Skip to main content

2017 | OriginalPaper | Buchkapitel

Linguistic Assimilation and Ethno-religious Conflict

verfasst von : Indraneel Dasgupta

Erschienen in: The Theory of Externalities and Public Goods

Verlag: Springer International Publishing

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

I examine the consequences, of integrating large minorities into productivity-relevant majority ethno-linguistic conventions, for income distribution and ethnic conflict. I develop a two-community model where such assimilation generates social gains by: (a) facilitating economic interaction, and (b) dampening ethno-religious or racial conflict over symbolic and normative contents of the public sphere, measured by the proportion of total output allocated to such conflict. However, integration shifts the distribution of both material and symbolic goods against the minority. It also expands income inequality within the minority community. Total resource wastage due to conflict may go up in absolute terms. My analysis explains why attempts to integrate large minorities into majority ethno-linguistic conventions may meet with strong resistance, even if there are potential gains from such integration. Results suggest that minorities may be more open to assimilation in productivity-relevant majority cultural (especially linguistic) conventions when assimilatory policies are bundled with measures to secularize or de-racialize the public sphere, in the sense of closing a larger part of it to ethno-religious or racial contestation.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Denial of recognition to the Kurdish language in Turkey is linked to the Turkish nationalist policy of cultural assimilation. In Latvia, despite about 40 % of the population being Russian-speaking, Latvian remains both the sole state language and a requirement for citizenship. In the UK, English language requirements for citizenship tests have been progressively tightened in recent years. Ortega and Tangerås (2008) develop a political-economic analysis of the imposition of mono-lingual education by dominant groups.
 
2
The first extends a free trade argument into social policy (e.g., Lazear 1999). It was advanced by colonial administrators and social reformers in colonized countries in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, as the justification for westernizing the education system, the legal code, and social behaviour. Civil rights laws and anti-discrimination statutes in the US are motivated at least partly by the belief that social integration promotes economic efficiency (Fredrickson 1999). Contemporary examples of populist articulation of the second and third arguments include political parties such as the French National Front, the Dutch Party for Freedom, the Bharatiya Janata Party of India, Jobbik of Hungary and Golden Dawn of Greece.
 
3
Lazear (1999), Kónya (2005), Kuran and Sandholm (2008), Li (2013) and Bowles et al. (2014) develop models of assimilation (or, more generally, social segregation and integration), but do not analyze the implications for ethnic conflict. Akerlof and Kranton (2000) explain forms of dysfunctional individual behaviour in terms of stresses generated by identity norms, but do not model their aggregate consequences for conflict between communities. Conversely, Dasgupta and Kanbur (2005b, 2007) and Esteban and Ray (2008, 2011) examine how exogenous changes in the income distribution affect conflict between communities, and thus do not connect the income distribution to the extent of cultural-linguistic integration prevailing in the society. The connection between cultural integration and social conflict thus remains unexplored in their analysis. Dasgupta (2009) shows how class conflict between workers and employers, and ethnic conflict between different groups of workers, mutually condition one another, but assumes homogeneity within the working class in all employment-relevant aspects except the reservation wage. Bakshi and Dasgupta (2017) explore the dynamic evolution of ethnic conflict when state institutions are susceptible to ethnic capture. Our analysis has a distant family resemblance with that of Bhattacharya et al. (2015), who examine the role of inter-group mobility in the emergence of conflict, but varies greatly from theirs both in its specific structure and modelling of conflict.
 
4
In reality, some practices with religious, racial or ethnic identity connotations may also have productivity implications. The broad-brush distinction is porous but nonetheless empirically helpful, and is routinely deployed in the economic analysis of discrimination.
 
5
In 2010, France banned the wearing of a face-covering veil in public. The key official justification was productivity-relevant: face-coverings prevent identification, which is both a security risk and a coordination hindrance, in a society which relies on facial recognition and expression in communication. Thus, headscarves were not affected. In contrast, the wearing of all conspicuous religious symbols in public schools was banned in France in 2004 by a different law, which did affect the wearing of both Islamic veils and headscarves. The Turkish government has traditionally banned women who wear headscarves from working in the public sector. In both cases, the ban on headscarves was justified not by any direct negative impact it might have on productivity, but by its symbolic role in keeping the public sphere secular. In a referendum held in Switzerland in 2009, a constitutional amendment banning new mosque minarets was approved by 57.5 %. In Northern Ireland, clashes often break out over rival Catholic and Protestant marches organized annually to commemorate events in the history of past antagonisms, in India Hindus and Muslims contest ownership of medieval structures, while in Europe conflicts rage between rival mobilizations over demands for censorship on grounds of blasphemy. In all these cases, the items of contestation do not appear to have any direct or immanent implications for workplace coordination or economic productivity, but are intrinsically valued by (typically ethno-religious) communities as constitutive symbols of self-expression in the public sphere.
 
6
Generalized discrimination against the minority can be modelled as a constant cost component, \( d\le {\rho}_N \), that impacts all assimilating N individuals equally. Thus, an increase in such discrimination simply reduces the returns from assimilation by an identical amount for all minority individuals. Individuals may perceive their own expressive and behavioural habits as norms rather than conventions, in that they may intrinsically value them as ideals to live by. In that case, identity-switching will involve a psychic cost. If such marginal psychic cost increases with the level of workplace effort, individuals may rationally provide less than full effort in an alien work environment. The effort level provided will then vary according to idiosyncratic differences in the marginal psychic cost function. Though evidently compatible with my analysis, I refrain from explicitly modelling this additional source of idiosyncratic differences in productivity on considerations of expositional ease and simplicity.
 
7
There exist multi-cultural equilibria involving partial assimilation as well, but these are all unstable.
 
8
For a detailed discussion of such movements and their role in the construction of ethno-linguistic nationalism in modern Europe, see Hobsbawm and Ranger (1983) and Hobsbawm (1992).
 
9
Furthermore, such an equilibrium necessarily generates lower total output than the one where the minority assimilates, provided M, on average, finds it at least as costly to change its behavioural patterns as the minority (i.e., \( E\left({c}_M\right)\ge E\left({c}_N\right) \)], and may do so even otherwise. Since this is empirically likely, it is therefore of limited normative interest.
 
10
I think of this space as one of constitutional/legal guarantees of secularism or race-blindness. A constitution may ban all overt religious content, practices and symbols from the education system and the public sector; personal laws governing marriage, divorce, inheritance, sexual preference and abortion rights may be based entirely on secular principles and violate the traditional norms of all religious communities of any significant size present in that society. Analogously, a legal code may ban the overt display of all racial symbols in public places, or the open discussion of racial identities in the public education system.
 
11
An off-shoot of assimilation, at least over time, may conceivably be the weakening of community cohesion within the minority, and therefore of conflicts with the majority. Kuran and Sandholm (2008) offer an evolutionary game theoretic perspective on this view. My static argument is independent of this dynamic argument. Note also that a shift to assimilation may increase inter-group conflicts when N is sufficiently less cohesive, relative to M. Then, income inequality engendered within N by assimilation may actually increase total political spending by N, expressed as a proportion of total societal income.
 
12
This follows immediately from condition (22) in the Appendix.
 
13
Montalvo and Reynal-Querol (2005, 2008) find that societies which are ethnically more polarized, i.e., where majority and minority communities are close in size, may be more prone to social conflicts (specifically civil wars and genocides). Easterly et al. (2006) present a similar finding in the context of mass killings. The analysis here can be seen as providing a theoretical rationalization of these empirical findings. See also footnote 17.
 
14
Conflicts within the African-American community over ‘acting White’ constitute a specific example, of which Austen-Smith and Fryer (2005) provide a formalization.
 
15
There is some weak cross-country evidence linking greater external openness with lower internal conflict, and it is well-known that globalization affects domestic conflict in contradictory ways through channels such as income distribution, international prices for contestable mineral resources, revenue base of the government etc. [see Barbieri and Reuveny (2005) and Magee and Massoud (2011) for recent discussions]. I thus add to this literature by highlighting an additional mechanism. Collapse of the Soviet Union and the consequent economic disruption arguably played an important role in the revival of ethno-linguistic tensions in parts of Eastern and Central Europe, as well as in many former Soviet republics. Integration into some third linguistic-cultural tradition shifts the normative issue of a just distribution of gains to a global level (see Van Parijs (2011).
 
16
In recent decades, opening up of job opportunities in Saudi Arabia has led to important income gains for some sections of Indian Muslims, but has also incentivized greater adoption of Saudi Wahhabism-inspired behavioural and religious norms and expanded the influence of Arabic in expressive practices. Remittances have funded ethno-religious assertion (e.g., the building and refurbishment of denominational mosques and religious schools, lavish spending on ceremonies, withdrawal of women from the labour market, campaigns for strict observance of dress and dietary codes, etc.), and on mobilizations to organize, defend or enforce such assertion. This in turn has generated conflict and counter-mobilization. The Saudi influence is noticeable in conflicts over organized attempts to impose Wahhabism-inspired linguistic, behavioural and religious norms in Bangladesh and Pakistan as well. See, for example, Boone (2014) for a discussion in the context of Pakistan.
 
17
Note that such societies are ethno-linguistically less polarized, and recall footnote 13. Desmet et al. (2009) and Desmet et al. (2012) develop an empirical operationalization of the idea of linguistic distance between communities. Consistent with my analysis, the latter contribution finds deep linguistic cleavages (which imply large assimilation costs) to be empirically better predictors of civil conflict.
 
18
On affirmative action, see, for example, Holzer and Neumark (2000). Transfers conditional on assimilation efforts (e.g., participation in language classes) may also generate socially excessive adjustment by minorities: Bougheas et al. (2007) show how conditional anti-poverty transfers may be inefficient, yet persist indefinitely.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Akerlof, G. A. (1980). A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(4), 749–775.CrossRef Akerlof, G. A. (1980). A theory of social custom, of which unemployment may be one consequence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(4), 749–775.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–53.CrossRef Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–53.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Austen-Smith, D., & Fryer, R. G., Jr. (2005). An economic analysis of ‘acting White’”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 551–583. Austen-Smith, D., & Fryer, R. G., Jr. (2005). An economic analysis of ‘acting White’”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(2), 551–583.
Zurück zum Zitat Barbieri, K., & Reuveny, R. (2005). Economic globalization and civil war. Journal of Politics, 67(4), 1228–1247.CrossRef Barbieri, K., & Reuveny, R. (2005). Economic globalization and civil war. Journal of Politics, 67(4), 1228–1247.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bergstrom, T. C., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.CrossRef Bergstrom, T. C., Blume, L., & Varian, H. (1986). On the private provision of public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 29, 25–49.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bhattacharya, S., Deb, J., & Kundu, T. (2015). Mobility and conflict. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7(1), 281–319. Bhattacharya, S., Deb, J., & Kundu, T. (2015). Mobility and conflict. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 7(1), 281–319.
Zurück zum Zitat Bougheas, S., Dasgupta, I., & Morrissey, O. (2007). Tough love or unconditional charity? Oxford Economic Papers, 59(4), 561–582.CrossRef Bougheas, S., Dasgupta, I., & Morrissey, O. (2007). Tough love or unconditional charity? Oxford Economic Papers, 59(4), 561–582.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bowles, S., Sethi, R., & Loury, G. (2014). Group inequality. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(1), 129–152.CrossRef Bowles, S., Sethi, R., & Loury, G. (2014). Group inequality. Journal of the European Economic Association, 12(1), 129–152.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cornes, R. C., & Schweinberger, A. G. (1996). Free riding and the inefficiency of the private production of pure public goods. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(1), 70–91.CrossRef Cornes, R. C., & Schweinberger, A. G. (1996). Free riding and the inefficiency of the private production of pure public goods. Canadian Journal of Economics, 29(1), 70–91.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta, I. (2009). ‘Living’ wage, class conflict and ethnic strife. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 72(2), 750–765.CrossRef Dasgupta, I. (2009). ‘Living’ wage, class conflict and ethnic strife. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 72(2), 750–765.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2005a). Community and anti-poverty targeting. Journal of Economic Inequality, 3(3), 281–302.CrossRef Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2005a). Community and anti-poverty targeting. Journal of Economic Inequality, 3(3), 281–302.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2005b). Bridging communal divides: Separation, patronage, integration. In C. Barrett (Ed.), The social economics of poverty: On identities, groups, communities and networks (pp. 146–170). London: Routledge. Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2005b). Bridging communal divides: Separation, patronage, integration. In C. Barrett (Ed.), The social economics of poverty: On identities, groups, communities and networks (pp. 146–170). London: Routledge.
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2007). Community and class antagonism. Journal of Public Economics, 91(9), 1816–1842.CrossRef Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2007). Community and class antagonism. Journal of Public Economics, 91(9), 1816–1842.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2011). Does philanthropy reduce inequality? Journal of Economic Inequality, 9(1), 1–21.CrossRef Dasgupta, I., & Kanbur, R. (2011). Does philanthropy reduce inequality? Journal of Economic Inequality, 9(1), 1–21.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Desmet, K., Ortuño-Ortín, I., & Wacziarg, R. (2012). The political economy of linguistic cleavages. Journal of Development Economics, 97, 322–338.CrossRef Desmet, K., Ortuño-Ortín, I., & Wacziarg, R. (2012). The political economy of linguistic cleavages. Journal of Development Economics, 97, 322–338.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Desmet, K., Ortuño-Ortín, I., & Weber, S. (2009). Linguistic diversity and redistribution. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(6), 1291–1318.CrossRef Desmet, K., Ortuño-Ortín, I., & Weber, S. (2009). Linguistic diversity and redistribution. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(6), 1291–1318.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Easterly, W., Gatti, R., & Kurlat, S. (2006). Development, democracy and mass killings. Journal of Economic Growth, 11(2), 129–56.CrossRef Easterly, W., Gatti, R., & Kurlat, S. (2006). Development, democracy and mass killings. Journal of Economic Growth, 11(2), 129–56.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (2008). On the salience of ethnic conflict. American Economic Review, 98, 2185–2202.CrossRef Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (2008). On the salience of ethnic conflict. American Economic Review, 98, 2185–2202.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (2011). A model of ethnic conflict. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(3), 496–521.CrossRef Esteban, J., & Ray, D. (2011). A model of ethnic conflict. Journal of the European Economic Association, 9(3), 496–521.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fredrickson, G. M. (1999). Models of American ethnic relations: A historical perspective”. In D. A. Prentice & D. T. Miller (Eds.), Cultural divides: Understanding and overcoming group conflict (pp. 23–34). New York: Russell Sage. Fredrickson, G. M. (1999). Models of American ethnic relations: A historical perspective”. In D. A. Prentice & D. T. Miller (Eds.), Cultural divides: Understanding and overcoming group conflict (pp. 23–34). New York: Russell Sage.
Zurück zum Zitat Hobsbawm, E. J. (1992). Nations and nationalism since 1780 (2nd ed.). New York: Cambridge University Press. Hobsbawm, E. J. (1992). Nations and nationalism since 1780 (2nd ed.). New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Hobsbawm, E. J., & Ranger, T. (Eds.). (1983). The invention of tradition. New York: Cambridge University Press. Hobsbawm, E. J., & Ranger, T. (Eds.). (1983). The invention of tradition. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Holzer, H., & Neumark, D. (2000). Assessing affirmative action. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), 483–568.CrossRef Holzer, H., & Neumark, D. (2000). Assessing affirmative action. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), 483–568.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kónya, I. (2005). Minorities and majorities: A dynamic model of assimilation. Canadian Journal of Economics, 38(4), 1431–1452.CrossRef Kónya, I. (2005). Minorities and majorities: A dynamic model of assimilation. Canadian Journal of Economics, 38(4), 1431–1452.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kuran, T., & Sandholm, W. (2008). Cultural integration and its discontents. Review of Economic Studies, 75, 201–228.CrossRef Kuran, T., & Sandholm, W. (2008). Cultural integration and its discontents. Review of Economic Studies, 75, 201–228.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lazear, E. (1999). Culture and language. Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), S95–S126.CrossRef Lazear, E. (1999). Culture and language. Journal of Political Economy, 107(6), S95–S126.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lewis, D. (1969). Convention: A philosophical study. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Lewis, D. (1969). Convention: A philosophical study. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Li, Q. (2013). Language and urban labor market segmentation: Theory and evidence. Journal of Urban Economics, 74, 27–46.CrossRef Li, Q. (2013). Language and urban labor market segmentation: Theory and evidence. Journal of Urban Economics, 74, 27–46.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Magee, C., & Massoud, T. (2011). Openness and internal conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 48(1), 59–72.CrossRef Magee, C., & Massoud, T. (2011). Openness and internal conflict. Journal of Peace Research, 48(1), 59–72.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2005). Ethnic polarization, potential conflict and civil wars. American Economic Review, 95(3), 796–816.CrossRef Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2005). Ethnic polarization, potential conflict and civil wars. American Economic Review, 95(3), 796–816.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2008). Discrete polarization with an application to the determinants of genocides. Economic Journal, 118(533), 1835–65. Montalvo, J., & Reynal-Querol, M. (2008). Discrete polarization with an application to the determinants of genocides. Economic Journal, 118(533), 1835–65.
Zurück zum Zitat Ortega, J., & Tangerås, T. (2008). Unilingual versus bilingual education: A political economy analysis. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(5), 1078–1108.CrossRef Ortega, J., & Tangerås, T. (2008). Unilingual versus bilingual education: A political economy analysis. Journal of the European Economic Association, 6(5), 1078–1108.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Schelling, T. (1960). The strategy of conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Van Parijs, P. (2011). Linguistic justice for Europe and the world. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRef Van Parijs, P. (2011). Linguistic justice for Europe and the world. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Linguistic Assimilation and Ethno-religious Conflict
verfasst von
Indraneel Dasgupta
Copyright-Jahr
2017
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-49442-5_12