income taxation: Mirrlees meets Ramsey. Journal of Political Economy, 129(11), 3141–3184.CrossRef Heathcote, J., & Tsujiyama, H. (2021). Optimal income taxation: Mirrlees meets Ramsey. Journal of Political Economy, 129(11), 3141–3184.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hendrickson, J. R. (2019). U.S. maritime policy and economic efficiency (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3486330). Social Science Research Network. Hendrickson, J. R. (2019). U.S. maritime policy and economic efficiency (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3486330). Social Science Research Network.
Zurück zum Zitat Hendrickson, J. R. (2020). Usury enforcement as an alternative to capital taxation in pre-modern states (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3652489). Social Science Research Network. Hendrickson, J. R. (2020). Usury enforcement as an alternative to capital taxation in pre-modern states (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. 3652489). Social Science Research Network.
Zurück zum Zitat Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W., & Albrecht, B. C. (2018). Preventing plunder: Military technology, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 58, 154–173.CrossRef Hendrickson, J. R., Salter, A. W., & Albrecht, B. C. (2018). Preventing plunder: Military technology, capital accumulation, and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 58, 154–173.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28(1), 59–83.CrossRef Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28(1), 59–83.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Keen, M., & Wildasin, D. (2004). Pareto-efficient international taxation. American Economic Review, 94(1), 259–275.CrossRef Keen, M., & Wildasin, D. (2004). Pareto-efficient international taxation. American Economic Review, 94(1), 259–275.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2012). Ordeals. The Journal of Law and Economics, 55(3), 691–714.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2012). Ordeals. The Journal of Law and Economics, 55(3), 691–714.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeson, P. T. (2020). Logic is a harsh mistress: Welfare economics for economists. Journal of Institutional Economics, 16(2), 145–150.CrossRef Leeson, P. T. (2020). Logic is a harsh mistress: Welfare economics for economists. Journal of Institutional Economics, 16(2), 145–150.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2015). De gustibus non est taxandum: Heterogeneity in preferences and optimal redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 124, 74–80.CrossRef Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2015). De gustibus non est taxandum: Heterogeneity in preferences and optimal redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 124, 74–80.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2016). Positive and normative judgments implicit in U.S. tax policy, and the costs of unequal growth and recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 30–47.CrossRef Lockwood, B. B., & Weinzierl, M. (2016). Positive and normative judgments implicit in U.S. tax policy, and the costs of unequal growth and recessions. Journal of Monetary Economics, 77, 30–47.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lohmann, S. (1998). An information rationale for the power of special interests. The American Political Science Review, 92(4), 809–827.CrossRef Lohmann, S. (1998). An information rationale for the power of special interests. The American Political Science Review, 92(4), 809–827.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2004). The politician and the judge: Accountability in government. American Economic Review, 94(4), 1034–1054.CrossRef Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2004). The politician and the judge: Accountability in government. American Economic Review, 94(4), 1034–1054.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McCloskey, D. (1998). The so-called Coase theorem. Eastern Economic Journal, 24(3), 367–371. McCloskey, D. (1998). The so-called Coase theorem. Eastern Economic Journal, 24(3), 367–371.
Zurück zum Zitat McCormick, R. E., Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1984). The disinterest in deregulation. The American Economic Review, 74(5), 1075–1079. McCormick, R. E., Shughart, W. F., & Tollison, R. D. (1984). The disinterest in deregulation. The American Economic Review, 74(5), 1075–1079.
Zurück zum Zitat Medema, S. G. (1994). The myth of two Coases: What Coase is really saying. Journal of Economic Issues, 28(1), 208–217.CrossRef Medema, S. G. (1994). The myth of two Coases: What Coase is really saying. Journal of Economic Issues, 28(1), 208–217.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Munger, M. C. (2019). Tullock and the welfare costs of corruption: There is a “political Coase Theorem.” Public Choice, 181(1), 83–100.CrossRef Munger, M. C. (2019). Tullock and the welfare costs of corruption: There is a “political Coase Theorem.” Public Choice, 181(1), 83–100.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. The American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368. North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. The American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368.
Zurück zum Zitat Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press. Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Parisi, F. (2003). Political Coase theorem. Public Choice, 115(1), 1–36.CrossRef Parisi, F. (2003). Political Coase theorem. Public Choice, 115(1), 1–36.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2), 211–240.CrossRef Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. The Journal of Law & Economics, 19(2), 211–240.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.CrossRef Posner, R. A. (1974). Theories of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 5(2), 335–358.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Priest, G. L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 65–82.CrossRef Priest, G. L. (1977). The common law process and the selection of efficient rules. The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 65–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rubin, P. H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 51–63.CrossRef Rubin, P. H. (1977). Why is the common law efficient? The Journal of Legal Studies, 6(1), 51–63.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). MacMillan Publishing. Stigler, G. J. (1966). The theory of price (3rd ed.). MacMillan Publishing.
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3.CrossRef Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stigler, G. (1992). Law or economics? Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2), 455–468.CrossRef Stigler, G. (1992). Law or economics? Journal of Law and Economics, 35(2), 455–468.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stokey, N. L. (2008). The economics of inaction: Stochastic control models with fixed costs. Princeton University Press.CrossRef Stokey, N. L. (2008). The economics of inaction: Stochastic control models with fixed costs. Princeton University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A. (2008). A rational alternative to social contract theory and correspondingly new theory of optimal government [working paper]. Available from authors upon request. Thompson, E. A. (2008). A rational alternative to social contract theory and correspondingly new theory of optimal government [working paper]. Available from authors upon request.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A. (1974). Taxation and national defense. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 755–782.CrossRef Thompson, E. A. (1974). Taxation and national defense. Journal of Political Economy, 82(4), 755–782.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A. (1979). An economic basis for the “national defense argument” for aiding certain industries. Journal of Political Economy, 87(1), 1–36.CrossRef Thompson, E. A. (1979). An economic basis for the “national defense argument” for aiding certain industries. Journal of Political Economy, 87(1), 1–36.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A., & Faith, R. L. (1981). A pure theory of strategic behavior and social institutions. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 366–380. Thompson, E. A., & Faith, R. L. (1981). A pure theory of strategic behavior and social institutions. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 366–380.
Zurück zum Zitat Thompson, E. A., & Hickson, C. R. (2001). Ideology and the evolution of vital institutions. Springer.CrossRef Thompson, E. A., & Hickson, C. R. (2001). Ideology and the evolution of vital institutions. Springer.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Tollison, R. D. (1988). Public choice and legislation. Virginia Law Review, 74(2), 339–371.CrossRef Tollison, R. D. (1988). Public choice and legislation. Virginia Law Review, 74(2), 339–371.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.CrossRef Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–664.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.CrossRef Wittman, D. (1989). Why democracies produce efficient results. Journal of Political Economy, 97(6), 1395–1424.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Evolution, uncertainty, and the asymptotic efficiency of policy
verfasst von
Brian C. Albrecht
Joshua R. Hendrickson
Alexander William Salter
Publikationsdatum
07.06.2022
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 1-2/2022
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-022-00978-2

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1-2/2022

Public Choice 1-2/2022 Zur Ausgabe