Skip to main content

2015 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

2. Institutions and Trade Policy: A Review

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

This analysis examines the impact of institutions on a particular trade policy instrument, i.e. anti-dumping. In doing so, it draws on a body of existing research both from political science and economics. This chapter provides an account of the relevant literature. It explains how the different lines of research interact to establish the theoretical and methodological background, points out remaining gaps in the literature and suggests how this analysis can contribute to address them.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Fußnoten
1
There is an extensive literature on AD, its history and development. For a comprehensive review see for instance Nelson (2006) or Bloningen and Prusa (2003). Relevant characteristics of AD as well stylised facts will also be addressed in Chaps. 3 and 4 when focusing on the application of theoretical arguments to AD.
 
2
This has several obvious reasons: first, AD had only been used by a small group of countries for a long time, which obviously limited possibilities for cross-country analysis. This only changed relatively recently with AD use spreading and data on use being made available as a consequence. Second, scholars who study institutions and those who study AD often come from different disciplines, hence the development of separate literatures and the lack of connection between institutions, notably democratic rule, as an independent and AD as the dependent variable.
 
3
The respective legal definition refers to dumping as “(…) a product is to be considered as being dumped, i.e. introduced into the commerce of another country at less than its normal value, if the export price of the product exported from one country to another is less than the comparable price, in the ordinary course of trade, for the like product when destined for consumption in the exporting country.” See the Agreement on the implementation of Art.6 of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade 1994. Available at http://​www.​wto.​org/​english/​docs_​e/​legal_​e/​19-adp_​01_​e.​htm
 
4
Notably, delegation is an important issue in the literature on American trade politics. Members of the legislature represent narrower constituencies making them more prone for capture by special interests pushing for protection. Given their narrow constituency focus policymakers may engage in logrolling activities, i.e. they agree to barriers for other products in return for favours for their own constituency, resulting in higher trade barriers across the board—as illustrated by the infamous Smoot-Hawley tariffs (Oatley 2008). “Theories of Presidential liberalism” claim that the president tends to be more pro-trade because he represent a nationwide constituency and can better balance different interests. Hence, delegating powers to the president should help o foster openness. Looking beyond the US, the delegation of trade policy competences to the European Commission at an early stage of integration also reflects a similar logic.
 
5
Haggard and Webb (1993) similarly suggest that any autocratic advantage in terms of pursuing reforms essentially depends on leadership.
 
6
See Haggard and Webb (1993) and Haggard and Kaufmann (1995) for a more extensive discussion.
 
7
Scholars point out other factors that contributed to the success of liberalizing reforms for particular countries, e.g. American influence in the case of East Asia (Young 1996) or suggest counter examples such as Chile which also enacted tariff cuts under democratic rule (Henisz and Mansfield 2006) or Germany in the 1930s where autocracy went hand in hand with favouring autarky (Verdier 1998).
 
8
Ability, effectiveness and persistence of trade policy reforms then follow as a second step and require thorough theorising and empirical examination. See for instance the analyses by Giavazzi and Tabellini (2005) or Frye and Mansfield (2003).
 
9
Note that there is a debate in the literature as to what extent factor or sector-based models perform better to explain trade policy preferences. Factor mobility is important in this respect, with higher mobility of production factors across sectors, factor-based models provide a more accurate view and when mobility is low, sector-based models are better suited. Alternatively, the two approaches can be interpreted as short and long-term views. Apart from that, analyses of survey data also reveal that other noneconomic factors such as gender, social status or nationalism play a role in the formation of individual preferences about trade policy (Mayda and Rodrik 2005). Also, Mansfield and Mutz (2009) challenge the view that trade policy preferences are mainly based on income effects and stress the importance “societal effects” based on perceptions of how trade affects the entire country for the formation of preferences.
 
10
On the link between trade and growth see for example Sachs and Warner (1995), Dollar and Kraay (2001), and Wacziarg and Welch (2003). Wintrobe (1998) suggests that democracy helps to reduce rent-seeking. Verdier (1998) focuses on trade policy in industrialized countries in the nineteenth century and similarly argues that democratic leaders are less likely to use trade barriers to extract economic rents.
 
11
See Kono (2006) for an example.
 
12
While Aidt and Gassebner focus on reductions in bureaucratic inefficiencies, better protection of property rights—a characteristic typically associated with democracies—is another example with possible positive repercussions on trade. Better protection of property rights is conducive to FDI (Jensen 2003), which can help encourage trade as recent research suggests that both are complementary (Busse and Hefeker 2006).
 
13
Rodrik (1994, p. 69) for example makes a general claim based on historic observations: “Indeed, historically sharp changes in trade policy have almost always been preceded (or accompanied) by changes in the political regime. (…) Not all political transformation result in trade reform, but sharp changes in trade policy are typically the result of such transformations.” Verdier (1998) also starts from a historical approach examining trade liberalization in nineteenth century Europe.
 
14
Economic liberalisation is not limited to trade policy in this case. Rather, the authors start from a broader concept of reforms and then assess as part of their analysis to what extent policy reforms translate into changes in outcomes such as trade volumes.
 
15
The actual number of countries varies from 14 to 156 for the different regressions and increases over time.
 
16
See Milner and Kubota (2005, p. 120).
 
17
Gravity models which include geographic distance in their estimation solve this problem only to some extent because distance does not equal accessibility which may be promoted or hindered by geographical conditions (e.g. coastline, high mountains).
 
18
Kono is careful to demonstrate that higher NTB’s in democracies are not the result of policymakers being simply more responsive to public concerns, e.g. for higher product safety standards. He backs his argument by examining how the level of NTB’s is affected by several proxies measuring consumer demand for high quality regulation as well as interest group pressure and concludes that it is not consumer demand proxies but rather interest group pressure that explain NTB’s.
 
19
Additional evidence for this logic is provided by examining whether high tariffs prompt frequent challenges to protectionist policies in the domestic political arena. Kono finds that high tariffs are associated with parties more frequently denouncing protectionism in election manifestos.
 
20
For example, Bliss and Russett (1998) use a dummy to distinguish democratic dyads from all other categories and therefore differences between pairs of autocracies and mixed dyads cannot be discerned. Dixon and Moon (1993) exclusively look at trade relationships of the US with other countries and hence no inference about autocratic pairs is possible.
 
21
See McGillivray and Smith (2008, p. 121): […] “but if all else is equal on this dimension, the trader strongly prefers to trade with another large coalition system because of the stability of cooperative relations between large coalition systems. Traders in large coalition systems disproportionally trade with other traders from large coalition systems. This diverts trade by merchants in large coalition systems away from small coalition systems toward other large coalition systems.
 
22
See however Dai (2002) for a critique of the model.
 
23
While this is a monadic argument, the authors argue that the probability to join a trade agreement for A is independent of B and therefore the probability of two democracies to cooperate is highest.
 
24
Tomz (2002) provides evidence for this logic examining the case of Argentina and the link between popular attitudes, debt repayment and electoral success.
 
25
Henisz and Mansfield (2006) similarly suggest that trade openness in democracies is more responsive to shocks and present empirical evidence for this but their argument is more general and not limited to the use of specific flexibility provisions.
 
26
It could be argued that trade disputes are “hybrids” in the sense that they include both elements of cooperation and conflict. On the one hand, they involve disagreement between nations. On the other, disagreement is addressed within a cooperative forum and subject to adjudication.
 
27
Given some recent evidence of China becoming a more active player in dispute settlement, this may change somewhat in the future.
 
28
See also Bown (2009a, p. 94): “Governments that feel the need to implement new import protection will try to do so against trading partners through the use of policies with the lowest costs of implementing such protection.
 
29
As Smith (1999, p. 1256) notes: “Strategic choice is the explicit study of counterfactuals.
 
30
While there are approaches to take particular types of interdependence into account, e.g. for cross-sectional time series data (Beck et al. 1998), the type of interdependence in strategic models is different as it directly arises from the structure of interaction between the two players.
 
31
While non-linearities can be modelled to some extent with interaction effects or squared terms, a simple logit or probit with an interaction effect would still not properly account for the interaction between two players, which is at the heart of a strategic model.
 
32
The game-theoretic solution concept with agent error is the Quantal Response Equilibrium (McKelvey and Palfrey 1995, 1998). Here, the distribution over outcomes basically comes from wrong decisions. With private information, players are observationally equivalent but hold preferences that are only privately known (Kenkel and Signorino 2014). For a discussion of the different sources of uncertainty also see Signorino (2003).
 
33
Another type of strategic interaction would be suggested by (anti)dumping models that focus on the activities of firms to engage in dumping practices. However, this is not the primary focus of this analysis which focuses on the decision-making processes associated with AD that involve government (re)actions.
 
34
Two factors that affect retaliatory capacity are the industry’s export share to the trading partner and whether the target country has an AD mechanism.
 
35
The authors use interaction terms to construct variables for retaliatory capacity. For the first stage, they use product specific export shares of industry to the potential target country and interact this with a dummy variable for having an AD law. The scope of the export component is broadened from product to sector level as part of robustness checks to capture the possibility that firms export multiple products. For the second stage, Bloningen and Bown interact US export shares to the target with several measures to proxy legal capacity (whether a country has brought a case against the US before, whether it has ever been a plaintiff and whether it is a GATT/WTO member).
 
36
Busch, Reinhardt and Raciborski examine US AD cases from 1978 to 2001 using a Heckman probit selection model. Note that both Blonigen and Bown (2003) and Busch, Reinhardt and Raciborski rely on hypothetic control cases, i.e. they try to identify a set of suppliers that could have been named in investigations but where no cases were ultimately initiated.
 
37
Their total sample includes 1,321 cases with 17 investigating countries and 33 targets. The sample for the second set consists of 849 measures.
 
38
They construct a measure to capture bureaucratic quality and litigation capacity based on survey data. Not combined with export shares.
 
39
For direct retaliatory capacity, Bown considers the value of US export shares at industry level to the target. The higher they are, the larger the target’s capability for retaliation.
 
40
Busch et al. (2009) propose the argument in reverse as they argue that dispute settlement and “the rule of law” can (better) deter protection against members lacking the ability to retaliate via other means.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Aidt, T., & Gassebner, M. (2010). Do autocracies trade less? The World Bank Economic Review, 24(1), 38–76.CrossRef Aidt, T., & Gassebner, M. (2010). Do autocracies trade less? The World Bank Economic Review, 24(1), 38–76.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Alvarez, M., Jose, C., Fernando, L., & Przeworski, A. (1996). Classifying political regimes. Studies in Comparative International Development, 31(2), 3–34.CrossRef Alvarez, M., Jose, C., Fernando, L., & Przeworski, A. (1996). Classifying political regimes. Studies in Comparative International Development, 31(2), 3–34.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York, NY: Basic Books. Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York, NY: Basic Books.
Zurück zum Zitat Balassa, B. (1978). Export incentives and export performance in developing countries: A comparative analysis. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 114(1), 24–61.CrossRef Balassa, B. (1978). Export incentives and export performance in developing countries: A comparative analysis. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 114(1), 24–61.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Beck, N., Katz, J., & Tucker, R. (1998). Taking time seriously: Time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 42(4), 1260–1288.CrossRef Beck, N., Katz, J., & Tucker, R. (1998). Taking time seriously: Time-series-cross-section analysis with a binary dependent variable. American Journal of Political Science, 42(4), 1260–1288.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bernauer, T., & Sattler, T. (2011). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation in the world trade organization. European Journal of Political Research, 50(2), 143–167.CrossRef Bernauer, T., & Sattler, T. (2011). Gravitation or discrimination? Determinants of litigation in the world trade organization. European Journal of Political Research, 50(2), 143–167.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bliss, H., & Russett, B. (1998). Democratic trading partners: The liberal connection. Journal of Politics, 60, 1126–1147.CrossRef Bliss, H., & Russett, B. (1998). Democratic trading partners: The liberal connection. Journal of Politics, 60, 1126–1147.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blonigen, B., & Bown, C. (2003). Anti-dumping and retaliation threats. Journal of International Economics, 60(2), 249–273.CrossRef Blonigen, B., & Bown, C. (2003). Anti-dumping and retaliation threats. Journal of International Economics, 60(2), 249–273.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blonigen, B., & Prusa, T. (2003). Anti-dumping. In K. Choi & J. Hartigan (Eds.), Handbook of international trade (pp. 456–476). Oxford: Blackwell. Blonigen, B., & Prusa, T. (2003). Anti-dumping. In K. Choi & J. Hartigan (Eds.), Handbook of international trade (pp. 456–476). Oxford: Blackwell.
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C. (2005). Trade remedies and the world trade organization dispute settlement: Why are so few challenged? World Bank working paper series, no. 3540, World Bank, Washington, DC. Revised version published in Journal of Legal Studies, 23(2), 515–555. Bown, C. (2005). Trade remedies and the world trade organization dispute settlement: Why are so few challenged? World Bank working paper series, no. 3540, World Bank, Washington, DC. Revised version published in Journal of Legal Studies, 23(2), 515–555.
Zurück zum Zitat Bown, C. (2009a). Self-enforcing trade. Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. Bown, C. (2009a). Self-enforcing trade. Developing countries and WTO dispute settlement. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. & Morrow, J. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT. Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson, R. & Morrow, J. (2003). The logic of political survival. Cambridge, MA: MIT.
Zurück zum Zitat Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson R. & Morrow, J. (2008). Retesting selectorate theory: Separating the effects of W from other elements of democracy. American Political Review, 102(3), 393–400. Bueno de Mesquita, B., Smith, A., Siverson R. & Morrow, J. (2008). Retesting selectorate theory: Separating the effects of W from other elements of democracy. American Political Review, 102(3), 393–400.
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M. (2000). Democracy, consultation, and the paneling of disputes under GATT. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(4), 425–446.CrossRef Busch, M. (2000). Democracy, consultation, and the paneling of disputes under GATT. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 44(4), 425–446.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Busch, M., Reinhardt, E., & Shaffer, G. (2008). Does legal capacity matter? Explaining dispute initiation and anti-dumping actions in the WTO. International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development, Issue paper no. 4. Busch, M., Reinhardt, E., & Shaffer, G. (2008). Does legal capacity matter? Explaining dispute initiation and anti-dumping actions in the WTO. International Centre for Trade and Sustainable Development, Issue paper no. 4.
Zurück zum Zitat Busse, M., & Hefeker, C. (2006). Political risk, institutions and foreign direct investment. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(2), 397–415.CrossRef Busse, M., & Hefeker, C. (2006). Political risk, institutions and foreign direct investment. European Journal of Political Economy, 23(2), 397–415.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dai, X. (2002). Political regimes and international trade: The democratic difference revisited. American Political Science Review, 96(1), 159–165.CrossRef Dai, X. (2002). Political regimes and international trade: The democratic difference revisited. American Political Science Review, 96(1), 159–165.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Davis, C., & Blodgett-Bermeo, S. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. Journal of Politics, 71(3), 1033–1049.CrossRef Davis, C., & Blodgett-Bermeo, S. (2009). Who files? Developing country participation in GATT/WTO adjudication. Journal of Politics, 71(3), 1033–1049.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Destler, I. M. (2005). American trade politics (4th ed.). Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics. Destler, I. M. (2005). American trade politics (4th ed.). Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Dixon, W., & Moon, B. (1993). Political similarity and American foreign trade patterns. Political Research Quarterly, 46, 5–25.CrossRef Dixon, W., & Moon, B. (1993). Political similarity and American foreign trade patterns. Political Research Quarterly, 46, 5–25.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2001). Trade, growth and poverty. Finance and Development, 38(3). Dollar, D., & Kraay, A. (2001). Trade, growth and poverty. Finance and Development, 38(3).
Zurück zum Zitat Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2002). Endogenous trade policy through majority voting: An empirical investigation. Journal of International Economics, 58, 107–133.CrossRef Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2002). Endogenous trade policy through majority voting: An empirical investigation. Journal of International Economics, 58, 107–133.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Eichengreen, B., & Leblang, D. (2006). Democracy and globalization. NBER working paper no. 12450, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Eichengreen, B., & Leblang, D. (2006). Democracy and globalization. NBER working paper no. 12450, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Zurück zum Zitat Feinberg, R. M., & Reynolds, K. M. (2006). The spread of anti-dumping regimes and the role of retaliation in findings. Southern Economic Journal, 72(4), 877–890.CrossRef Feinberg, R. M., & Reynolds, K. M. (2006). The spread of anti-dumping regimes and the role of retaliation in findings. Southern Economic Journal, 72(4), 877–890.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Frye, T., & Mansfield, E. (2003). Fragmenting protection: The political economy of trade policy in the post-communist world. British Journal of Political Science, 33(4), 635–657.CrossRef Frye, T., & Mansfield, E. (2003). Fragmenting protection: The political economy of trade policy in the post-communist world. British Journal of Political Science, 33(4), 635–657.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Garrett, G. (2000). The causes of globalization. Comparative Political Studies, 33, 341–391.CrossRef Garrett, G. (2000). The causes of globalization. Comparative Political Studies, 33, 341–391.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Giavazzi, F., & Tabellini, G. (2005). Economic and political liberalizations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1297–1330.CrossRef Giavazzi, F., & Tabellini, G. (2005). Economic and political liberalizations. Journal of Monetary Economics, 52, 1297–1330.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goodhart, L. (2008). Trade protection as pork. Paper prepared for the annual meetings of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago, IL, April 2–6, 2008. Goodhart, L. (2008). Trade protection as pork. Paper prepared for the annual meetings of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago, IL, April 2–6, 2008.
Zurück zum Zitat Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. The American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850. Grossman, G., & Helpman, E. (1994). Protection for sale. The American Economic Review, 84(4), 833–850.
Zurück zum Zitat Guisinger, A. (2009). Determining trade policy: Do voters hold politicians accountable? International Organization, 63, 533–557.CrossRef Guisinger, A. (2009). Determining trade policy: Do voters hold politicians accountable? International Organization, 63, 533–557.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: The selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34, 597–598.CrossRef Guzman, A., & Simmons, B. (2005). Power plays and capacity constraints: The selection of defendants in world trade organization disputes. Journal of Legal Studies, 34, 597–598.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Haggard, S. (1990). Pathways from the periphery: The politics of growth in newly industrializing countries. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Haggard, S. (1990). Pathways from the periphery: The politics of growth in newly industrializing countries. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. (1995). The political economy of democratic transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Haggard, S., & Kaufman, R. (1995). The political economy of democratic transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Haggard, S., & Webb, S. (1993). What do we know about the political economy of economic policy reform? World Bank Research Observer, 8, 143–167.CrossRef Haggard, S., & Webb, S. (1993). What do we know about the political economy of economic policy reform? World Bank Research Observer, 8, 143–167.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Haggard, S., & Webb, S. (Eds.). (1994). Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment. New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Haggard, S., & Webb, S. (Eds.). (1994). Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Helmke, G. (2010). The origins of institutional crises in Latin America. American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 737–750.CrossRef Helmke, G. (2010). The origins of institutional crises in Latin America. American Journal of Political Science, 54(3), 737–750.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Henisz, W., & Mansfield, E. (2006). Votes and vetoes: The political determinants of commercial openness. International Studies Quarterly, 50(1), 189–212.CrossRef Henisz, W., & Mansfield, E. (2006). Votes and vetoes: The political determinants of commercial openness. International Studies Quarterly, 50(1), 189–212.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hiscox, M., & Kastner, S. (2008). Trade policy openness, government spending, and democratic consolidation. In A. Langlois (Ed.), Global democracy and its difficulties. New York, NY: Routledge. Hiscox, M., & Kastner, S. (2008). Trade policy openness, government spending, and democratic consolidation. In A. Langlois (Ed.), Global democracy and its difficulties. New York, NY: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Hoekman, B., & Kostecki, M. (2001). The political economy of the world trading system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Hoekman, B., & Kostecki, M. (2001). The political economy of the world trading system. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Jensen, N. (2003). Democratic governance and multinational corporations: The political economy of foreign direct investment. International Organization, 57(3), 586–616.CrossRef Jensen, N. (2003). Democratic governance and multinational corporations: The political economy of foreign direct investment. International Organization, 57(3), 586–616.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Johns, L., & Rosendorff, P. (2009). Dispute settlement, compliance and domestic politics. In J. Hartigan (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO: An interdisciplinary assessment (pp. 139–163). Bingley: Emerald. Johns, L., & Rosendorff, P. (2009). Dispute settlement, compliance and domestic politics. In J. Hartigan (Ed.), Trade disputes and the dispute settlement understanding of the WTO: An interdisciplinary assessment (pp. 139–163). Bingley: Emerald.
Zurück zum Zitat König, T., & Mäder, L. (2014). The strategic nature of compliance: An empirical evaluation of law implementation in the central monitoring system of the European Union. American Journal of Political Science, 58(1), 246–263.CrossRef König, T., & Mäder, L. (2014). The strategic nature of compliance: An empirical evaluation of law implementation in the central monitoring system of the European Union. American Journal of Political Science, 58(1), 246–263.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kono, D. (2006). Optimal obfuscation: Democracy and trade policy transparency. American Political Science Review, 100(3), 369–384.CrossRef Kono, D. (2006). Optimal obfuscation: Democracy and trade policy transparency. American Political Science Review, 100(3), 369–384.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Krugman, P., & Obstfeld, M. (2006). Internationale Wirtschaft (7th ed.). München: Pearson Studium. Krugman, P., & Obstfeld, M. (2006). Internationale Wirtschaft (7th ed.). München: Pearson Studium.
Zurück zum Zitat Kucik, J., & Reinhardt, E. (2008). Does flexibility promote cooperation? An application to the global trade regime. International Organization, 62(3), 477–505.CrossRef Kucik, J., & Reinhardt, E. (2008). Does flexibility promote cooperation? An application to the global trade regime. International Organization, 62(3), 477–505.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leblang, D. (2003). To devalue or to defend? The political economy of exchange rate policy. International Studies Quarterly, 47(4), 533–560.CrossRef Leblang, D. (2003). To devalue or to defend? The political economy of exchange rate policy. International Studies Quarterly, 47(4), 533–560.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leeds, B. (1999). Domestic political institutions, credible commitments and international organization. American Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 979–1002.CrossRef Leeds, B. (1999). Domestic political institutions, credible commitments and international organization. American Journal of Political Science, 43(4), 979–1002.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lindsey, B., & Ikenson, D. (2003). Anti-dumping exposed: The devilish details of unfair trade law. Washington, DC: Cato Institute. Lindsey, B., & Ikenson, D. (2003). Anti-dumping exposed: The devilish details of unfair trade law. Washington, DC: Cato Institute.
Zurück zum Zitat Lohmann, S., & O’Halloran, S. (1994). Divided government and US trade policy: Theory and evidence. International Organization, 48(4), 595–632.CrossRef Lohmann, S., & O’Halloran, S. (1994). Divided government and US trade policy: Theory and evidence. International Organization, 48(4), 595–632.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E., & Busch, M. (1995). The political economy of non-tariff barriers: A cross-national analysis. International Organization, 49(4), 723–749.CrossRef Mansfield, E., & Busch, M. (1995). The political economy of non-tariff barriers: A cross-national analysis. International Organization, 49(4), 723–749.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94(2), 305–321.CrossRef Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2000). Free to trade: Democracies, autocracies, and international trade. American Political Science Review, 94(2), 305–321.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2002). Why democracies cooperate more: Electoral control and international trade agreements. International Organization, 56(03), 477–513.CrossRef Mansfield, E., Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2002). Why democracies cooperate more: Electoral control and international trade agreements. International Organization, 56(03), 477–513.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mansfield, E., & Mutz, D. (2009). Support for free trade: Self-interest, sociotropic politics, and out-group anxiety. International Organization, 63, 425–457.CrossRef Mansfield, E., & Mutz, D. (2009). Support for free trade: Self-interest, sociotropic politics, and out-group anxiety. International Organization, 63, 425–457.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mayda, A. M., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Why are some individuals (and countries) more protectionist than others? European Economic Review, 49, 1393–1430.CrossRef Mayda, A. M., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Why are some individuals (and countries) more protectionist than others? European Economic Review, 49, 1393–1430.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mayer, W. (1984). Endogenous tariff formation. American Economic Review, 74, 970–985. Mayer, W. (1984). Endogenous tariff formation. American Economic Review, 74, 970–985.
Zurück zum Zitat McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging industry - the comparative politics of trade and industrial policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. McGillivray, F. (2004). Privileging industry - the comparative politics of trade and industrial policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat McGillivray, F., & Smith, A. (2008). Punishing the prince. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. McGillivray, F., & Smith, A. (2008). Punishing the prince. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat McKelvey, R., & Palfrey, T. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 6–38.CrossRef McKelvey, R., & Palfrey, T. (1995). Quantal response equilibria for normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 6–38.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat McKelvey, R., & Palfrey, T. (1998). Quantal response equilibria for extensive form games. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 9–41. McKelvey, R., & Palfrey, T. (1998). Quantal response equilibria for extensive form games. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 9–41.
Zurück zum Zitat McLean, E., & Whang, T. (2010). Friends or foes? Major trading partners and the success of economic sanctions. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2), 427–447.CrossRef McLean, E., & Whang, T. (2010). Friends or foes? Major trading partners and the success of economic sanctions. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2), 427–447.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H. (1999). The political economy of international trade. Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 91–114.CrossRef Milner, H. (1999). The political economy of international trade. Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 91–114.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H. (2012). International trade. In W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, & S. Beth (Eds.), Handbook of international relations (2nd ed.). London: Sage. Milner, H. (2012). International trade. In W. Carlsnaes, T. Risse, & S. Beth (Eds.), Handbook of international relations (2nd ed.). London: Sage.
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H., & Kubota, K. (2005). Why the move to free trade? Democracy and trade policy in developing countries. International Organization, 59(1), 107–143.CrossRef Milner, H., & Kubota, K. (2005). Why the move to free trade? Democracy and trade policy in developing countries. International Organization, 59(1), 107–143.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H., & Mukherjee, B. (2009). Democratization and economic globalization. Annual Review of Political Sciences, 12, 163–181.CrossRef Milner, H., & Mukherjee, B. (2009). Democratization and economic globalization. Annual Review of Political Sciences, 12, 163–181.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2001). The optimal design of international trade institutions: Uncertainty and escape. International Organization, 55(4), 829–857.CrossRef Milner, H., & Rosendorff, P. (2001). The optimal design of international trade institutions: Uncertainty and escape. International Organization, 55(4), 829–857.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morrow, J., Siverson, R., & Tabares, T. (1998). The political determinants of international trade: The great powers, 1907–1990. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 649–661.CrossRef Morrow, J., Siverson, R., & Tabares, T. (1998). The political determinants of international trade: The great powers, 1907–1990. American Political Science Review, 92(3), 649–661.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Morrow, J., Siverson, R., & Tabares, T. (1999). Correction to “the political determinants of international trade”. American Political Science Review, 93(4), 931–933.CrossRef Morrow, J., Siverson, R., & Tabares, T. (1999). Correction to “the political determinants of international trade”. American Political Science Review, 93(4), 931–933.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Myerson, R. (1995). Analysis of democratic institutions: Structure, conduct and performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(1), 77–89.CrossRef Myerson, R. (1995). Analysis of democratic institutions: Structure, conduct and performance. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(1), 77–89.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Myerson, R. (1996). Economic analysis of political institutions: An introduction. Paper written for presentation at the World Congress of Econometric Society, Tokyo. Myerson, R. (1996). Economic analysis of political institutions: An introduction. Paper written for presentation at the World Congress of Econometric Society, Tokyo.
Zurück zum Zitat Nelson, D. (2006). The political economy of anti-dumping: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 554–590.CrossRef Nelson, D. (2006). The political economy of anti-dumping: A survey. European Journal of Political Economy, 22, 554–590.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Oatley, T. (2008). International political economy. New York, NY: Pearson-Longman. Oatley, T. (2008). International political economy. New York, NY: Pearson-Longman.
Zurück zum Zitat Oneal, J., & Russett, B. (1997). The classical liberals were right: Democracy, interdependence and conflict, 1950–1985. International Studies Quarterly, 41, 267–293.CrossRef Oneal, J., & Russett, B. (1997). The classical liberals were right: Democracy, interdependence and conflict, 1950–1985. International Studies Quarterly, 41, 267–293.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Oneal, J., & Russett, B. (1999). Is the liberal peace just an artifact of cold War interests? Assessing recent critiques. International Interactions: Empirical and Theoretical Research in International Relations, 25(3), 213–241.CrossRef Oneal, J., & Russett, B. (1999). Is the liberal peace just an artifact of cold War interests? Assessing recent critiques. International Interactions: Empirical and Theoretical Research in International Relations, 25(3), 213–241.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat O’Rourke, K. & Taylor, A. (2006). Democracy and protectionism. NBER working paper no. 12250, NBER, Washington, DC. O’Rourke, K. & Taylor, A. (2006). Democracy and protectionism. NBER working paper no. 12250, NBER, Washington, DC.
Zurück zum Zitat Prusa, T. (2005). The growing problem of anti-dumping protection. In T. Ito & A. Rose (Eds.), International trade in East Asia(NBER-East Asia seminar on economics, Vol. 14, pp. 329–365). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef Prusa, T. (2005). The growing problem of anti-dumping protection. In T. Ito & A. Rose (Eds.), International trade in East Asia(NBER-East Asia seminar on economics, Vol. 14, pp. 329–365). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prusa, T., & Skeath, S. (2002). The economic and strategic motives for anti-dumping filings. Weltwirschaftliches Archiv, 138, 389–413.CrossRef Prusa, T., & Skeath, S. (2002). The economic and strategic motives for anti-dumping filings. Weltwirschaftliches Archiv, 138, 389–413.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Prusa, T., & Skeath, S. (2004). Modern commercial policy: Managed trade or retaliation? In K. Choi & J. Hartigan (Eds.), The handbook of international trade. Volume II: Economic and legal analyses of trade policy and institutions (pp. 3.58–382). Oxford: Blackwell.CrossRef Prusa, T., & Skeath, S. (2004). Modern commercial policy: Managed trade or retaliation? In K. Choi & J. Hartigan (Eds.), The handbook of international trade. Volume II: Economic and legal analyses of trade policy and institutions (pp. 3.58–382). Oxford: Blackwell.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and development: Political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950-1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Przeworski, A., Alvarez, M., Cheibub, J. A., & Limongi, F. (2000). Democracy and development: Political institutions and well-being in the world, 1950-1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Remmer, K. (1998). Does democracy promote interstate cooperation? International Studies Quarterly, 42, 25–52.CrossRef Remmer, K. (1998). Does democracy promote interstate cooperation? International Studies Quarterly, 42, 25–52.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rodrik, D. (1994). The rush to free trade in the developing world. Why so late? Why now? Will it last? In S. Haggard & S. Webb (Eds.), Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment (pp. 61–88). New York, NY: Oxford University Press. Rodrik, D. (1994). The rush to free trade in the developing world. Why so late? Why now? Will it last? In S. Haggard & S. Webb (Eds.), Voting for reform: Democracy, political liberalization, and economic adjustment (pp. 61–88). New York, NY: Oxford University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Roelfsema, H. (2004). Political institutions and trade protection. Working papers 04-06, Utrecht School of Economics. Roelfsema, H. (2004). Political institutions and trade protection. Working papers 04-06, Utrecht School of Economics.
Zurück zum Zitat Rogowski, R. (1987). Trade and the variety of democratic institutions. International Organization, 41, 203–224.CrossRef Rogowski, R. (1987). Trade and the variety of democratic institutions. International Organization, 41, 203–224.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rogowski, R., & Kayser, M. (2002). Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: Price-level evidence from the OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 526–539.CrossRef Rogowski, R., & Kayser, M. (2002). Majoritarian electoral systems and consumer power: Price-level evidence from the OECD countries. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 526–539.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Russett, B., Oneal, J., & Davis, D. (1998). The third leg of the Kantian tripod: International organizations and militarized disputes, 1950–1985. International Organization, 52, 441–467.CrossRef Russett, B., Oneal, J., & Davis, D. (1998). The third leg of the Kantian tripod: International organizations and militarized disputes, 1950–1985. International Organization, 52, 441–467.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Russett, B., & Oneal, J. (2001). Triangulating peace: Democracy, interdependence and international organizations. New York, NY: W.W Norton. Russett, B., & Oneal, J. (2001). Triangulating peace: Democracy, interdependence and international organizations. New York, NY: W.W Norton.
Zurück zum Zitat Rodriguez, Francisco and Dani Rodrik (2001): Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-national Evidence. In Bernanke, Ben and Kenneth Rogoff (Edts.): NBER Macro Annual (15). NBER, Washington. Rodriguez, Francisco and Dani Rodrik (2001): Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-national Evidence. In Bernanke, Ben and Kenneth Rogoff (Edts.): NBER Macro Annual (15). NBER, Washington.
Zurück zum Zitat Sachs, J., & Warner, A. (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1–118.CrossRef Sachs, J., & Warner, A. (1995). Economic reform and the process of global integration. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 1–118.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schattschneider, E. (1935). Politics, pressures and the tariff. New York, NY: Prentice Hall. Schattschneider, E. (1935). Politics, pressures and the tariff. New York, NY: Prentice Hall.
Zurück zum Zitat Scheve, K., & Slaughter, M. (2001). What determines individual trade policy preferences? Journal of International Economics, 5, 267–292.CrossRef Scheve, K., & Slaughter, M. (2001). What determines individual trade policy preferences? Journal of International Economics, 5, 267–292.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Signorino, C. (1999). Strategic interaction and analysis of international conflict. American Political Science Review, 93(2), 279–298.CrossRef Signorino, C. (1999). Strategic interaction and analysis of international conflict. American Political Science Review, 93(2), 279–298.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Signorino, C. (2002). Strategy and selection in international relations. International Interactions, 28, 93–115.CrossRef Signorino, C. (2002). Strategy and selection in international relations. International Interactions, 28, 93–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Signorino, C. (2003). Structure and uncertainty in discrete choice models. Political Analysis, 11(4), 316–344.CrossRef Signorino, C. (2003). Structure and uncertainty in discrete choice models. Political Analysis, 11(4), 316–344.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Signorino, C., & Yilmaz, K. (2003). Strategic misspecification in regression models. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 551–566.CrossRef Signorino, C., & Yilmaz, K. (2003). Strategic misspecification in regression models. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 551–566.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Signorino, C., & Tarar, A. (2006). A unified theory and test of extended immediate deterrence. American Journal of Political Science, 50(3), 586–605.CrossRef Signorino, C., & Tarar, A. (2006). A unified theory and test of extended immediate deterrence. American Journal of Political Science, 50(3), 586–605.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, A. (1999). Testing theories of strategic choice: The example of crisis escalation. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 1254–1283.CrossRef Smith, A. (1999). Testing theories of strategic choice: The example of crisis escalation. American Journal of Political Science, 42, 1254–1283.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Verdier, D. (1998). Democratic convergence and free trade? International Studies Quarterly, 42, 1–24.CrossRef Verdier, D. (1998). Democratic convergence and free trade? International Studies Quarterly, 42, 1–24.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wacziarg, R., & Welch, K. (2003). Trade liberalization and growth: New evidence. NBER working paper no. 10152, NBER, Washington, DC. Wacziarg, R., & Welch, K. (2003). Trade liberalization and growth: New evidence. NBER working paper no. 10152, NBER, Washington, DC.
Zurück zum Zitat Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Wintrobe, R. (1998). The political economy of dictatorship. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat WTO. (2009). World trade report 2009. Trade policy commitments and contingency measures. Geneva: World Trade Organisation. WTO. (2009). World trade report 2009. Trade policy commitments and contingency measures. Geneva: World Trade Organisation.
Zurück zum Zitat Young, S. (1996). The political economy of trade liberalization in east Asia. In J. Schott (Ed.), The world trading system: Challenges ahead (pp. 141–149). Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics. Young, S. (1996). The political economy of trade liberalization in east Asia. In J. Schott (Ed.), The world trading system: Challenges ahead (pp. 141–149). Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics.
Metadaten
Titel
Institutions and Trade Policy: A Review
verfasst von
Patricia Wruuck
Copyright-Jahr
2015
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-11224-4_2