Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Public Choice 3-4/2015

01.03.2015

How do elections affect international cooperation? Evidence from environmental treaty participation

verfasst von: Antoine Cazals, Alexandre Sauquet

Erschienen in: Public Choice | Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Is there a strategically beneficial time for political leaders to make international environmental commitments? Based on the political cycles theory, we argue that leaders have incentives to delay costly ratification of international environmental agreements to the post-electoral period. However, the cost of participating in these agreements is often lower for developing countries, and they may enjoy indirect advantages, which may make them more prone to ratifying in the pre-electoral period. These hypotheses are assessed empirically by studying the ratification process of 41 global environmental agreements censused in the Environmental Treaties and Resources Indicators’ database from 1976 to 1999. We use a duration model in which time is measured on a daily basis, enabling us to precisely identify pre- and post-electoral periods—a significant challenge in political cycles studies. Our investigation reveals the existence of political ratification cycles that are of substantial magnitude and non-linear over the pre- and post-electoral years.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
While no influence of foreign peers is observed by Beron et al. (2003) in the Montreal Protocol ratification process, Murdoch et al. (2003) find that a country is positively influenced by its polluting neighbors in the case of the Helsinki Protocol. In a study of 255 IEAs, Bernauer et al. (2010) find evidence that the ratification of countries from the same region increases the probability of ratifying an IEA. Finally, Sauquet (2014) highlights that, for the case of the Kyoto Protocol, countries are positively influenced by their trade and investment partners.
 
2
Citizen preferences have been shown to be related to a country’s development level and its number of green NGOs (Fredriksson et al. 2007). In addition, the possibility of expressing preferences is determined by a country’s democracy level (Congleton 1992; Fredriksson and Gaston 2000; Neumayer 2002a). Furthermore, the obligations contained in an IEA are suspected to constrain the behavior of polluting goods producers. Therefore, participation is expected to be inversely related to the presence of industrial lobbies and (possibly) trade openness, even if supporting evidence is weak (Fredriksson and Gaston 1999; Neumayer 2002b; Fredriksson et al. 2007).
 
3
In the specific case of the environment, Ashworth et al. (2006) show that the adoption of environmental taxes is delayed beyond an election year by Flemish municipalities.
 
4
Although this view is widely accepted, Ansolabehere et al. (2003) present some dissonant elements. However, even in the case of low campaign contributions, Dahm et al. (2014) show that firms or special interest groups may exert substantial influence over policymakers.
 
5
Moreover, concerned workers may hold leaders accountable for not having managed to preserve jobs. This can ultimately have a detrimental effect on voter perception of the incumbent’s performance and ability, reducing his or her reelection prospects.
 
6
In particular, fishing-related treaties are numerous and fishermen are affected directly by species protection policies, such as restrictions, quotas, and prohibition, or even regulations and norms regarding nets or vessels.
 
7
However, List and Sturm (2006) compare the behavior of U.S. leaders during their tenure, depending on whether they can be reelected or not. Here, the setting is different. For instance, a number of developing countries’ binding term limits are not credible and have not been respected by incumbents, making their theoretical framework not applicable in our context.
 
8
The literature often refers to “vote-trading”, describing a transaction involving a vote. In our case there is no vote directly at stake but rather agreement ratification and international cooperation.
 
9
The Environmental Treaties and Resources Indicators database is provided by the joint efforts of SEDAC (NASA) and CIESIN (Columbia University), with contributions by IUCN and UNEP, among others. The advantage of using the ENTRI database is that it is built on several existing sources of information and contains a large set of information concerning these treaties, which was not available in alternative databases.
 
10
On numerous occasions amendments are not subject to explicit ratification. Rather, they must be denounced before a specific deadline if a country does not want to be bound to them, as with the examples presented in Descamps et al. (2008). The ratification date for an amendment provided by the ENTRI database is the aforementioned specific deadline, which is common to all countries. In that case there would be no point in studying if the “ratification date” is influenced by the electoral agenda of countries.
 
11
A list providing each treaty name, along with its year of entry into force and the number of countries from our sample that had (already) ratified it as of 1999 can be found in Online Appendix A, available at http://​tinyurl.​com/​osbt7hz.
 
12
This methodological approach is standard in the literature (Shi and Svensson 2006; Brender and Drazen 2013, for instance). Regime information is extracted from the “System” variable in the DPI. We classify mixed and parliamentary regimes together, as they are not characterized by a strong separation between executive and legislative powers, as opposed to countries with presidential systems (Persson and Tabellini 2003).
 
13
Countries are classified according to their status during the majority of the period.
 
14
A list of countries along with their respective political regime, is provided in Online Appendix B, available at http://​tinyurl.​com/​osbt7hz. Some countries are obviously democratic only during subperiods and so enter the study only during these subperiods.
 
15
Duration analysis has also been used to study the determinants of IEA ratifications by Fredriksson and Gaston (2000), Neumayer (2002b), Fredriksson et al. (2007), and Sauquet (2014). However, to our knowledge, this is the first attempt to use such a model in a multi-treaty setting.
 
16
In “coxme,” the R routine used to estimate our model, the frailties are estimated using penalized likelihoods for ease of computation. See Therneau et al. (2003) for more details. Frailties are preferred to individual dummies since Allison (2002) and Greene (2004) show that the latter can bias the estimator.
 
17
Revenue and trade openness measures are taken from the World Bank Development Indicators database. The democracy level is taken from Polity IV.
 
18
We deliberately limit our set of control variables for several reasons. First, few variables in the literature are found to be robust in explaining environmental cooperation. Second, an additional variable should be chosen very carefully, since our model may be severely biased by missing observations, especially if they match the ratification year. Finally, as election dates mostly are exogenous, omitted variable bias is a limited concern. Nevertheless, we examine this issue in Sect. 5.2.
 
19
Indeed, election dates are available only from 1975, so to determine whether or not the period under study is post-electoral, the analysis must start on January 1, 1976.
 
20
Note that if a country deposes withdrawal or succession instruments, the country-treaty pair is excluded from the analysis.
 
21
For instance, Barack Obama was elected for the first time on November 4, 2008 but took office only 11 weeks later, on January 20, 2009.
 
22
To clearly demonstrate the implications for the construction of the database and to allow for a better understanding of our empirical contribution, we have developed an example in Online Appendix C, available at http://​tinyurl.​com/​osbt7hz.
 
23
For brevity, we present results only from the full model, taking into account both country and treaty heterogeneity that we believe to be more conservative and rigorous. Not controlling for these heterogeneities does not, however, affect our results qualitatively (available columns (1) and (2) in Table D.1 of Online Appendix D, available at http://​tinyurl.​com/​osbt7hz).
 
24
Furthermore, note that excluding neither control variables nor the freshest treaties open to ratification in the sample significantly affects our results (columns (3) and (4) in Table D.1 of Online Appendix D).
 
25
That is to say, cases in which leaders may have real incentives to behave strategically and, therefore, for which our theoretical mechanisms actually are relevant (as in Brender and Drazen 2005).
 
26
When developing this classification, the author was interested in the ratification of Human Rights agreements. However, after looking at excerpts from countries’ constitutions used by Beth Simmons to justify her classification, we consider this classification to be a good proxy for the case of IEAs.
 
27
Interested readers may find more details in Appendix 3.2 (Ratification rules) of Beth Simmons’s book.
 
28
Countries scoring 1.5 follow a “rule or tradition of informing the legislative body of signed treaties”. Even if legislative assent is not requested, the body that has more influence on this decision may be ambiguous. Moreover, as most countries concerned by this issue are parliamentary (Australia, Botswana, Canada, Egypt, New Zealand, Norway, and the United Kingdom, but not Malawi or Peru), legislative power is likely to exert substantive control over the chief executive it has elected or appointed. However, classifying these countries in one of the two groups does not affect the main results (columns (1) and (2) in Table D.2 of Online Appendix D).
 
29
Growth rates are extracted from the World Bank Development Indicators database.
 
30
This mechanism is well-illustrated by the New Zealand Government’s ratification of the Kyoto Protocol (Yang 2004) which took place after the 2002 election, won by the pro-ratification labour-led party, which the conservative party had opposed.
 
31
To do so, we use election dates to delimitate mandates and the variable “PRTYIN” from DPI, which measures how long the chief executive’s party has been in office, to identify changes in the party in power. An alternative would have been to test whether left-right differences play a significant role. However, Schulze (2014) devoted a paper specifically to this issue and found that partisan differences do not influence significantly decisions to ratify (or not) environmental agreements. We think the underlying argument—that left-wing parties are more environmentally-friendly—is questionable. In addition, implementing such an analysis encounters several technical issues, including: relevance of a right/left classification for the case of developing countries, difficulty classifying center parties, and lack of data for many developing countries.
 
32
However, interpretation of the coefficient associated with the “Post_S2*Newparty” is subject to caution. Indeed, in that case, the marginal impact is not given by the coefficient associated with interacted terms (Ai and Norton 2003; Brambor et al. 2005). Ai and Norton (2003) developed the methodology for interpreting this coefficient in the cases of logit and probit models only. Yet, the behavior of newly elected parties is a secondary result for us and it is not the purpose of this paper to extend Ai and Norton’s methodology for the case of duration models.
 
33
Yet, this result has to be taken with caution, due to the aforementioned difficulty of interpreting coefficients associated with interacted variables in duration models (see footnote 32).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.CrossRef Ai, C., & Norton, E. C. (2003). Interaction terms in logit and probit models. Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Akhmedov, A., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2004). Opportunistic political cycles: Test in a young democracy setting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(4), 1301–1338.CrossRef Akhmedov, A., & Zhuravskaya, E. (2004). Opportunistic political cycles: Test in a young democracy setting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(4), 1301–1338.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. D. (1997). Political cycles and the macroeconomy. Cambridge: MIT Press. Alesina, A., Roubini, N., & Cohen, G. D. (1997). Political cycles and the macroeconomy. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Allison, P. (2002). Bias in fixed-effects Cox regression with dummy variables. Unpublished Paper, University of Pennsylvania. Allison, P. (2002). Bias in fixed-effects Cox regression with dummy variables. Unpublished Paper, University of Pennsylvania.
Zurück zum Zitat Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. J. (2003). Why is there so little money in U.S. politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 105–130.CrossRef Ansolabehere, S., de Figueiredo, J. M., & Snyder, J. M. J. (2003). Why is there so little money in U.S. politics? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(1), 105–130.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2006). Determinants of tax innovation: The case of environmental taxes in flemish municipalities. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 223–247.CrossRef Ashworth, J., Geys, B., & Heyndels, B. (2006). Determinants of tax innovation: The case of environmental taxes in flemish municipalities. European Journal of Political Economy, 22(1), 223–247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Barrett, S. (1998). On the theory and diplomacy of environmental treaty-making. Environmental and Resource Economics, 11(3), 317–333.CrossRef Barrett, S. (1998). On the theory and diplomacy of environmental treaty-making. Environmental and Resource Economics, 11(3), 317–333.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beck, N., Katz, J. N., & Tucker, R. (1998). Taking time seriously: Time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 1260–1288.CrossRef Beck, N., Katz, J. N., & Tucker, R. (1998). Taking time seriously: Time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 45(4), 1260–1288.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2010). A comparison of international and domestic sources of global governance dynamics. British Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 509–538.CrossRef Bernauer, T., Kalbhenn, A., Koubi, V., & Spilker, G. (2010). A comparison of international and domestic sources of global governance dynamics. British Journal of Political Science, 40(3), 509–538.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beron, K. J., Murdoch, J. C., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). Why cooperate? Public goods, economic power, and the Montreal protocol. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 286–297.CrossRef Beron, K. J., Murdoch, J. C., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). Why cooperate? Public goods, economic power, and the Montreal protocol. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(2), 286–297.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brambor, T., Clark, W. R., & Golder, M. (2005). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.CrossRef Brambor, T., Clark, W. R., & Golder, M. (2005). Understanding interaction models: Improving empirical analyses. Political Analysis, 14(1), 63–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1271–1295.CrossRef Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2005). Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52(7), 1271–1295.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2013). Elections, leaders, and the composition of government spending. Journal of Public Economics, 97, 18–31.CrossRef Brender, A., & Drazen, A. (2013). Elections, leaders, and the composition of government spending. Journal of Public Economics, 97, 18–31.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carraro, C., Marchiori, C., & Oreffice, S. (2009). Endogenous minimum participation in international environmental treaties. Environmental and Resource Economics, 42(3), 411–425.CrossRef Carraro, C., Marchiori, C., & Oreffice, S. (2009). Endogenous minimum participation in international environmental treaties. Environmental and Resource Economics, 42(3), 411–425.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.CrossRef Carter, D. B., & Signorino, C. S. (2010). Back to the future: Modeling time dependence in binary data. Political Analysis, 18(3), 271–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Clark, N. (2013). In French air traffic controllers plan strike over pan-European plan. The New York Times, June 10. Clark, N. (2013). In French air traffic controllers plan strike over pan-European plan. The New York Times, June 10.
Zurück zum Zitat Cleves, M., Gould, W., & Gutierrez, R. (2010). An introduction to survival analysis using Stata (3rd ed.). College Station: Stata Press. Cleves, M., Gould, W., & Gutierrez, R. (2010). An introduction to survival analysis using Stata (3rd ed.). College Station: Stata Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Congleton, R. D. (1992). Political institutions and pollution control. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(3), 412–421.CrossRef Congleton, R. D. (1992). Political institutions and pollution control. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 74(3), 412–421.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dahm, M., Dur, R., & Glazer, A. (2014). How a firm can induce legislators to adopt a bad policy. Public Choice, 159(1), 63–82.CrossRef Dahm, M., Dur, R., & Glazer, A. (2014). How a firm can induce legislators to adopt a bad policy. Public Choice, 159(1), 63–82.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davies, R. B., & Naughton, H. T. (2014). Cooperation in environmental policy: A spatial approach. International tax and public finance, 21(5), 923–954. Davies, R. B., & Naughton, H. T. (2014). Cooperation in environmental policy: A spatial approach. International tax and public finance, 21(5), 923–954.
Zurück zum Zitat De Haan, J., & Klomp, J. (2013). Conditional political budget cycles: A review of recent evidence. Public Choice, 157(3), 387–410.CrossRef De Haan, J., & Klomp, J. (2013). Conditional political budget cycles: A review of recent evidence. Public Choice, 157(3), 387–410.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat De Mesquita, B. B., & Smith, A. (2009). A political economy of aid. International Organization, 63, 309–340.CrossRef De Mesquita, B. B., & Smith, A. (2009). A political economy of aid. International Organization, 63, 309–340.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Descamps, H., Slabbinck, R., & Bocken, H. (2008). International documents on environmental liability (1st ed.). Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRef Descamps, H., Slabbinck, R., & Bocken, H. (2008). International documents on environmental liability (1st ed.). Dordrecht: Springer.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Drazen, A. (2000). The political business cycle after 25 years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 75–138. Drazen, A. (2000). The political business cycle after 25 years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 15, 75–138.
Zurück zum Zitat Drazen, A., & Eslava, M. (2010). Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: Theory and evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 92(1), 39–52.CrossRef Drazen, A., & Eslava, M. (2010). Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: Theory and evidence. Journal of Development Economics, 92(1), 39–52.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dreher, A., Nunnenkamp, P., & Thiele, R. (2008). Does U.S. aid buy U.N. general assembly votes? A disaggregated analysis. Public Choice, 136(1), 139–164.CrossRef Dreher, A., Nunnenkamp, P., & Thiele, R. (2008). Does U.S. aid buy U.N. general assembly votes? A disaggregated analysis. Public Choice, 136(1), 139–164.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Faye, M., & Niehaus, P. (2012). Political aid cycles. The American Economic Review, 102(7), 3516–3530.CrossRef Faye, M., & Niehaus, P. (2012). Political aid cycles. The American Economic Review, 102(7), 3516–3530.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Foremny, D., & Riedel, N. (2014). Business taxes and the electoral cycle. Journal of Public Economics, 115, 48–61.CrossRef Foremny, D., & Riedel, N. (2014). Business taxes and the electoral cycle. Journal of Public Economics, 115, 48–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Franzese, J. R., & Robert, J. (2000). Electoral and partisan manipulation of public debt in developed democracies, 1956–90. Institutions, politics and fiscal policy. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Press. Franzese, J. R., & Robert, J. (2000). Electoral and partisan manipulation of public debt in developed democracies, 1956–90. Institutions, politics and fiscal policy. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (1999). The importance of trade for the ratification of the 1992 climate change convention. Trade, global policy, and the environment (World Bank discussion paper 402) (pp. 173–190). Washington: World Bank Publications.CrossRef Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (1999). The importance of trade for the ratification of the 1992 climate change convention. Trade, global policy, and the environment (World Bank discussion paper 402) (pp. 173–190). Washington: World Bank Publications.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (2000). Ratification of the 1992 climate change convention: What determines legislative delay? Public Choice, 104(3–4), 345–368.CrossRef Fredriksson, P. G., & Gaston, N. (2000). Ratification of the 1992 climate change convention: What determines legislative delay? Public Choice, 104(3–4), 345–368.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fredriksson, P. G., Neumayer, E., & Ujhelyi, G. (2007). Kyoto protocol cooperation: Does government corruption facilitate environmental lobbying? Public Choice, 133(1), 231–251.CrossRef Fredriksson, P. G., Neumayer, E., & Ujhelyi, G. (2007). Kyoto protocol cooperation: Does government corruption facilitate environmental lobbying? Public Choice, 133(1), 231–251.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greene, W. (2004). The behaviour of the maximum likelihood estimator of limited dependent variable models in the presence of fixed effects. The Econometrics Journal, 7(1), 98–119.CrossRef Greene, W. (2004). The behaviour of the maximum likelihood estimator of limited dependent variable models in the presence of fixed effects. The Econometrics Journal, 7(1), 98–119.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Special interest politics. Cambridge: The MIT Press. Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2002). Special interest politics. Cambridge: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Haggard, S., & Webb, S. B. (1993). What do we know about the political economy of economic policy reform? World Bank Research Observer, 8(2), 143–68.CrossRef Haggard, S., & Webb, S. B. (1993). What do we know about the political economy of economic policy reform? World Bank Research Observer, 8(2), 143–68.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kalbfleisch, J. D., & Prentice, R. L. (2002). The statistical analysis of failure time data (2nd ed.), Wiley series in probability and statistics. New York: Wiley. Kalbfleisch, J. D., & Prentice, R. L. (2002). The statistical analysis of failure time data (2nd ed.), Wiley series in probability and statistics. New York: Wiley.
Zurück zum Zitat Kelemen, R. D., & Vogel, D. (2010). Trading places: The role of the United States and the European Union in international environmental politics. Comparative Political Studies, 43(4), 427–456.CrossRef Kelemen, R. D., & Vogel, D. (2010). Trading places: The role of the United States and the European Union in international environmental politics. Comparative Political Studies, 43(4), 427–456.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kiefer, N. M. (1988). Economic duration data and hazard functions. Journal of Economic Literature, 26(2), 646–679. Kiefer, N. M. (1988). Economic duration data and hazard functions. Journal of Economic Literature, 26(2), 646–679.
Zurück zum Zitat Kuziemko, I., & Werker, E. (2006). How much is a seat on the security council worth? Foreign aid and bribery at the United Nations. Journal of Political Economy, 114(5), 905–930.CrossRef Kuziemko, I., & Werker, E. (2006). How much is a seat on the security council worth? Foreign aid and bribery at the United Nations. Journal of Political Economy, 114(5), 905–930.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat List, J. A., & Sturm, D. M. (2006). How elections matter: Theory and evidence from environmental policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1249–1281. List, J. A., & Sturm, D. M. (2006). How elections matter: Theory and evidence from environmental policy. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4), 1249–1281.
Zurück zum Zitat Marra, R. F., Ostrom, C. W., & Simon, D. M. (1990). Foreign policy and presidential popularity: Creating windows of opportunity in the perpetual election. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34(4), 588–623.CrossRef Marra, R. F., Ostrom, C. W., & Simon, D. M. (1990). Foreign policy and presidential popularity: Creating windows of opportunity in the perpetual election. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34(4), 588–623.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Matschke, X. (2003). Are there election cycles in wage agreements? An analysis of German public employees. Public Choice, 114(1–2), 103–35.CrossRef Matschke, X. (2003). Are there election cycles in wage agreements? An analysis of German public employees. Public Choice, 114(1–2), 103–35.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mikesell, J. L. (1978). Election periods and state tax policy cycles. Public Choice, 33(3), 99–106.CrossRef Mikesell, J. L. (1978). Election periods and state tax policy cycles. Public Choice, 33(3), 99–106.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moreno-Dodson, B., Rota-Graziosi, G., & Vergne, C. (2012). Breaking the wave of democracy: The effect of foreign aid on the incumbent’s re-election probability. Working papers 201231, CERDI. Moreno-Dodson, B., Rota-Graziosi, G., & Vergne, C. (2012). Breaking the wave of democracy: The effect of foreign aid on the incumbent’s re-election probability. Working papers 201231, CERDI.
Zurück zum Zitat Murdoch, J. C., Sandler, T., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). The participation decision versus the level of participation in an environmental treaty: A spatial probit analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 87(2), 337–362.CrossRef Murdoch, J. C., Sandler, T., & Vijverberg, W. P. M. (2003). The participation decision versus the level of participation in an environmental treaty: A spatial probit analysis. Journal of Public Economics, 87(2), 337–362.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson, M. A. (2000). Electoral cycles and the politics of state tax policy. Public Finance Review, 28(6), 540–560.CrossRef Nelson, M. A. (2000). Electoral cycles and the politics of state tax policy. Public Finance Review, 28(6), 540–560.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Neumayer, E. (2002a). Do democracies exhibit stronger international environmental commitment? A cross-country analysis. Journal of Peace Research, 39(2), 139–164.CrossRef Neumayer, E. (2002a). Do democracies exhibit stronger international environmental commitment? A cross-country analysis. Journal of Peace Research, 39(2), 139–164.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Neumayer, E. (2002b). Does trade openness promote multilateral environmental cooperation? The World Economy, 25(6), 815–832.CrossRef Neumayer, E. (2002b). Does trade openness promote multilateral environmental cooperation? The World Economy, 25(6), 815–832.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. The Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169–190.CrossRef Nordhaus, W. D. (1975). The political business cycle. The Review of Economic Studies, 42(2), 169–190.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nordhaus, W. D. (1989). Alternative approaches to the political business cycle. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 20(2), 1–68.CrossRef Nordhaus, W. D. (1989). Alternative approaches to the political business cycle. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 20(2), 1–68.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat OECD. (2013). Scaling-up finance mechanisms for biodiversity. Paris: OCDE Publishing. OECD. (2013). Scaling-up finance mechanisms for biodiversity. Paris: OCDE Publishing.
Zurück zum Zitat Osborn, A. (2003). All at sea. The Guardian, December 17. Osborn, A. (2003). All at sea. The Guardian, December 17.
Zurück zum Zitat Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. London: The MIT Press. Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (2003). The economic effects of constitutions. London: The MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.CrossRef Putnam, R. D. (1988). Diplomacy and domestic politics: The logic of two-level games. International Organization, 42(3), 427–460.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rose, A. K., & Spiegel, M. M. (2009). Noneconomic engagement and international exchange: The case of environmental treaties. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41(2–3), 337–363.CrossRef Rose, A. K., & Spiegel, M. M. (2009). Noneconomic engagement and international exchange: The case of environmental treaties. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41(2–3), 337–363.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sauquet, A. (2014). Exploring the nature of inter-country interactions in the process of ratifying international environmental agreements: the case of the Kyoto Protocol. Public Choice, 159(1–2), 141–158.CrossRef Sauquet, A. (2014). Exploring the nature of inter-country interactions in the process of ratifying international environmental agreements: the case of the Kyoto Protocol. Public Choice, 159(1–2), 141–158.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schulze, K. (2014). Do parties matter for international environmental cooperation? An analysis of environmental treaty participation by advanced industrialised democracies Environmental Politics, 23(1), 115–139. Schulze, K. (2014). Do parties matter for international environmental cooperation? An analysis of environmental treaty participation by advanced industrialised democracies Environmental Politics, 23(1), 115–139.
Zurück zum Zitat Schulze, K., & Tosun, J. (2013). External dimensions of European environmental policy: An analysis of environmental treaty ratification by third states. European Journal of Political Research, 52(5), 581–607.CrossRef Schulze, K., & Tosun, J. (2013). External dimensions of European environmental policy: An analysis of environmental treaty ratification by third states. European Journal of Political Research, 52(5), 581–607.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2003). Political budget cycles: A review of recent developments. Nordic Journal of Political Economy, 29, 67–76. Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2003). Political budget cycles: A review of recent developments. Nordic Journal of Political Economy, 29, 67–76.
Zurück zum Zitat Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2006). Political budget cycles: Do they differ across countries and why? Journal of Public Economics, 90(8–9), 1367–1389.CrossRef Shi, M., & Svensson, J. (2006). Political budget cycles: Do they differ across countries and why? Journal of Public Economics, 90(8–9), 1367–1389.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Simmons, B. A. (2009). Mobilizing for human rights: International law in domestic politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Simmons, B. A. (2009). Mobilizing for human rights: International law in domestic politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Stone, C. D. (2004). Common but differentiated responsibilities in international law. American Journal of International Law, 98(2), 276–301.CrossRef Stone, C. D. (2004). Common but differentiated responsibilities in international law. American Journal of International Law, 98(2), 276–301.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Therneau, T. M., Grambsch, P. M., & Pankratz, V. S. (2003). Penalized survival models and frailty. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 12(1), 156–175.CrossRef Therneau, T. M., Grambsch, P. M., & Pankratz, V. S. (2003). Penalized survival models and frailty. Journal of Computational and Graphical Statistics, 12(1), 156–175.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Yang, J. (2004). New-Zealand and the Kyoto protocol: Ideals, interests and politics. New Zealand International Review, 29(3), 6–10. Yang, J. (2004). New-Zealand and the Kyoto protocol: Ideals, interests and politics. New Zealand International Review, 29(3), 6–10.
Zurück zum Zitat Zhou, M. (2001). Understanding the Cox regression models with time-change covariates. The American Statistician, 55(2), 153–155.CrossRef Zhou, M. (2001). Understanding the Cox regression models with time-change covariates. The American Statistician, 55(2), 153–155.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
How do elections affect international cooperation? Evidence from environmental treaty participation
verfasst von
Antoine Cazals
Alexandre Sauquet
Publikationsdatum
01.03.2015
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Public Choice / Ausgabe 3-4/2015
Print ISSN: 0048-5829
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7101
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0221-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 3-4/2015

Public Choice 3-4/2015 Zur Ausgabe

Commissioned Editorial Commentary

Thanks to Gordon Tullock

Commisioned Editorial Commentary

In remembrance of Gordon Tullock