Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Mathematics and Financial Economics 1/2019

Open Access 09.06.2018

Foreign exchange markets with Last Look

verfasst von: Álvaro Cartea, Sebastian Jaimungal, Jamie Walton

Erschienen in: Mathematics and Financial Economics | Ausgabe 1/2019

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We examine the Foreign exchange (FX) spot price spreads with and without Last Look on the transaction. We assume that brokers are risk-neutral and they quote spreads so that losses to latency arbitrageurs are recovered from other traders in the FX market. These losses are reduced if the broker can reject, ex-post, loss-making trades by enforcing the Last Look option which is a feature of some trading venues in FX markets. For a given rejection threshold the risk-neutral broker quotes a spread to the market so that her expected profits are zero. When there is only one venue, we find that the Last Look option reduces quoted spreads. If there are two venues we show that the market reaches an equilibrium where traders have no incentive to migrate. The equilibrium can be reached with both venues coexisting, or with only one venue surviving. Moreover, when one venue enforces Last Look and the other one does not, counterintuitively, it may be the case that the Last Look venue quotes larger spreads.
Hinweise
Sebastian Jaimungal would like to thank NSERC and GRI for partially funding this work. The authors thank C. Alexander, R. Anderson, F. Barnes, E. Benos, J. Danielsson, A. Gerig, PK Jain, C.A. Lehalle, R. Oomen, H. Ralston, Y. Sharaiha, C. Vega, J.P. Zigrand, and seminar participants at the University of Sussex, Norges Bank Investment Management, U.S. Securities Exchange Commission (SEC), U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System Washington DC, 6th Annual Stevens Conference on High-Frequency Finance and Analytics, Market Microstructure CFM-Imperial 2015, the Systemic Risk Centre (LSE), University of Oxford, and the Bank of England for comments on an earlier version of this article.

1 Introduction

The Foreign Exchange (FX) marketplace has some unique structures which have lead to specific solutions for both exchanges and market makers. Unlike equities, there are less than 100 actively traded currencies and many can be traded across multiple platforms simultaneously. As there is no central exchange framework in FX, many Electronic Crossing Networks (ECNs) exist to service trading of currencies. The most common G10 currencies may be available to trade in more than 20 ECNs with multiple liquidity providers. Additionally, most major banks offer access to trade currencies through their own platforms either using an application or over an application programming interface (API) as well as through many ECNs.
In high-frequency trading, liquidity providers making markets on multiple streams are exposed to many risks. The technology race to reduce latency between exchanges has created an opportunity to extract value through latency arbitrage. This can manifest as a fast market participant trading on prices shown by slower liquidity providers in a rapidly updating market, and is not necessarily malicious. However, when the market taker is intentionally trading with the last liquidity provider to update her prices, or on stale quotes, then it may become necessary for the liquidity provider to construct a form of protection to prevent the misuse of her liquidity.
A second concern for market makers is that they frequently show larger liquidity than what they have available. They do this because large market makers display prices/liquidity on multiple ECNs in the fragmented FX marketplace and at the same time provide streaming prices to traders through APIs. This can mean that there exist thousands of potential streams where they are exposed to some notional amount of liquidity. Instantaneously, this liquidity does not represent the prices they are prepared to show in the full amount. Typically, however, if one-sided liquidity starts to be accessed on multiple venues simultaneously, then the market maker updates prices to all streams to reflect the new value of liquidity – and ideally to attract traders to take them out of the risk by crossing some part of the spread. The risk therefore lies on the ability of the market maker to update prices on all streams in a rapid manner and thus is also at risk of latency arbitrage.
Generally, larger size trades have a larger bid-offer spread to represent the additional cost in trading out of the risk. In order to reduce transaction costs some traders may choose to split up a large order into smaller standard size amounts and hit liquidity on multiple venues simultaneously. This reduces the cost for the trader, but exposes liquidity providers to the risk that the market will run away from them as they try to exit this position. In FX this activity is sometimes referred to as ‘spamming the market’.1 The trader may also be accessing the same underlying source of liquidity on multiple venues if the best price on the ECNs is offered by the same provider. This is clearly a problem for the market maker.2
There are some measures that market makers and ECNs can take to limit the exposure to latency arbitrage strategies and to market takers spamming the market. In FX, some ECNs allow liquidity providers ‘Last Look’: after a trader has traded on a market maker’s price then the ‘Last Look’ is a fixed period of time in which the market maker has an option to reject the trade. Generally the trade is rejected if in this fixed period of time the trade moves against the market maker beyond some threshold. The market maker is inferring that the trader may be taking advantage of the liquidity and is essentially withdrawing the price they made to market. Doing so can neutralize the effect of a latency arbitrage as well as providing protection against market spamming, at least over the interval of time that Last Look is active, typically measured in milliseconds. Market makers may also use Last Look trade rejections on price streams provided to traders, particularly for traders who trade at a higher frequency.
In over-the-counter transactions FX brokers stream quotes to a wide range of clients. A key characteristic that differentiates clients is their ability to see quote updates, react to market news, and trade on the most up-to-date public information. Having access to low latency technology is expensive. FX brokers who stream prices recognize that not all clients have the capability of seeing the most recent quote and may come to the market trying to execute a trade on a stale quote at a price which could be advantageous to either the client or the broker. Thus, it is not unusual for brokers to allow trades on stale quotes, despite having streamed a new quote, because she wishes to attract order flow which could convey information that she may use to update her quotes.
The broker cannot discern amongst the different strategies employed by an individual trader, in particular whether the trade is taking advantage of latency. For example, institutional investors often employ many strategies, some of which may involve latency arbitrages. Thus, Last Look is a measure designed for a type of strategy, not for a particular type of trader. In this paper we classify trades as either a latency arbitrage or non-latency arbitrage. We allocate the latency arbitrage trades as the activity emanating from latency arbitrageurs (LAs), and the other trades as activity from slow traders (STs). Clearly, trades from market participants who employ both types of strategies will sometimes be classified as coming from LAs and others from STs. This slight abuse of nomenclature helps to clarify the setup of the model and discussion of the Last Look option in the rest of the paper.
Last Look is a controversial topic in the FX marketplace with some ECNs actively advertising that they do not allow Last Look liquidity providers on their platforms. However it does protect market makers from more aggressive behavior and ultimately, prices offered on Last Look platforms may have lower spreads than on non-Last Look markets. This means that market participants who are not latency arbitraging the market maker are not penalized in the prices they receive, but may still face rejection of some of their trades. For direct pricing streams, employing trade rejection over Last Look also allows market makers to offer more liquidity to traders than they could without such protection. The disadvantage for traders is that they no longer have guaranteed fills when they go to market and, more pertinently, the rejected trades generally are the ones that have gone in their favor, at least over the Last Look time interval.
FX market makers are exposed to being picked-off if they do not update their quotes quickly. However, some FX brokers willingly allow trades on stale quotes (e.g. in over-the-counter and quote streaming set-ups), but this is not a free option available to liquidity takers. FX brokers ‘charge’ for the option, to be hit/lifted on stale quotes, by rejecting trades through the Last Look mechanism—see [2] who discuss firm quotes as free options given to market takers.
Our paper and the contemporaneous work of [7] are the first to examine FX spot price spreads with and without Last Look on the transaction, see also and [6]. We model latency arbitrage by allowing the market taker to trade on a stale quote, which in FX markets is a quote that is no longer valid either because the liquidity provider has sent an updated quote, or because the market has moved since the liquidity provider made the price. We consider the value to the liquidity provider of having the option to reject a quote over the Last Look interval given that there is a target rejection threshold which affects all traders.
We assume that market makers or brokers are risk-neutral and competition drives spreads so that expected profits from dealing in the FX market are zero. Brokers cannot observe the type of trade they are facing, so rejection affects all traders: LAs, who only trade on stale quotes which produce an immediate risk-less positive profit, and STs, who are not (latency) arbitraging the market. The brokers reject trades that generate losses greater than a predetermined threshold. These losses are calculated ex-post using the price update after the trader executed his order. As expected, the right to cancel trades over the rejection window caps brokers’ losses, so everything else equal, quoted spreads decrease.
We show that in markets where there is price momentum, i.e. price revisions are positively correlated (such as what occurs when there is spamming in the market), the broker’s rejection rule is more effective at singling out latency arbitrage trades. Thus, everything else equal, when there is momentum in prices, spreads are tighter. Conversely, when price revisions are negatively correlated, prices mean revert and it is more difficult for the broker to single out loss-leading trades whose counterparty are LAs, hence spreads widen.
Tighter spreads have different effects on market participants. LAs have more opportunities to attempt an arbitrage (on stale quotes), because spreads are tighter and therefore LAs can take advantage of smaller price movements, but they also face higher rejection rates and overall they are worse off in markets with the Last Look option. On the other hand, the STs benefit from lower spreads, but face rejection of their most profitable trades, so depending on market parameters, how STs account for the foregone profits of rejected trades, and other rejection costs, they will seek or avoid trading in venues with Last Look.
Is there an optimal spread? In a market where there is only one venue to trade, the risk-neutral brokers are indifferent between making markets with or without the Last Look option because spreads are determined by the zero expected profit condition. On the other hand, when STs account for rejection costs, our results show that there is an optimal spread that minimizes the STs’ costs of executing round-trip trades. In addition to the spread that STs pay when executing trades, the rejection costs include: forgone profits; immediacy costs which are high if the ST requires immediate and guaranteed execution; the additional cost arising from returning to the market to execute the trade; and, arguably, the potential exposure to front-running costs.
When there is more than one FX venue, traders migrate to those where they are better off: LAs migrate to venues where the expected profit of a round-trip trade is highest, and STs to those where the expected cost of a round-trip trade is lowest. Quoted spreads depend on a number of factors which are specific to each venue: rejection rule, and proportion of LAs. We show that there is an equilibrium region where there are no incentives to migrate and also examine cases in which the equilibrium region is a corner solution where only one FX venue survives, i.e. one venue attracts all order flow from both types of traders as well as all market makers.
In particular we discuss the two-venue case where in one venue brokers employ the Last Look option, while the other venue does not allow market makers to enforce Last Look. We show that there are two distinctive regions (defined by pairs of numbers of LAs and STs trading in each venue), where traders have incentives to migrate and the equilibrium reached is either both venues coexist or only one survives. When the market’s starting point is in the region where the venue with Last Look starts off with a low proportion of LAs, then equilibrium is reached when all traders exit the venue without Last Look, i.e. all order flow occurs in the venue that employs a rejection rule.
The other region is one where the venue without Last Look starts with a low proportion of LAs (so the venue with Last Look has a high proportion of LAs). In this case, LAs find it optimal to migrate to the venue without Last Look. Thus the brokers in the venue without Last Look increase spreads to recover the losses to LAs, but this increases the STs’ trading costs, so some of them migrate to the venue with Last Look, but do so at a rate lower than that at which LAs flow into the venue without Last Look. Equilibrium is reached at a point where both venues coexist (apart from very extreme cases where the starting point is one where most LAs are concentrated in one venue). Interestingly, when both venues coexist the Last Look venue does not always quote the lowest spread.
When traders switch between venues they incur a fixed cost. In the over-the-counter FX market, this fixed cost includes ‘reputational’ costs to build a relationship with the market maker, and software set-up costs to connect to other exchanges and counterparties. We show that when migration costs are very low, the market settles to an equilibrium where only one venue survives and this outcome depends on the starting point, but in most cases all traders migrate to the venue which enforces Last Look.
Finally, the Last Look feature in FX markets is in the spotlight of regulators and financial authorities. This paper provides a framework to analyze the provision of liquidity and immediacy in a market where some venues enforce rejection of trades. For example, in a recent consultation document, the Bank of England (joint with the HM Treasury and the Financial Conduct Authority) express the concern raised by some market participants who “have argued that such practices may also incentivize market makers to delay a decision for longer periods in order to observe market moves and reject unprofitable trades or even engage in front-running of orders.”, [1]. This paper provides a framework to understand how FX venues with different rejection rules set spreads to the market, thus providing a price for immediacy in the market, and how market participants choose venues for their trades.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. In Sect. 2 we present the model for the dynamics of exchange rates and show how a risk-neutral broker sets optimal spreads in a market consisting of LAs and STs. In Sect. 3 we develop the model further to allow the broker to enforce the Last Look option to cancel trades ex-post and determine the optimal spread quoted in the market. In Sect. 4 we model how STs impute costs to rejected trades and compute the optimal spread (hence the rejection threshold) that minimizes the costs that STs are exposed to. In Sect. 6 we discuss how the market reaches equilibrium when there is more than one FX venue. Finally, Sect. 7 concludes and proofs are collected in the “Appendix”.

2 Optimal spreads without Last Look

We assume that brokers are risk-neutral and operate in a competitive market, so that the expected profits of round-trip trades is zero. In addition, brokers do not incur any fees or other variable costs to operate in the market. The midprice, i.e. the exchange rate between two currencies, follows a stochastic process which is observed by all market participants. There are three time markers \(i=0,1,2\), the midprice is denoted by \(P_i\), \(P^a_i\) denotes the ask, \(P^b_i\) the bid. The spread is given by \(\Delta = P^a_i- P^b_i \ge 0 \) and is determined by the brokers’ zero-expected profit condition. Point \(i=0\) corresponds to the initial time when the broker posts a quote, \(i=1\) corresponds to the time when the broker updates the quote, and \(i=2\) corresponds to the time at which the broker decides whether to accept or reject the trade if there is a Last Look option. All trades are of one unit.
Throughout this paper the spread arises from the brokers’ need to break-even when trading with market participants who arbitrage stale quotes.3 In general, the difference between the bid and ask is explained by the various risks that the market maker or broker faces when intermediating trades, e.g. adverse selection and inventory risk, see for instance [35]. Here, we focus on the effect that LAs have on spreads, and one could include these other effects, which would widen the spreads.
Innovations in the midprice are given by
$$\begin{aligned} P_{i+1}-P_i =\sigma \,Z_{i+1}\,, \end{aligned}$$
where \(\sigma \) is a positive constant, the price revisions \(Z_1\) and \(Z_2\) are correlated standard normal random variables, with correlation coefficient \(\rho \), and we write,
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{pmatrix} Z_1 \\ Z_2 \end{pmatrix} \sim {\mathcal {N}}\left( \begin{pmatrix} 0 \\ 0 \end{pmatrix}, \begin{pmatrix} 1 &{} \rho \\ \rho &{} 1 \end{pmatrix}\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
Positive correlation, \(\rho >0\), corresponds to a period of trading where prices are trending up/down, while negative correlation, \(\rho <0\), corresponds to a time of mean-reversion of prices. Naturally, there is no trend in prices when correlation is zero. In this section the broker does not have the Last Look option to veto trades ex-post, so the second price increment is irrelevant, it will however play an important role when this option is incorporated in Sect. 3.
When there is spamming in the market, i.e. when an LA takes liquidity from multiple venues simultaneously, price updates reflect this type of market activity by moving in the direction of the trade. Consider the case of an LA submitting buy orders over multiple venues (and possibly from different brokers) simultaneously. Several brokers will then be left with excessive short positions that they must unwind. To do so, the brokers will either take liquidity and thus add to overall buying pressure in the market resulting in upward price movements; and/or adjust their bids (and hence also asks) upwards to entice other traders to offset their short position. The end result is that prices move upwards and this pressure can persist over multiple periods depending on the size of the total short position the brokers found themselves in. A similar argument follows if the LA submits sell orders over multiple venues simultaneously, resulting in a downward trend in prices. Overall, spamming in the market induces positive correlation between price increments.
All brokers send quote updates at the beginning of every period i and traders decide if they want to trade. The market is populated by two types of traders: STs and LAs. STs do not possess the technology to always observe the updates that the brokers post. LAs have the speed and technology to see, and act on, all quote updates to the market.
The brokers cannot differentiate trader type, but know that a proportion \(\alpha \in [0,1]\) of traders are LAs, and know that STs observe the updated quote (at \(i=1\)) with probability \(\beta \). The brokers wish to do business with STs, so they allow all market participants to trade on stale quotes. This may happen in two ways. (i) At time \(i=1\) a broker updates her quotes to \(P^a_1=P_1+\frac{\Delta }{2}\) and \(P^b_1=P_1-\frac{\Delta }{2}\), but will honor trades at the stale quotes \(P^{a,b}_0\). (ii) At time \(i=1\) the market has moved and a broker did not update her quotes and will honor trades at the stale quotes \(P^{a,b}_0\). In the sequel, a trade on a stale quote refers to either one of these cases. Throughout we refer to \(\alpha \) as the proportion of traders, but could also be interpreted as the ratio of latency arbitrage trades to the total number of trades in the FX market.
An ST always trades at the quotes he sees, whether stale or not. LAs will always trade at the most favorable quote for him, stale or new. Thus, brokers are exposed to ‘latency losses’ when trading with LAs who take advantage of stale quotes. In equilibrium, brokers set the spread \(\Delta \) to recover these losses.

2.1 Optimal spread

The broker determines the quoted spread so that the expected profit of each round-trip trade, in any given period, is zero. When the broker enters a position at time \(i=1\) the expected profit of the round-trip is calculated using the price at which the first leg of the trade is entered, and the price of the leg to close out the position. The former depends on whether the broker accepted the trade on a stale or updated quote. The latter is either \(P^b_1\), if first leg was a sell, or \(P^a_1\), if the first leg was a buy.
Figure 1 shows quote updates. The size of the spread and the midprice change determine if the LA trades on a stale quote. Cases I and II show arbitrage opportunities executed by LAs. Panel (c) depicts the cases where the midprice change is small enough to preclude latency losses to the broker.
To determine the broker’s optimal spread we first look at the trades where the counterparty is an ST and then when it is an LA.
Trading with STs
Recall that the ST sees the updated quote at \(t=1\) with probability \(\beta \).
  • If the ST receives the updated quote, then the profit to the broker of a round-trip trade is the spread \(\Delta \).
  • If the ST does not receive the updated quote, and therefore trades on the stale quote, the profit to the broker of a round-trip trade is
    $$\begin{aligned} P_1-P_0+\Delta \,. \end{aligned}$$
    Clearly, when the ST trades on a stale quote it will be, unbeknownst to him, at a profit or at a loss.
Trading with LAs
Trades on stale quotes result from options provided by the broker to liquidity takers who exercise them. In equity markets, firm quotes in the limit order book are ‘free’ options given to liquidity takers to pick-off stale quotes. In FX markets with Last Look these options are not free because the broker may reject trades.
Here we list the midprice revisions which expose the broker to latency losses:
  • Case I: If \(P_1^b>P_0^a\), the LA executes a buy at the stale quote, followed by (an instant later) a sell at the updated quote, and the LA receives a net profit of
    $$\begin{aligned} \left( P_1^b-P_0^a\right) _+\,, \end{aligned}$$
    where \((x)_+=\max (0,\, x)\).
  • Case II: If \(P_1^a<P_0^b\), the LA executes a sell at the stale quote, followed by (an instant later) a buy at the updated quote, and the LA receives a net profit of
    $$\begin{aligned} \left( P_0^b-P_1^a\right) _+\,. \end{aligned}$$
And midprice revisions which do not lead to latency losses:
  • Case III: If \(P_1-P_0 \in [- \Delta , \Delta ]\), the LA cannot profit from a round-trip trade and therefore makes no trades.
Putting the above scenarios together, the broker’s expected profits stemming from trading with STs and LAs, respectively, are:
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST}= \beta \,\Delta + (1-\beta )\,{{\mathbb {E}}}_0[P_1-P_0+\Delta ]\,, \end{aligned}$$
(1)
and
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA}={{\mathbb {E}}}_0\left[ \left( P_1^b-P_0^a\right) _+ \, +\, \left( P_0^b-P_1^a\right) _+\right] \,, \end{aligned}$$
(2)
where \({{\mathbb {E}}}_0\) is the expectation operator conditioned on information at time \(i=0\).
Thus, the broker’s expected profits at time \(i=0\) are given by
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega = (1-\alpha )\,\Omega _{ST}\,-\, \alpha \,\Omega _{LA}\,. \end{aligned}$$
(3)
Next, we determine the balancing equation that the spread must satisfy. Recall the broker is risk-neutral and does not incur any fees or other variable costs to make markets. Thus, in equilibrium, the broker sets a spread where the expected profit is zero. We seek the optimal spread by conditioning on type of trader.
First, due to the martingale nature of the price movement over the first period, the expected profit from trading with STs is
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST} = \beta \,\Delta + (1-\beta )\,{{\mathbb {E}}}_0[P_1-P_0+\Delta ] = \Delta \,. \end{aligned}$$
Second, we can rewrite the expected profits from trading with LAs as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA} =&\, {{\mathbb {E}}}_0\left[ \left( P_1^b-P_0^a\right) _+ + \left( P_0^b-P_1^a\right) _+\right] \\ =&\, {{\mathbb {E}}}_0\Big [\left( P_1-P_0-\Delta \right) _+ + \left( P_0-P_1-\Delta \right) _+\Big ] \\ =&\, 2\,{{\mathbb {E}}}_0\Big [\left( P_1-(P_0+ \Delta )\right) _+ \Big ]\,. \end{aligned}$$
In this form, we can interpret the expected profits from trading with LAs as two call options on the midprice struck at the arrival price plus the spread, or alternatively as a single strangle option at the same strike. Since we assume prices are arithmetic, and increments are symmetric, these two options have the same value.
Proposition 1
Losses to Latency Arbitrageurs without Last Look. The broker’s expected losses to LAs are given by
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA} = 2\,\sigma \,\phi \left( \frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\right) -2\,\Delta \,\Phi \left( -\frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
(4)
where \(\phi (\cdot )\) and \(\Phi (\cdot )\) denote the standard normal pdf and cdf, respectively.
Proof
See “Appendix A.1”. \(\square \)
In equilibrium, the broker must break-even so the losses she incurs from trading with LAs must be offset by the gains obtained from trading with STs. Thus, the broker must quote a spread to the market so that \(\Omega =0\), so using (3), the zero-expected profit condition is \(\alpha \,\Omega _{LA} = (1-\alpha )\,\Omega _{ST}\). This is shown in the following corollary.
Corollary 2
Optimal Spread Balancing Equation without Last Look. The risk-neutral broker charges a spread \(\Delta ^*=\sigma \,x^*\), where \(x^*\) is a solution of the non-linear equation
$$\begin{aligned} \phi \left( x\right) -x\,\Phi \left( -x\right) =\frac{1-\alpha }{2\,\alpha }\,x\,. \end{aligned}$$
(5)
Proof
Setting the broker’s expected profits to zero \(\Omega =(1-\alpha )\,\Omega _{ST} - \alpha \,\Omega _{LA}=0\), and rearranging, leads directly to the above balancing equation. \(\square \)
Moreover, the proposition below shows that there is a unique optimal spread where (5) holds.
Proposition 3
There exists a unique finite solution \(x\in [0,+\infty )\) to the non-linear equation (5) if and only if \(\alpha \in [0,1)\).
Proof
See “Appendix A.2”. \(\square \)
It is clear that STs bear the costs imposed on the market by the LAs who trade on stale quotes. Figure 2 shows a plot of the optimal spread \(\Delta ^*\) as a function of the percentage \(\alpha \) of LAs in the market. As expected, this optimal spread is increasing in \(\alpha \). The diagram stops at \(\Delta ^*=2\,\sigma \), however, there is indeed a vertical asymptote at \(\alpha =1\); it is simple to see that as \(\alpha \rightarrow 1\), the solution of (5) is \(x^*\rightarrow \infty \).
Proposition 4
Asymptotic Optimal Spread. When the proportion of LAs trading in the market is small, i.e. \(\alpha \) is small, the asymptotic solution of the optimal spread is
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\Delta ^*}{\sigma }= \sqrt{\frac{2}{\pi }}\;\alpha + o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
(6)
to first order.
Proof
See “Appendix A.3”. \(\square \)
The dashed line in Fig. 2 shows the asymptotic solution. This asymptotic form has a connection to the [4] (GM) model. To see this, note that \({{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ |Z|\right] =\sqrt{\frac{2}{\pi }}\), where Z is a standard normal random variable, so that if we identify \(\sqrt{\frac{2}{\pi }}\;\sigma \sim \left( {\overline{V}}-{\underline{V}}\right) \) where \({\overline{V}}\), \({\underline{V}}\) are the two possible price outcomes in the GM model, then from (6), we have \(\Delta ^* \sim \alpha \,\left( {\overline{V}}-{\underline{V}}\right) \). This result corresponds to the spread in the GM approach when \(\alpha \) represents the percentage of informed traders in the market.

3 Optimal spread with Last Look

In this section we employ the same framework as the one developed above. As before, brokers allow market participants to trade on stale quotes, but brokers have the option of cancelling trades ex-post. Recall that brokers do not know the type of trader they are doing business with, so trades are rejected when the losses to the broker exceed a predetermined threshold which is the same for all brokers. The sequence of events is as follows.
LAs will only trade if midprice updates are such that they can make an immediate risk-less profit (Cases I and II in Fig. 1), which requires the first trade of their latency arbitrage to be on the stale quote—the second leg of their arbitrage is at the current quote \(P^{a,b}_1\). STs on the other hand, trade on stale quotes only when they did not receive the updated quote. In either case, let \(P_e\) denote the midprice at which the trader executed his first trade. Then the broker employs the following ex-post rejection rule at time \(i=2\). If the trader sells to the broker, the broker rejects the trade if \(-P_e+P_2 \le \xi \) (with the threshold \(\xi <0\)), while if the trader buys from the broker, the broker rejects the trade if \(P_e - P_2 \le \xi \), i.e. the broker rejects trades when her losses are larger than the threshold \(|\xi |\) net of the spread cost that they pick up.4
Here we assume that there is only one venue and the rejection threshold is set by the venue. The choice of threshold does not affect the brokers’ business because, conditioned on the threshold \(\xi \), brokers set spreads to break even. In addition, the choice of threshold does not alter the fraction of LAs and STs that the brokers face because there is only one venue to trade. Later, in Sect. 6 we examine in detail what happens when there is more than one venue.
In the following subsection we discuss the ST’s costs of round-trip trades conditioned on the fact that they were accepted, and in Sect. 4 we discuss how STs calculate costs of round-trip trades by also imputing a cost to rejected trades.

3.1 The slow trader’s cost

If the ST receives the updated quote (with probability \(\beta \)), then a round-trip trade costs him the spread \(\Delta \). If he buys (which we assume occurs \(50\%\) of the time), his trade will only be accepted if \(P_e-P_2=P_1-P_2>\xi \). Similarly, if he sells, his trade will only be accepted if \(P_2-P_e=P_2-P_1>\xi \). In all, the ST’s expected cost of a round-trip trade when he receives the updated quote is
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST\,|\,\text {updated}} =\tfrac{1}{2} \, \Delta \, {\mathbb P}\left[ P_1-P_2>\xi \right] + \tfrac{1}{2} \, \Delta \, {\mathbb P}\left[ P_2-P_1>\xi \right] =\Delta \;\Phi \left( -\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
(7)
If the ST does not receive the updated quote, then a round-trip trade costs him \(\left( P_0+\frac{\Delta }{2}\right) - \left( P_1-\frac{\Delta }{2}\right) \) if he buys (then sells), and his trade is accepted only if \(P_e-P_2=P_0-P_2>\xi \). Similarly for the case when the trader sells (then buys). In all, the ST’s expected cost, given that he does not receive the updated quote, is
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST\,|\,\text {stale}} =&\, \tfrac{1}{2} \, {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \left( P_0-P_1+\Delta \right) \,{\mathbb 1}_{\{P_0-P_2>\xi \}}\right] + \tfrac{1}{2} \, {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \left( P_1-P_0+\Delta \right) \,{\mathbb 1}_{\{P_2-P_0>\xi \}}\right] \nonumber \\ =&\, \sigma \,\sqrt{\frac{1+\rho }{2}}\;\phi \left( \frac{1}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) +\Delta \;\Phi \left( -\frac{1}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
(8)
See “Appendix A.4” for the detailed computation.
Proposition 5
Cost to Slow Traders with Last Look. The cost of a round-trip trade by an ST when the broker has the Last Look option is
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST}=&\, \sigma \,(1-\beta )\,\sqrt{\frac{1+\rho }{2}}\;\phi \left( \frac{1}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) \\&\,+\,\Delta \left\{ \beta \,\Phi \left( -\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) +(1-\beta )\,\Phi \left( -\frac{1}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) \right\} \,. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(9)
Proof
This follows immediately from (7) and (8). \(\square \)
Proposition 6
Probability of a Slow Trader’s Execution. The probability that the ST’s trade is executed equals
$$\begin{aligned} \Psi _{ST} = {\mathbb P}[ P_e - P_2 > \xi ] = \beta \,\Phi \left( -\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) +(1-\beta )\,\Phi \left( -\frac{\xi }{\sigma \,\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
(10)
Proof
See “Appendix A.5”. \(\square \)
This probability is independent of the quoted spread because STs are not attempting to latency arbitrage the broker by trading on stale quotes.

3.2 The latency arbitrageur’s profit

The LA uses the same strategy as he did without the Last Look clause. He only trades if, relative to the stale quote, he can make a risk-less and profitable round-trip trade. Thus, whenever the LA executes a trade he always does the first leg at the bid or ask posted in the previous period, i.e. \(P^{a,b}_0\). However, since the broker rejects trades, the LA’s expected profit of a round-trip trade is
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA} = 2\,{{\mathbb {E}}}_0\left[ \; (P_1-P_0-\Delta )_+\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{\,P_0-P_2> \xi \, \}}\; \right] \,, \end{aligned}$$
(11)
which is as (2), but including the indicator function \({\mathbb 1}_{\{\,P_0-P_2> \xi \, \}}\) to account only for accepted trades.
Proposition 7
Losses to Latency Arbitrageurs with Last Look. The expected losses that the broker, who employs the Last Look option, incurs when trading with LAs is
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA} = 2\,(B({{\tilde{\Delta }}})- A({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,\sigma \,, \end{aligned}$$
(12)
where \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}= \frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\), \({\tilde{\xi }}=\frac{\xi }{\sigma }\),
$$\begin{aligned} A({{\tilde{\Delta }}})&:={\mathbb P}[\;P_1-P_0>\Delta \,,\,P_0-P_2> \xi \;] \nonumber \\&=\, \Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) -\Phi _{\sqrt{\frac{1+\rho }{2}}}\left( {{\tilde{\Delta }}}\;,\;-\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
(13)
and
$$\begin{aligned} B({{\tilde{\Delta }}})&:= {{\mathbb {E}}}_0\left[ \; \tfrac{1}{\sigma }(P_1-P_0)\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{\,P_1-P_0>\Delta \,,\,P_0-P_2> \xi \,\}}\; \right] \nonumber \\&= \, \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\, \Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}+(1+\rho ){{\tilde{\Delta }}}}{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\right) -\sqrt{\frac{1+\rho }{2}}\,\phi \left( \frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}+2\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}}{\sqrt{2(1-\rho )}} \right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
(14)
Proof
See “Appendix A.6”. \(\square \)

3.3 Optimal spread with Last Look

Figure 3 shows the optimal spread as a function of the rejection threshold \(\xi \). Recall that the optimal spread is set such that the broker has zero expected profit and satisfies
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha )\,\Omega _{ST}(\Delta ) - \alpha \,\Omega _{LA}(\Delta ) =0\,, \end{aligned}$$
(15)
and all brokers use the same threshold \(\xi \), which is determined by the venue.
The left panel shows how the optimal spread (normalized by the volatility parameter \(\sigma \)) depends on the percentage \(\alpha \) of LAs trading in the market (correlation is fixed at \(\rho =0.5\)) and the rejection threshold imposed by the venue. The right panel shows how the optimal spread depends on the correlation between the shocks to the midprice (percentage of LAs is fixed at \(\alpha =0.1\)). In both panels the optimal spread decreases as the cutoff \(\xi \) increases. This result reflects the fact that LAs make less profits from the broker because as \(\xi \) increases, more trades are rejected – the broker transfers less losses to the STs by charging a smaller spread to the market. Furthermore, it is clear that the optimal spread is bounded above (this bound is obtained when \(\xi \rightarrow -\infty \)) by the optimal spread in the absence of the Last Look option.
The figure also shows that there is a critical cutoff level \(\xi ^*\) which renders the optimal spread equal to zero, and as the percentage of LAs increases, the optimal spread increases—this is natural, as the broker must recover the costs that the additional LAs impose on her. With the Last Look option, brokers can remove the cost to STs entirely (i.e. spread is set at zero) because they are able to recover those costs by rejecting trades from the LAs. Note however, that with the Last Look option the costs of only accepted trades from STs is reduced to zero, but the most profitable trades executed by the ST are cancelled—we return to this point in Sect. 4 where the ST internalizes the costs of rejected trades.
Finally, we observe that when there are trends or momentum in the market, the Last Look feature singles out a higher proportion of LAs’ trades. For example, as correlation between midprice revisions increases, when an LA profits in the first increment, this profit will also be reflected in the increment over the second period, which is when brokers enforce the ex-post rejection option, and hence the rejection rule will pick them out better. The same argument shows that when correlation is negative, prices mean revert, it is more difficult for brokers to use the ex-post price to decide when to reject loss-leading trades executed by LAs, so spreads for a fixed rejection threshold are wider.
Next, we investigate how effective is the Last Look option at rejecting trades from LAs and not those stemming from STs. For this, we need the two results in the following propositions.
Proposition 8
Probability of a Latency Arbitrageur’s Execution. The probability that the LA’s trade is executed is
$$\begin{aligned} \Psi _{LA} = {\mathbb P}\Big [ \,(P_0 - P_2)> \xi \,\Big |\, (P_1-P_0)>\Delta \,\Big ] = \frac{A}{\Phi \left( \frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\right) }\,, \end{aligned}$$
where \(A(\cdot )\) is given in (13).
Proof
Due to symmetry, we need only look at the case when the sell is at the stale and buy at the updated quote. The result above then follows immediately from the definition of conditional probabilities and using the result in (13). \(\square \)
Proposition 9
Rejecting Latency Arbitrageur’s Execution. The probability that a trader was an LA given that the trade was rejected is
$$\begin{aligned} \Upsilon = {\mathbb P}[\text {LA}\,|\, \text {reject}\,] = \alpha \;\frac{1-\Psi _{LA} }{1-(\alpha \,\Psi _{LA}+(1-\alpha )\,\Psi _{ST})}\,. \end{aligned}$$
Proof
A straightforward application of Bayes’ Theorem implies that
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb P}[\text {LA}\,|\, \text {trade rejected}\,] =&\, \alpha \;\frac{{\mathbb P}[\text {reject} \,|\, \text {trade LA}\,]}{{\mathbb P}[\text {reject}\,|\,\text {trade}]}\,, \end{aligned}$$
(16)
and the result follows. \(\square \)
In Fig. 4, we plot the probability that the agent was an LA, given that the trade was rejected, as a function of the cutoff \(\xi \). For each level of \(\xi \), we first determine the optimal spread as in Fig. 3, and then compute \(\Upsilon \) from Proposition 9. The plot shows this is a decreasing function of \(\xi \), and can be interpreted as follows: as the rejection threshold \(\xi \) increases, so that more trades are rejected, it is more difficult to assess whether the trade was emanating from an LA or an ST because the rule rejects trades that are modestly profitable. That is, as the broker increases the value of \(\xi \) and rejects more trades, she is risking rejecting trades from STs and not only those of the LAs.

4 Optimal spread for a slow trader and value of order flow

As seen in the last section, if the venue selects a cutoff level \(\xi \), then there is a unique optimal spread \(\Delta ^*\) which earns the risk-neutral broker zero-expected profit. In other words, there is an optimal spread such that the brokers’ expected revenue from trading with STs equal the expected losses from trading with LAs. Moreover, although the broker is indifferent to the choice of \(\xi \), increasing the cutoff, increases the probability that the rejected trade stems from an ST and not an LA, see Fig. 4.
Hence, what is the optimal cutoff \(\xi ^*\) and the corresponding optimal spread? To answer this question, we view the problem from the perspective of an ST and the different costs that accrue to the ST. In addition to the expected roundtrip cost \(\Omega _{ST}\), other costs are: forgone profits which should have accrued to the ST; immediacy costs which are high if the ST requires immediate and guaranteed execution—for example costs that stem from a trading objective that could not be realized (trade could be part of larger operation); and more importantly, the ST must return to the market to complete the trade which, if executed, is expected to be at a worse price because rejections occur when prices move in favor of (against) the ST (broker); and, arguably, the ST is exposed to being frontrun.5 Thus the ‘effective cost’ to the ST is given by
$$\begin{aligned} {\widehat{\Omega }}_{ST} = \Omega _{ST} + C_{ST}(\alpha , \beta , \Delta , \sigma , \theta _{ST}) \,, \end{aligned}$$
(17)
where \(\Omega _{ST}\) is the cost to the ST due to the spread and the potential rejection of trades due to Last Look as given in Proposition 5, \(C_{ST}\) is the additional cost, where \(\theta _{ST}\) is a set of idiosyncratic parameters.
We remark that the ST’s effective cost is not necessarily lower than the cost that he would incur if trading in a venue without the Last Look option. Thus, depending on the value of the additional cost \( C_{ST}\), the ST will prefer to trade in a venue with Last Look if \({\widehat{\Omega }}_{ST}< \Delta ^0\), where \(\Delta ^0\) is the spread without Last Look, i.e. \(\xi =-\infty \). If the proportion \(\alpha \) of LAs in the market is not too large, so that we can use the simpler expression for the spread without Last Look in Proposition 4, then STs prefer venues with Last Look as long as their effective costs are such that
$$\begin{aligned} {\widehat{\Omega }}_{ST} < \sqrt{\frac{2}{\pi }}\,\alpha \,\sigma \,. \end{aligned}$$
(18)
Moreover, when the ST prefers venues with Last Look, our results also help to determine the rejection threshold which minimizes the ST’s effective cost. Figure 5 shows the ST’s effective cost with
$$\begin{aligned} C_{ST}(\alpha , \beta , \Delta , \sigma , \theta _{ST})=\delta \,(1-\Psi _{ST})\,, \end{aligned}$$
(19)
where \(\delta = 0.5\,|\xi |\), and recall \(\Psi _{ST}\) is the probability that the ST’s trade is accepted and given in (10), \(\beta =0.8\), and \(\alpha = 0.15\). This choice of \(\delta \) is such that every time the ST’s profitable trade is rejected, he imputes a cost of half the broker’s rejection threshold which is less than half of the forgone profits. For this choice of parameters it is clear that there is an optimal spread where the costs to the ST are minimized. The ST’s effective cost is minimized at \(\xi ^*/\sigma = -\,2.49\) which corresponds to an optimal spread of \(\Delta ^*]/\sigma =0.065\), (one can also trace this optimal spread by looking at the left panel in Fig. 2). Finally, this spread is about \(50\%\) of the spread that the broker charges in the absence of the Last Look option, which is \(\Delta /\sigma =0.12\) (see spreads as \(\xi /\sigma \) goes to \(-\infty \) in the left panel of Fig. 3).
In our model we assume that the broker does not know the type of trader she is facing, but when FX transactions are over-the-counter (instead of an ECN where the counterparty is anonymous) the broker has more information about the identity and strategies of her counterparties. For example, the broker might know if she is facing a trader who executes latency arbitrage trades and she is still willing to trade (and reject) some of the trades. LAs may also be considered informed traders so the broker benefits from observing the order flow from informed traders. Recall that liquidity providers make prices to their over-the-counter clients and also post quotes on other venues and ECNs. Thus, observing order flow from informed traders is valuable. We could include this in our model in the same way that we included the additional cost that the STs incur, but in this case the broker imputes a positive revenue to executing trades with LAs. Thus, the broker’s effective losses to LAs are
$$\begin{aligned} {\widehat{\Omega }}_{LA} = \Omega _{LA} - C_{LA}(\alpha , \beta , \Delta , \sigma , \theta _{LA})\,, \end{aligned}$$
(20)
where \(C_{LA}\ge 0\) is the benefit that the broker imputes to learning from LAs’ order flow.

5 Asymptotic expressions: spread, profit, and cost

When the proportion of LAs in the market is small, the expressions for: the optimal spread (with Last Look), expected profit and cost of a round-trip trade for LAs and STs, can be approximated to first order. Later, in Sect. 6 we employ these expressions to show the equilibrium quantities when there are multiple venues.
Proposition 10
Asymptotic Optimal Spread with Last Look. When the proportion of LAs trading in the market is small, the asymptotic solution of the optimal spread is given by
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\Delta ^*}{\sigma } = {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0 + {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1\,\alpha + o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
(21)
where
$$\begin{aligned} {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0 = -\frac{ (1-\beta )\,\sqrt{\frac{1+\rho }{2}}\;\phi \left( \frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\right) }{\beta \,\Phi \left( -{{\tilde{\xi }}}\right) +(1-\beta )\,\Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) }\,, \end{aligned}$$
(22)
and
$$\begin{aligned} {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1 = 2 \frac{ B({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)- {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\,A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) }{\beta \,\Phi \left( -{{\tilde{\xi }}}\right) +(1-\beta )\Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) }\,, \end{aligned}$$
(23)
and \(A(\cdot )\) and \(B(\cdot )\) are defined in (13) and (14), respectively.
Proof
See “Appendix A.7”. \(\square \)
Proposition 11
Asymptotic Cost to STs. When the proportion of LAs trading in the market is small, the broker sets spreads to make zero net profit according to (15), and \(C_{ST}\) is as in (19), the expected (asymptotic) costs of a round-trip trade to STs are
$$\begin{aligned} {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST} = \eta _0\,\sigma + \eta _1\,\sigma \,\alpha + o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
(24)
where
$$\begin{aligned} \eta _0 = \frac{\delta }{\sigma }\,(1-\Psi _{ST})\,, \qquad \text {and} \qquad \eta _1=2\,(B({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)-{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\,A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0))\,\,. \end{aligned}$$
Proof
See “Appendix A.8”. \(\square \)
Proposition 12
Asymptotic Profit to LAs. When the proportion of LAs trading in the market is small, the expected (asymptotic) profit of a round-trip trade to LAs is
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA}= \gamma _0\,\sigma + \gamma _1\,\sigma \,\alpha + o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
(25)
where
$$\begin{aligned} \gamma _0 = 2\,\left( B({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) - {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\,A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)\right) \,, \qquad \gamma _1 = 2\,\left( B'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) - A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)- {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\,A'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
\(A(\cdot )\) and \(B(\cdot )\) are as in (13) and (14) respectively, and \(A'(\cdot )\) and \(B'(\cdot )\) denote derivatives w.r.t. \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}\):
$$\begin{aligned} A'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) = -\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}\,\phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,\Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
(26)
and
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} B'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) =&\, -\left\{ \frac{1+\rho }{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\, \phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}+(1+\rho ){{\tilde{\Delta }}}}{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\right) +{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\; \Phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}+(1+\rho ){{\tilde{\Delta }}}}{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\right) \right\} \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) \,\\&\, + \,\sqrt{\frac{1+\rho }{1-\rho }} \;\phi \left( \frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \;\phi \left( -\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}+2\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}}{\sqrt{2(1-\rho )}} \right) \,. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(27)
Proof
See “Appendix A.9”. \(\square \)

6 Equilibrium: trading in multiple venues

When there is more than one venue to trade, STs will migrate to the one where the expected losses of a round-trip trade are lowest, and LAs will migrate to the one where the expected gains are highest. Thus, the market is in equilibrium when there are no incentives for either type of trader to migrate to a different venue. On the other hand, brokers have no preference for a particular venue because spreads are set so that expected profits are zero. Moreover, recall that we assume that brokers do not pay any costs from entering/exiting a venue.
Assume there are n venues to trade and each venue chooses a rejection threshold \(\xi _i\), \(i={1,\,2,\ldots \, n}\). Brokers and market makers in all venues are as the one described above: risk-neutral and quote spreads using the zero expected profit condition so that losses to LAs are recovered from STs, i.e. in each venue spreads are set so that \(\alpha \,\Omega _{LA} = (1-\alpha )\, \Omega _{ST}\). When traders switch between venues they incur a fixed cost denoted by \(c\ge 0\). This includes customized connection costs and the costs associated with building a relationship with the broker in the over-the-counter FX market.
Definition 13
Equilibrium Across Venues. Let c denote the fixed migration costs between venues and \(\xi _i\) denote the rejection threshold of venue i. In a market with n venues, an equilibrium (no incentives to migrate) are pairs \((\alpha _i, \,\Delta _i)\) for \(i={1,\,2,\,\cdots \, n}\) such that all of the following are (simultaneously) satisfied:
$$\begin{aligned} \left| \,{{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}^i(\alpha _i, \,\Delta _i) - {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}^j(\alpha _j, \,\Delta _j) \,\right| \le c\,, \end{aligned}$$
(28a)
and
$$\begin{aligned} \left| \,\Omega _{LA}^i(\alpha _i, \,\Delta _i) - \Omega _{LA}^j(\alpha _j, \,\Delta _j) \,\right| \le c\,, \end{aligned}$$
(28b)
for \(i\ne j\), and
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha _i)\,\Omega _{ST}^i(\alpha _i,\Delta _i) = \alpha _i\,\Omega _{LA}^i(\alpha _i,\Delta _i) \end{aligned}$$
(28c)
for all i, where superscripts label the venue.
In addition, the population preserving relationships must be satisfied:
$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _i =&\, \frac{N_{LA}^i}{N_{LA}^i + N_{ST}^i}\,, \end{aligned}$$
(28d)
$$\begin{aligned} N_{LA} =&\, \sum ^n_i N_{LA}^i \,, \end{aligned}$$
(28e)
$$\begin{aligned} N_{ST} =&\, \sum ^n_i N_{ST}^i\,, \end{aligned}$$
(28f)
and the constraints
$$\begin{aligned} N_{ST}^i \, , \, N_{LA}^i\, \ge 0\,. \end{aligned}$$
(28g)
In this definition we assume that traders decide to migrate if the gains from one trade exceed the fixed migration costs. An alternative is to calculate the migration gains employing the number of transactions that the trader expects to execute in the new venue, in which case the left-hand side of inequalities (28a), (28b) is premultiplied by the expected number of trades.

6.1 Equilibrium across two FX trading venues

Assume there are two venues which employ rejection thresholds \(\xi _1\) and \(\xi _2\). Let \(N_{LA}\) and \(N_{ST}\) denote the total number of LAs and STs in the market. These traders choose which venue to trade in and decide to migrate if they are better off in the other venue. As discussed above, the venues are in equilibrium if the expected costs for STs and expected profits for LAs, net of the migration cost c, are the same across both venues—so the marginal trader, whether ST or LA, has no incentives to migrate.
To obtain the equilibrium region we proceed as follows. For each venue we find the pairs \((\alpha _i,\,\Delta _i)\) such that STs do not have an incentive to migrate and the region where LAs do not have an incentive to migrate. That is, we find the regions where (28a) and (28b) (together with the population constraints and the brokers’ zero expected profit condition) both hold. Thus, the intersection between these two regions define the equilibrium where traders do not migrate to the other venue.
To obtain the regions where the two types of traders are indifferent between the two venues, we can use the closed-form formulae derived above for the optimal spread, LA’s expected profits and ST’s expected costs. Alternatively, if the proportion of LAs in each venue is small, we can employ the expressions in Propositions 1011, and 12. Either approach will result in approximately the same equilibrium region. There are two advantages to employing the small \(\alpha \) approximations: (i) computations are extremely fast, (ii) we can characterize the equilibrium region in closed-form. For the parameters we used, there is no discernable difference between the exact and approximate equilibrium regions, nor the optimal spreads implied by them.
Figure 6 shows the equilibrium region for Venue 1, when migration costs are \(c=0.05\) (left-hand panel), and \(c=0.025\) (right-hand panel). The additional costs incurred by the STs are as in (19) with \(\delta = 0.5\,|\xi |\). The other parameters are: total number of LAs \(N_{LA} = 200\), total number of STs \(N_{ST} = 800\), rejection threshold in Venue 1 is fixed at \(\xi _1=-3.5\), and there is no Last Look in Venue 2. The equilibrium region is obtained using the small \(\alpha \) formulae.
In the left panel of the figure the equilibrium region (dark gray) clearly shows that both venues can co-exist but the number of traders that each venue supports can vary from very few traders to nearly all traders. At all points in this equilibrium, neither STs nor LAs find it optimal to migrate to the other venue. The region between the blue lines (which includes the dark gray region) is where STs are indifferent between the two venues. Similarly, the region between the red lines is where LAs are indifferent between the two venues. Here we assume that venues can survive with little order flow or that there is no value to brokers from observing flow. In more realistic scenarios, where brokers impute value to order flow (so their profit function is different from the one assumed above), these results will very likely differ—see discussion leading to Eq. (20).
If the market is at a point outside the equilibrium region there are incentives to flow between the two venues until it is suboptimal for any type of trader to migrate. The path that traders take from disequilibrium to an equilibrium depends on how quickly they spot, and can act on, better opportunities. Note that as soon as one trader changes venue, the proportion of LAs in both venues changes and brokers must adjust the quoted spreads to break-even. These changes in both quoted spreads and proportion of LAs, affect the profitability of round-trip trades for LAs and the costs borne by STs, so both types reassess whether they should remain in their current venue or migrate to the other one.
Another interesting feature to observe is that the equilibrium region shrinks as migration costs to trades become smaller. In the right panel of the figure the migration cost is \(c=0.025\) and we observe that the market cannot reach an equilibrium. Clearly, in markets where migration is costly there are less incentives for traders to switch venues. Similarly, in markets where traders can easily switch venues will show more traffic of traders between them because traders can exploit any discrepancy, however small, between the costs and profits of trading in the two venues.

6.2 Analytical characterization of equilibrium region

When the asymptotic forms of the value to LAs and costs to STs provided in Propositions 11 and 12 are used, we can characterize the equilibrium region for the two-venue case in a compact form. Both constraints (28a) and (28b) reduce to the same form and only differ in the coefficients that appear. Hence, we focus only on rewriting (28a) subject to the condition (28c) and the population preserving constraints.
First, using Proposition 11, (28a) subject to the broker setting the spread to make zero expected profits, i.e. that (28c) is satisfied, reduces to
$$\begin{aligned} \left| H_0 + \eta _1^1\,\alpha ^1 - \eta _1^2\,\alpha ^2 \right| \le c\,, \end{aligned}$$
where \(H_0=\eta _0^1-\eta _0^2\). Imposing the population constraint further implies that
$$\begin{aligned} \left| H_0 + \eta _1^1\,\frac{x}{x+y} - \eta _1^2\,\frac{M-x}{N-(x+y)} \right| \le c \,, \end{aligned}$$
where x and y represent the number of LAs and STs, respectively, in Venue 1, N is total population size, M is the total number of LAs, and the constant \(H_0=\eta _0^1-\eta _0^2\). The population constraints also impose the conditions \(0\le x\le M\) and \(0 \le x+y\le N\) which implies that the numerator and denominator of each of the fractions appearing above are all non-negative. We can rewrite this inequality as the following pair of inequalities
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} H_0 + \eta _1^1\,\frac{x}{x+y} - \eta _1^2\,\frac{M-x}{N-(x+y)} \lesseqqgtr \pm c\,. \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
Multiplying by \((x+y)(N-(x+y))\), which is positive due to the population constraints, we obtain, after some tedious algebra,
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} (\eta _1^2-\eta _1^1-\zeta _\pm )\, x^2&+ (\eta _1^2-\eta _1^1-2\,\zeta _\pm )\,x\,y -\zeta _\pm \,y^2 \\&+\, ((\zeta _\pm +\eta _1^1)\,N-\eta _1^2\,M)\,x + (\zeta _\pm \,N-\eta _1^2 \,M)\,y \lesseqqgtr 0\,, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(29)
where the constants
$$\begin{aligned} \zeta _\pm =H_0\mp c\,. \end{aligned}$$
If the inequalities above are replaced by equality, then (29) represent conic sections. A standard result shows that, after a rotation and a translation, there are three cases (when non-degenerate). Letting \(\omega _\pm = B^2 - 4\,A\,C\), where A, B and C are the coefficients of \(x^2\), xy and \(y^2\), respectively, then if
1.
\(\omega _\pm <0\), the conic section is an ellipse,
 
2.
\(\omega _\pm >0\), the conic section is a hyperbola, and
 
3.
\(\omega _\pm =0\), the conic section is a parabola.
 
From (29), we see that
$$\begin{aligned} \omega _\pm =\left( \eta _1^2-\eta _1^1-2\,\zeta _\pm \right) ^2+4\,\left( \eta _1^2-\eta _1^1-\zeta _\pm \right) \,\zeta _\pm = \left( \eta _1^2-\eta _1^1\right) ^2 \ge 0\,, \end{aligned}$$
hence the conics are rotated and translated hyperbolae or parabolas. For example, parabolas appear when \(\eta _1^2 = \eta _1^1\)—one such case is when the two venues are identical. Moreover, by direct substitution into (29), we see that the hyperbolae go through the origin \((x,\;y)=0\) as well as the corner \((x,\;y) = (M, \;N)\)—i.e. either there are no traders in Venue 1 (and no flow into that venue), or all traders are in Venue 1 (and there is no flow out of that venue).

6.3 Path to equilibrium between two venues

Here we illustrate how traders migrate between two venues until they reach an equilibrium. We use the closed-form formulae derived above to obtain the equilibrium pairs \((\alpha ,\, \Delta )\). We assume that there are two venues where the proportion of LAs and quoted spreads are such that in each individual venue the broker makes zero net expected profits from trading, however, there may be incentives for traders to migrate. We assume that traders, whether an LA or an ST, move between venues at a rate proportional to the gain in expected value, after accounting for switching costs, they receive from making the migration only if these gains are positive. To this end, let \(n_{LA}(t)\) and \(n_{ST}(t)\) denote the number of LAs and STs in Venue 1, and let \(N_{LA}\), \(N_{ST}\), and N denote the total number of LAs, STs, and total participants in the market, we assume the dynamic flow
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{dn_{LA}}{dt} =&\, \frac{\kappa _{LA}}{\sigma } \left\{ \left( \Omega _{LA}^1\left( \tfrac{n_{LA}}{n_{ST}+n_{LA}}\right) - \Omega _{LA}^2\left( \tfrac{N_{LA}-n_{LA}}{N-(n_{ST}+n_{LA})}\right) -c_{LA}\right) _+ \! \mathbb 1_{\{n_{LA}<N_{LA}\}} \right. \\&\qquad -\, \left. \left( \Omega _{LA}^2\left( \tfrac{N_{LA}-n_{LA}}{N-(n_{ST}+n_{LA})}\right) - \Omega _{LA}^1\left( \tfrac{n_{LA}}{n_{ST}+n_{LA}}\right) -c_{LA}\right) _+ \! \mathbb 1_{\{n_{LA}>0\}} \right\} \,, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(30a)
$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} \frac{dn_{ST}}{dt} =&\, \frac{\kappa _{ST}}{\sigma } \left\{ \left( {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}^1\left( \tfrac{n_{LA}}{n_{ST}+n_{LA}}\right) - {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}^2\left( \tfrac{N_{LA}-n_{LA}}{N-(n_{ST}+n_{LA})}\right) -c_{ST}\right) _+ \! \mathbb 1_{\{n_{ST}<N_{ST}\}} \right. \\&\qquad -\, \left. \left( {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}^2\left( \tfrac{N_{LA}-n_{LA}}{N-(n_{ST}+n_{LA})}\right) - {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}^1\left( \tfrac{n_{LA}}{n_{ST}+n_{LA}}\right) -c_{ST}\right) _+ \! \mathbb 1_{\{n_{ST}<0\}} \right\} \,, \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(30b)
where we have suppressed the explicit dependence on t for compactness, the superscripts label the venues, recall that \((x)_+=\max (x, \,0)\), \(\kappa _{LA},\kappa _{ST}>0\) are constants which transform the migration gains into rates, and \(c_{LA}, c_{ST}\ge 0\) are the costs of switching from one venue to the other.
Throughout we assume that all market makers know exactly the parameters in the model and react immediately to the flow of traders, however, in reality this information would be corrupted by noise. To account for this, we could add in Brownian motion components to (30), which changes the ordinary differential equations (ODEs) into stochastic differential equations and no equilibria would exist, instead the flow would approach the noise free equilibrium regions, but fluctuate around them.
The above equations define a system of coupled non-linear ODEs and we cannot hope to solve them in general. There are, however, a few simple features of this dynamic flow that we can glean. In the equilibrium region, the right-hand sides of (30) are both zero and there is no migration between venues. In the region where LAs have no incentive to migrate, but the STs do, (e.g., the region between the red lines in Fig. 6), then there is flow in only \(n_{ST}\). In the region where STs have no incentive to migrate, but the LAs do, (e.g., the region between the blue lines in Fig. 6), then there is flow in only \(n_{LA}\).
To illustrate how the market reaches an equilibrium we first look at an example where there are two venues that start at a particular point outside the equilibrium region and traders migrate between venues until an equilibrium point is reached. After this example we examine the general case by considering all possible starting points and employ the coupled system of ODEs to show the path that traders take until an equilibrium is reached.
Assume that Venue 1 fixes a rejection threshold, Venue 2 does not have the Last Look option, and each venue starts with a given number of LAs and STs.6 In our first example migration between venues is sequential: at every step, one trader of each type may migrate to the other venue. Brokers and traders can always observe the number of LAs and STs trading in the venue. Thus, immediately after migration, brokers in both venues calculate the new break-even spreads, traders also calculate the new expected costs and profits of round-trip trades and reassess whether they should stay or migrate, and so on. This is repeated until there are no incentives to migrate.
Moreover, at the beginning, in Venue 1 there are \(N^1_{LA}=125\) and \(N^1_{ST}=375\), so \(\alpha _1 = 25\%\). And the starting point in Venue 2 is \(N^2_{LA}=75\) and \(N^2_{ST}=425\) so \(\alpha _2 = 15\%\). Recall that Venue 2 does not have the Last Look option. Table 1 shows the starting and equilibrium configuration for two examples: in the left-hand panel Venue 1 employs a rejection threshold \(\xi _1=-4\) and in the right-hand panel it employs a stricter rejection threshold of \(\xi _1 = -\,3.5\).
Table 1
Equilibrium across venues, fixed rejection thresholds and varying spreads, \(\beta =0.8\), \(\sigma = 1\), \(\rho = 0.5\), \(\delta = 0.5\,|\xi |\), \(c=0.05\)
\(\alpha \)
Initial
Final
 
25.0%
15.0%
21.1%
19.0%
\(\xi _1=-\,4\), \(\xi _2=-\,\infty \) (no Last Look)
N
500
500
469
531
\(N_{LA}\)
125
75
99
101
\(N_{ST}\)
375
425
370
430
\(\Delta ^*\)
0.19
0.12
0.16
0.15
\({{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}\)
0.20
0.12
0.17
0.15
\(\Omega _{LA}\)
0.58
0.68
0.61
0.65
\(\alpha \)
Initial
Final
 
25.0%
15.0%
18.6%
21.1%
\(\xi _1=-\,3.5\), \(\xi _2=-\,\infty \) (no Last Look)
N
500
500
456
544
\(N_{LA}\)
125
75
85
115
\(N_{ST}\)
375
425
371
429
\(\Delta ^*\)
0.18
0.12
0.13
0.17
\({{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST}\)
0.19
0.12
0.14
0.17
\(\Omega _{LA}\)
0.55
0.68
0.59
0.64
The two panels in the table show how the market reaches an equilibrium where a venue without Last Look coexists with one where brokers have the right to reject trades. With the assumption that only one trader of each type may migrate at each time-step, we see that equilibrium is reached where the proportion of LAs in each venue is close to 20%, despite the fact that the starting points were 25% and 15%. We observe that in the left-hand side panel, the lowest expected cost of a round-trip for an ST is in the venue without Last Look, but in the right-hand panel STs are better off in the venue with the Last Look option. Moreover, it is also interesting to observe the equilibrium spreads: in the left panel, the venue without Last Look quotes a tighter spread than the venue with Last Look—whereas in the right panel we see that the venue with Last Look quotes a tighter spread than the venue without Last Look.
Now we examine the general case where we consider all possible starting points in each venue and use the migration dynamics described by (30) to show the path to equilibrium. LAs are faster than other market participants, so they migrate between venues at a faster rate, i.e. \(\kappa _{LA}>\kappa _{ST}\), and in particular we use \(\kappa _{LA} =40\), \(\kappa _{ST} =20\). Figure 7 shows the migration paths seen in Venue 1 when migration costs are \(c=0.05\) (left panel) and \(c=0.025\) (right panel). Figure 7 is the same as Fig. 6 but it also shows, in black lines, the migration path of traders, and the blue arrows show the direction of the migration. Moreover, recall that the region between red lines is where the LAs do not have incentives to migrate to the other venue, and the region between blue lines is where the STs do not have incentives to migrate.
In the left panel, where migration costs are \(c=0.05\), we observe that when the starting point is in the ‘lower triangular’ white area, both STs and LAs have incentives to migrate to Venue 2 (they are better off in Venue 2 which has no Last Look) and equilibrium is eventually reached. In contrast, for any starting point in the ‘upper triangular’ white area, the equilibrium point is where Venue 1 attracts all the traders in the market—the Venue without Last Look loses all flow to Venue 1.
The picture in the right-hand panel shows that when migration costs are low, so that there is no equilibrium region as already discussed above, traders migrate to two corner solutions: all traders are in Venue 1 or are in Venue 2, i.e. only one FX venue survives in the marketplace. Note that only when the starting point is in the lower triangular region and the number of STs is small, do we see that all traders exit Venue 1 and prefer to trade in Venue 2 without Last Look. In all other cases, migration occurs until all traders leave Venue 2 in favor of Venue 1 with the Last Look option.
Moreover, the migration flows shown in the paths that start in the lower triangular area, and that end up where all traders are in Venue 1, follow an interesting pattern. First we observe that LAs exit Venue 1 and there is not much change in the population of STs. This pattern is seen until the market reaches the region where the STs are in equilibrium (between the blue lines) and at that point STs stop flowing and LAs continue flowing out of Venue 1. Then, the flow reaches the region between the two equilibrium regions. In this region, LAs flow out of Venue 1, while STs flow into Venue 1, causing the flow to get closer to the region where LAs are in equilibrium (between the red lines). Once the flow is in the region where LAs are in equilibrium, they do not flow out of Venue 1 anymore, but STs continue flowing into Venue 1. Then the flow exits the LA equilibrium region and both STs and LAs flow into Venue 1 at a rate which prevents the flow from entering the LA equilibrium region. The reason is that there is migration pressure from STs into Venue 1 within the LA equilibrium region. Interestingly, all these paths lead to an equilibrium where the venue without Last Look loses all its traders.
Recall that in our model \(\alpha \) may also be interpreted as the ratio of latency arbitrage trades to all trades in the market. Thus, the results above may be interpreted as spreads and equilibria across venues attracting trades. For example, an ST could require different immediacy for her trades (which would be reflected in the effective cost component \(C_{ST}\) for each trade) and this determines on which venue the ST executes the trade. Trades that require guaranteed execution have a high \(C_{ST}\), so are executed on venues with lenient or no rejection threshold. Finally, although we do not model the flow of market makers between venues, in our set-up brokers will cease to provide liquidity in venues that disappear and will make markets in other venues. Similarly, venues that do not cease to exist but lose order flow, will also see brokers switch to venues that gained order flow.

7 Conclusions

We show that risk-neutral market makers or brokers quote tighter spreads to the market when they reject loss-leading trades using the Last Look option. The Last Look option helps market makers to mitigate their losses to latency arbitrageurs and also reduces the wealth transfer between slow traders and those who arbitrage the market by trading on stale quotes. In our setup the market maker sets spreads so that she makes zero expected profits.
The Last Look option consists of a time frame and a rejection threshold used by the broker to reject trades ex-post. Since the market maker cannot distinguish the type of trader behind the trades, latency arbitrageur or slow trader, the Last Look option is enforced across all trades. Our results show that brokers are indifferent between different rejection thresholds because they set optimal spreads so that her losses to latency arbitrageurs are covered by the other traders in the market.
We show how effective is the Last Look option as a function of the rejection threshold which determines the market maker’s tolerance to losses on a trade-by-trade basis. When the venue sets a very strict threshold (i.e. any trade that yields a modest profit to the traders is cancelled by the broker), slow traders end up being penalized too often. On the other hand, if the rejection threshold is set so that only trades which result in large losses to the market maker are rejected, the Last Look option becomes very effective at singling out latency arbitrageurs given the fact that the trade is rejected.
At first sight it seems that a ‘relaxed’ threshold is better because the probability that a rejected trade came from a latency arbitrageur is higher. The flip side, however, is that rejection rarely happens, hence losses to latency arbitrage are high, and this results in higher quoted spreads.
Moreover, since the risk-neutral market maker determines the spread so that expected profits are zero, there is a one-to-one mapping between optimal spreads and rejection thresholds which are set by the venue. Strict thresholds lead to tight spreads, and lenient thresholds lead to large spreads. The extreme case is when the threshold is so lenient that no trades are rejected which is equivalent to trading in a venue without Last Look. Therefore, when there is only one FX venue, the market maker is indifferent between different levels of the threshold.
Slow traders, on the other hand, are not indifferent between rejection thresholds. Slow traders benefit from the Last Look option because market makers cap their losses to latency arbitrageurs, but slow traders’ most profitable trades are also cancelled. Thus, when slow traders account for forgone earnings (due to rejected trades), immediacy costs, and the costs from returning to the market to complete the trade, there is an optimal threshold that minimizes their costs of trading in the venue with Last Look. If there is only one FX venue, this optimal threshold could be the extreme where market makers never reject trades. In other words, depending on: the proportion of latency arbitrageurs acting in the market, and on the latency of the slow traders, slow traders will seek or avoid venues with Last Look.
When there is more than one FX venue, market makers still post spreads that ensure that losses to LAs are recovered from STs. Competition across venues, however, incentivizes traders to migrate to those where they are better off. We show that there is an equilibrium region where there are no incentives to migrate. If the market starts outside this region, traders will migrate until an equilibrium is reached. This equilibrium could be one where both venues coexist or one where only one venue survives.
Interestingly, we show that when there are two venues, one with and one without Last Look, the equilibrium reached by the market is chiefly dependent on the proportion of latency arbitrageurs trading in each market. When the no Last Look venue starts with a low proportion of latency arbitrageurs (i.e. a high proportion of latency arbitrageurs in the Last Look venue) the market reaches an equilibrium where both venues coexist. If the market’s starting point, however, is one where the venue with Last Look has a low proportion of latency arbitrageurs, the market reaches an equilibrium where the venue enforcing Last Look attracts all order flow, i.e. only the Last Look venue survives.
Open AccessThis article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://​creativecommons.​org/​licenses/​by/​4.​0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.
Anhänge

Appendix A Proof of results

Appendix A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

The result follows from a straightforward computation of the expectation:
$$\begin{aligned} {{\mathbb {E}}}_0\left[ (P_1-(P_0+\Delta ))_+\right]= & {} \int _{-\infty }^\infty \left( \sigma \,z - \Delta \right) {\mathbb 1}_{\{\sigma \,z-\Delta > 0\}}\,\frac{e^{-\frac{1}{2}z^2}}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\,dz \\= & {} \left. -\sigma \,\frac{e^{-\frac{1}{2}z^2}}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\right| _{\frac{\Delta }{\sigma }}^\infty -\Delta \,\Phi \left( \frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\right) \\= & {} \sigma \,\phi \left( \frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\right) -\Delta \Phi \left( \frac{\Delta }{\sigma }\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
\(\square \)

Appendix A.2 Proof of Proposition 3

It is easy to check that \(f(x) = \phi \left( x\right) -x\,\Phi \left( -x\right) \) is decreasing and convex on \(x\in [0,+\infty )\). In particular, we have
$$\begin{aligned} f'(x) = -\Phi \left( -x\right) \le 0\,, \qquad f''(x) = \phi \left( x\right) > 0\,, \qquad \forall x\ge 0\,. \end{aligned}$$
Moreover, \(f(0) = \sqrt{\frac{2}{\pi }}\), \(f'(0)=-\frac{1}{2}\), \(f''(0)>0\) and \(\lim _{x\rightarrow \infty } f'(x)=0\). Let g denote the line \(g(x)=\frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\,x\). Clearly, \(g(0)<f(0)\) and since f is convex, we must have \(f'(x)\le \lim _{x\rightarrow +\infty }f'(x)=0\). Together with the fact that \(f'(0)=-\frac{1}{2}\) and \(f''(0)>0\), we see that there must exist a single intersection point of f and g on \(x\in [0,+\infty )\) if and only if the slope of the line g is greater than the asymptotic slope of f, i.e. as long as the slope is positive. This occurs if and only if \(\alpha \in [0,1]\). \(\square \)

Appendix A.3 Proof of Proposition 4

First, rearrange the root of (5) to write
$$\begin{aligned} 2\alpha \left( \phi \left( x^*(\alpha )\right) -x^*(\alpha )\,\Phi \left( -x^*(\alpha )\right) \right) =(1-\alpha )\,x^*(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
and note the explicit dependence on \(\alpha \). Clearly, in the limit \(\alpha \downarrow 0\), \(x^*(\alpha )\downarrow 0\). With this observation, next, write
$$\begin{aligned} x^*(\alpha ) = c\,\alpha +o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
and aim to find the constant c. Inserting this expansion into the previous expression and expanding in \(\alpha \) we find that
$$\begin{aligned} 2\alpha \left[ \left( \phi (0) + c\,\alpha \,\phi '(0)\right) -c\,\alpha \,\left\{ \Phi (0)-c\,\alpha \,\phi (0)\right\} \right] =(1-\alpha )\,c\,\alpha +o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
so that \(c = 2 \phi (0)=\sqrt{\frac{2}{\pi }}\) and the result follows. \(\square \)

Appendix A.4 Computation of (8)

To derive this result, first note that due to symmetry both expectations are equal and therefore,
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST\,|\,\text {stale}} =-{{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \left( P_1-P_0-\Delta \right) \,{\mathbb 1}_{\{P_0-P_2>\xi \}}\right] \,. \end{aligned}$$
Next, separate the two terms in the expectation into two pieces: \(A={{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \left( P_1-P_0\right) \,{\mathbb 1}_{\{P_0-P_2>\xi \}}\right] \) and \(B={{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \Delta \,{\mathbb 1}_{\{P_0-P_2>\xi \}}\right] \).
The computation of B is straightforward. Since
$$\begin{aligned} P_0-P_2=\sigma (Z_1+Z_2) {\mathop {=}\limits ^{\small d}} \sigma \left( Z_1+\rho \,Z_1+\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}\,Z_1^\perp \right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
where \(Z_1^\perp \) is a standard normal independent of \(Z_1\). Therefore, \(P_0-P_2\) is normal with mean 0 and standard deviation \(\sqrt{(1+\rho )^2+(1-\rho ^2)}=\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}\), and so
$$\begin{aligned} B=\Delta \,\Phi \left( \frac{\xi }{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
Next, we need the following expectation to compute A:
$$\begin{aligned} {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ Z_1\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{Z_1+Z_2> c\}} \right]= & {} {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ Z_1\,{\mathbb 1}_{\left\{ (1+\rho )\,Z_1+\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}\,Z_1^\perp > c\right\} } \right] \\= & {} \int _{-\infty }^\infty \int _{a - b\,\zeta _1 }^\infty \zeta _1\,e^{-\frac{1}{2}\zeta _1^2 - \frac{1}{2} \zeta _2^2}\,\frac{d\zeta _2}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\frac{d\zeta _1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\,, \end{aligned}$$
where c is an arbitrary constant, \(a=\frac{c}{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\) and \(b=\frac{1-\rho }{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\). Continuing the computation,
$$\begin{aligned} {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ Z_1\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{Z_1+Z_2 > c\}} \right]&= \int _{-\infty }^\infty \zeta _1\,\Phi \left( b\,\zeta _1-a\right) \,e^{-\frac{1}{2}\zeta _1^2 }\,\frac{d\zeta _1}{\sqrt{2\pi }} \\&= \frac{b}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int _{-\infty }^\infty e^{-\frac{1}{2}\zeta _1^2 -\frac{1}{2}(b\,\zeta _1-a)^2}\,\frac{d\zeta _1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}&\text {(integration by parts)} \\&= \frac{b}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\,e^{-\frac{1}{2}\frac{a^2}{1+b^2}}\int _{-\infty }^\infty e^{-\frac{1+b^2}{2}\left( \zeta _1-\frac{a\,b}{1+b^2}\right) ^2}\,\frac{d\zeta _1}{\sqrt{2\pi }}&\text {(completing squares)} \\&= \frac{b}{\sqrt{1+b^2}}\;\phi \left( \frac{a^2}{1+b^2}\right) \\&= \sqrt{\frac{1-\rho }{2}}\;\phi \left( \frac{c}{\sqrt{2(1-\rho )}}\right) \,.&\text {(inserting }a\text { and }b\text {)} \end{aligned}$$
Thus, we use the above results to obtain
$$\begin{aligned} A={{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \sigma \,Z_1\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{Z_1+Z_2 > \frac{\xi }{\sigma }\}} \right] \,, \end{aligned}$$
and the previous result for B, and we arrive at (8).

Appendix A.5 Proof of Proposition 6

By conditioning on whether the trader receives the update or not, we have
$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb P}[ P_e - P_2> \xi ]&= \beta \, {\mathbb P}\left[ P_e - P_2> \xi \,| \,\text {update}\right] + (1-\beta ) \, {\mathbb P}\left[ P_e - P_2 > \xi \,| \, \text {stale}\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)
$$\begin{aligned}&= \beta \, {\mathbb P}\left[ P_1 - P_2> \xi \right] + (1-\beta ) \, {\mathbb P}\left[ P_0 - P_2 > \xi \right] \,, \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
and the result follows from computing these unconditional probabilities.

Appendix A.6 Proof of Proposition 7

To compute this we derive each term separately. Firstly,
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA\,|\,buy} =&\, {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \; (P_1-P_0-\Delta )_+\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{\,P_0-P_2> \xi \}}\; \right] \nonumber \\ =&\, {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ \; (P_1-P_0)\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{\,P_1-P_0>\Delta \,,\,P_0-P_2> \xi \,\}}\; \right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)
$$\begin{aligned}&\quad - \Delta \; {\mathbb P}\left[ \;P_1-P_0>\Delta \,,\,P_0-P_2> \xi \,\right] \,. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)
Let \(\sigma \,B\) denote the first term above (A.3) and \(\Delta \,A\) denote the second term above (A.4).
First, focus on computing A, so we have
$$\begin{aligned} A&= {\mathbb P}\left[ \;P_1-P_0>\Delta \,,\,P_0-P_2> \xi \,\right] \\&= {\mathbb P}\left[ \;Z_1>{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\,,\,Z_1+Z_2< -{{\tilde{\xi }}}\,\right] \\&= {\mathbb P}\left[ \;Z_1>{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\,,\,\frac{(1+\rho )\,Z_1+\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}\,Z_1^\perp }{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}<-\frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\;\right] \\&= {\mathbb P}\left[ \;Z_1>{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\,,\,Z_3<- \frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\;\right] \\&= {\mathbb P}\left[ \;Z_3<- \frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\;\right] - {\mathbb P}\left[ \;Z_1<{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\,,\,Z_3 <- \frac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\;\right] \,, \end{aligned}$$
where \(Z_1^\perp \) is a standard normal r.v. independent of \(Z_1\), and \(Z_3\) is standard normal r.v. correlated with \(Z_1\) with correlation \(\sqrt{(1+\rho )/2}\). The expression for A in (13) now follows immediately.
Next, for B we have
$$\begin{aligned} B =&{{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ Z_1\,{\mathbb 1}_{\{Z_1>{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\,,\,Z_2< -{{\tilde{\xi }}}\}} \right] \\ =&\, {{\mathbb {E}}}\left[ Z_1\,{\mathbb 1}_{\left\{ Z_1>{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\,,\,{(1+\rho )Z_1+\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}Z_1^\perp } <- {{\tilde{\xi }}}\right\} } \right] \\ =&\int _{{{\tilde{\Delta }}}}^\infty \zeta \, \Phi \left( a-b\,\zeta \right) e^{-\frac{1}{2}\zeta ^2} \, \frac{d\zeta }{\sqrt{2\pi }}\,, \end{aligned}$$
where \(a=-{{\tilde{\xi }}}/\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}\) and \(b=(1+\rho )/\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}\). Continuing the computation,
$$\begin{aligned} B=&-\frac{b}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\int _{{{\tilde{\Delta }}}}^\infty e^{-\frac{1}{2}(a-b\,\zeta )^2}\, e^{-\frac{1}{2}\zeta ^2} \, \frac{d\zeta }{\sqrt{2\pi }} + \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,\Phi (a-b{{\tilde{\Delta }}}) \qquad \qquad \text { (integration by parts)} \\ =&-\frac{b}{\sqrt{2\pi }}\,e^{-\frac{1}{2}\frac{a^2}{1+b^2}} \int _{{\tilde{\Delta }}}^\infty e^{-\frac{1+b^2}{2}(\zeta -\frac{a\,b}{1+b^2})^2}\,\frac{d\zeta }{\sqrt{2\pi }} + \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,\Phi (a-b{{\tilde{\Delta }}}) \qquad \text {(completing squares)} \\ =&\, - \frac{b}{\sqrt{1+b^2}} \,\phi \left( \frac{a^2}{1+b^2}\right) \,\Phi \left( \frac{a\,b}{\sqrt{1+b^2}}-{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\sqrt{1+b^2}\right) + \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,\Phi (a-b{{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,. \end{aligned}$$
The expression for B in (14) follows by substituting the expression for a and b in the above. \(\square \)

Appendix A.7 Proof of Proposition 10

First, from the expression for \(\Omega _{ST}\) in (9) we have
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) = \sigma \left( a_{ST} + {{\tilde{\Delta }}}\, b_{ST}\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)
where
$$\begin{aligned} a_{ST} =(1-\beta )\,\sqrt{\tfrac{1+\rho }{2}}\;\phi \left( \tfrac{1}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\tfrac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
and
$$\begin{aligned} b_{ST} = \beta \,\Phi \left( -\tfrac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) +(1-\beta ) \Phi \left( -\tfrac{1}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,\tfrac{\xi }{\sigma }\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
and \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}=\Delta /\sigma \).
Next, from (12),
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) = 2\,(B({{\tilde{\Delta }}})- A({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,\sigma \,, \end{aligned}$$
where
$$\begin{aligned} A({{\tilde{\Delta }}})&=\, a_{LA} -\Phi _{{{\tilde{\rho }}}}\left( {{\tilde{\Delta }}}\;,\;{{\hat{\xi }}}\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
with the constants
$$\begin{aligned} a_{LA} = \Phi \left( -\tfrac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \,, \quad {{\hat{\xi }}}= -\tfrac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\,, \quad {{\tilde{\rho }}}=\sqrt{\tfrac{1+\rho }{2}}\,, \end{aligned}$$
and
$$\begin{aligned} B({{\tilde{\Delta }}})&= \, \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\, \Phi \left( {{\check{\xi }}}-{{\check{\rho }}}\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\right) -b_{LA} \,\Phi \left( {\breve{\xi }}-{\breve{\rho }}\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
with constants
$$\begin{aligned} {{\check{\xi }}}= -\tfrac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\,, \quad {{\check{\rho }}}= \tfrac{1+\rho }{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\,, \quad b_{LA} = {{\tilde{\rho }}}\,\phi \left( \tfrac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1+\rho )}}\right) \,, \quad {\breve{\xi }}= -\tfrac{{{\tilde{\xi }}}}{\sqrt{2(1-\rho )}}\,, \quad {\breve{\rho }}= \tfrac{2}{\sqrt{2(1-\rho )}}\,. \end{aligned}$$
The optimal spread (relative to volatility) is defined as the solution to
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha )\, \Omega _{ST}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}^*) - \alpha \,\Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}^*) =0\,, \end{aligned}$$
and writing \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}^*={{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0+{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1\,\alpha +o(\alpha )\), we need to solve (keeping terms to \(o(\alpha )\)):
$$\begin{aligned} (1-\alpha ) \, \left( \Omega _{ST}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)+\alpha \,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1\,\Omega _{ST}'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) \right) - \alpha \,\Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) = o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
and collecting terms of equal orders we have
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{ST}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) + \alpha \left\{ {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1\,\Omega _{ST}'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) -\Omega _{ST}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) -\Omega _{LA}(\Delta _0) \right\} =o(\alpha )\,. \end{aligned}$$
Solving first for \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\) by setting the first term above to zero and using (A.5), we arrive at \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0 = \frac{a_{ST}}{b_{ST}}\) and (22) follows.
Hence, the above equation becomes
$$\begin{aligned} \alpha \left\{ {{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1\,\Omega _{ST}'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) +\Omega _{LA}(\Delta _0) \right\} =o(\alpha )\,. \end{aligned}$$
Finally, since \(\Omega _{ST}'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) = b_{ST}\), setting the terms in the braces to zero leads to \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1 = \frac{\Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)}{b_{ST}}\) and (23) follows immediately. \(\square \)

Appendix A.8 Proof of Proposition 11

From the proof of Proposition 10 in Appendix A.7, and since \(\Psi _{ST}\) is independent of \(\alpha \) and therefore \(\Delta \), when the broker sets spreads at their optimal level according to (15), we immediately have that
$$\begin{aligned} {{\widehat{\Omega }}}_{ST} =&\, \Omega _{ST}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}^*)+ \delta \,(1-\Psi _{ST}) \\ =&\, \sigma (a_{ST} + b_{ST} ({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0+\alpha \,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1))+ \delta \,(1-\Psi _{ST}) +o(\alpha ) \\ =&\, \sigma \ \alpha \,b_{ST}\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1+ \delta \,(1-\Psi _{ST}) +o(\alpha )\,, \end{aligned}$$
and using \({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1 = \frac{\Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)}{b_{ST}}\), the proof is complete. \(\square \)

Appendix A.9 Proof of Proposition 12

Using the same notation as in the proof of Proposition 10 in  “Appendix A.7”, we have
$$\begin{aligned} \Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}) = 2\,\left( B({{\tilde{\Delta }}})- A({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\right) \,\sigma \,, \end{aligned}$$
where
$$\begin{aligned} A({{\tilde{\Delta }}})&=\, a_{LA} -\Phi _{{{\tilde{\rho }}}}\left( {{\tilde{\Delta }}}\;,\;{{\hat{\xi }}}\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
and
$$\begin{aligned} B({{\tilde{\Delta }}})&= \, \phi ({{\tilde{\Delta }}})\, \Phi \left( {{\check{\xi }}}-{{\check{\rho }}}\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\right) -b_{LA} \,\Phi \left( {\breve{\xi }}-{\breve{\rho }}\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
When the broker sets spreads at their optimal level so that her expected profit and loss is zero, we have
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{2\sigma }\Omega _{LA}({{\tilde{\Delta }}}^*) =&\, \left\{ B({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0+\alpha \,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1)- A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0+\alpha \,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1)\,({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0+\alpha \,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_1) \right\} + o(\alpha ) \\ =&\, \left\{ B({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)- A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\right\} + \left\{ B'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) - A({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0) - A'({{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0)\,{{\tilde{\Delta }}}_0\right\} \alpha + o(\alpha )\,. \end{aligned}$$
Next, by direct computations
$$\begin{aligned} B'(x) = -x\,\phi (x)\,\Phi \left( {{\check{\xi }}}-{{\check{\rho }}}\, x\right) - {{\check{\rho }}}\,\phi (x)\,\phi \left( {{\check{\xi }}}-{{\check{\rho }}}x\right) +{\breve{\rho }}\,b_{LA}\,\Phi \left( {\breve{\xi }}-{\breve{\rho }}\, x\right) \,, \end{aligned}$$
and
$$\begin{aligned} A'(x) = -\partial _1\Phi _{{{\tilde{\rho }}}}\left( {{\tilde{\Delta }}},{{\hat{\xi }}}\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
Further, standard computations show that
$$\begin{aligned} \partial _1\Phi _{c}(x,y) =&\, \int _{-\infty }^y\phi _c(x,y)\,dx\,dy \\ =&\, \int _{-\infty }^y \exp \left\{ -\tfrac{1}{2(1-c^2)}\left( x^2 - 2c\,x\,u + u^2 \right) \right\} \frac{dx\,dy}{2\pi } \\ =&\, \frac{1}{\sqrt{2\pi }} e^{-\frac{1}{2}x^2} \int _{-\infty }^{\frac{y-c\,x}{\sqrt{1-c^2}}} e^{-\frac{1}{2}z^2}\frac{dz}{\sqrt{2\pi }} \\ =&\, \sqrt{1-c^2}\,\phi (x)\,\Phi \left( \frac{y-c\,x}{\sqrt{1-\rho ^2}}\right) \,. \end{aligned}$$
Inserting the explicit expressions for the various constants completes the proof. \(\square \)
Fußnoten
1
There seems to be no general term in the FX industry that refers to the activity when a trader takes liquidity (same currency pair) in different venues at the same time. Here we use the term spamming or spraying for this type of activity.
 
2
If the trader were to request a quote for the full amount, rather than the child orders, the broker would quote a wider spread than that quoted for smaller orders. Wider spreads for large size FX orders are equivalent to large orders in equity markets walking the limit order book.
 
3
When the trader hits the liquidity provider’s most up-to-date quote, but the market has moved, may also be considered as a trade on a stale quote.
 
4
When the broker receives a buy order, she sells the asset so her cash increases by \(P_e\) plus the half-spread, and at period \(i=2\) she uses the midprice \(P_2\) minus the half-spread to decide if the trade is rejected. Thus, the broker rejects the trade if her losses to this round-trip trade are less than \(\xi -\Delta \). So if the trader buys a share on the quote at \(i=1\), then the broker rejects it if \((P_e+\Delta /2) -(P_2-\Delta /2) \le \xi +\Delta \).
 
5
Frontrunning is an illegal activity, but FX market participants have argued that Last Look exposes them to frontrunning, see [1].
 
6
Traders who know \(\sigma \), \(\beta \), \(\xi \), and \(\rho \) can infer the proportions of LAs, in each venue, from posted spreads.
 
Literatur
1.
Zurück zum Zitat Bank of England, H.M. Treasury, and Financial Conduct Authority.: How fair and effective are the fixed income, foreign exchange and commodities markets? Fair and effective markets review (2015) Bank of England, H.M. Treasury, and Financial Conduct Authority.: How fair and effective are the fixed income, foreign exchange and commodities markets? Fair and effective markets review (2015)
2.
Zurück zum Zitat Copeland, T.E., Galai, D.: Information effects on the bid-ask spread. J. Finance 38(5), 1457–1469 (1983)CrossRef Copeland, T.E., Galai, D.: Information effects on the bid-ask spread. J. Finance 38(5), 1457–1469 (1983)CrossRef
3.
Zurück zum Zitat de Jong, F., Rindi, B.: The Microstructure of Financial Markets, 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2009)CrossRef de Jong, F., Rindi, B.: The Microstructure of Financial Markets, 1st edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2009)CrossRef
4.
Zurück zum Zitat Glosten, L.R., Milgrom, P.R.: Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders. J. Financ. Econ. 14(1), 71–100 (1985)CrossRef Glosten, L.R., Milgrom, P.R.: Bid, ask and transaction prices in a specialist market with heterogeneously informed traders. J. Financ. Econ. 14(1), 71–100 (1985)CrossRef
5.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, S.J., Miller, M.H.: Liquidity and market structure. J. Finance 43(3), 617–37 (1988)CrossRef Grossman, S.J., Miller, M.H.: Liquidity and market structure. J. Finance 43(3), 617–37 (1988)CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Foreign exchange markets with Last Look
verfasst von
Álvaro Cartea
Sebastian Jaimungal
Jamie Walton
Publikationsdatum
09.06.2018
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Mathematics and Financial Economics / Ausgabe 1/2019
Print ISSN: 1862-9679
Elektronische ISSN: 1862-9660
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11579-018-0218-3

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2019

Mathematics and Financial Economics 1/2019 Zur Ausgabe