Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Small Business Economics 1/2019

11.04.2018

The dynamics of switching between governmental and independent venture capitalists: theory and evidence

verfasst von: Laura Abrardi, Annalisa Croce, Elisa Ughetto

Erschienen in: Small Business Economics | Ausgabe 1/2019

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

In this paper, we study the switching dynamics between independent VCs (IVCs) and governmental VCs (GVCs) by means of a theoretical model and an empirical analysis. By assuming that (i) VCs of higher reputation are more selective in terms of venture quality and (ii) IVCs are mainly motivated by the desire to maximize the economic return of a venture, while GVCs also care about the social repercussions, we have obtained two results. First, low economic return ventures are more likely to be adopted by a new lead GVC that is more reputable than the IVC that drops them. Second, when switches from a GVC to an IVC are considered, a low economic return increases the likelihood that the venture dropped by the incumbent GVC will be re-matched with a less-reputable IVC. Our theoretical predictions match evidence that has emerged from a sample of 9610 rounds of VC financing in the USA between 1998 and 2010. Overall, our analysis sheds light on the puzzling evidence that GVCs seem to be more inclined to drop low return ventures than IVCs, but, at the same time, they are also more willing to adopt them.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
As reported in Cumming and MacIntosh (2001), only 10% of portfolio investments are “home runs” that provide the bulk of VC profits, a further 20% are less profitable and approximately 10–30% of investments are write-offs, while the remainder are investments that do not generate more than nominal returns for VC investors.
 
2
Prior research has shown that VCs often prefer to escalate their commitment to a prior course of action rather than terminate their investment, even when they receive negative information about future prospects of an investment (see Guler (2007) for a review of such studies). Guler (2007) examined multilevel influences on sequential investment decisions in the US venture capital industry and found that VC firms do not adjust their investment practices to reflect the change in expected returns, due to political and institutional constraints.
 
3
Cumming and Dai (2013) reported that, from 1991 to 2002 in the USA, in 23% of the cases, the lead VCs of follow-on rounds of financing were different from those of previous rounds. An even higher percentage (47.99%) was reported by Croce and Ughetto (2016) for the years 1998–2010 in the USA.
 
4
Two other related studies examined what drives GVC-backed ventures to receive additional financing by other VCs, especially when investments are syndicated between GVCs and IVCs (Brander et al. 2015; Guerini and Quas 2016).
 
5
VC investors are usually classified on the basis of different configurations of ownership and governance. VCs can be independent firms that manage pools of funds raised from limited partners, often institutional investors (Sahlman 1990), or captive firms, which are structured as investment vehicles, where the capital is provided by a parent company, which may be a financial institution (e.g., a bank), a corporation or a government agency.
 
6
Both Cumming and Dai (2013) and Croce and Ughetto (2016) also explored the perspective of entrepreneurs. They argued that switching may occur if entrepreneurs perceive that a change in the lead VC would allow their venture to access additional deal opportunities, financial resources, more valuable advice or coaching services from the new VC. However, informal talks with venture capital partners have suggested that, most of the time, the switching decision is not undertaken by the venture itself, but by the incumbent VC. Accordingly, we decided to leave aside the arguments concerning the decision of entrepreneurs to change lead VC investor and to only concentrate on the perspectives of both the incumbent and the new VCs.
 
7
A large body of research has identified the benefits and potential distortions of public intervention on the VC market, and has described successful and unsuccessful experiences developed in different countries (Avnimelech and Teubal 2006; Cumming and Li 2013; Cumming 2007; Cumming and MacIntosh 2006, 2007; Da Rin et al. 2006; Johan et al. 2014; Leleux and Surlemont 2003; Lerner 1999, 2010, among others). Governmental VC funds have been created in numerous countries to develop an active VC market (Brander et al. 2015). Examples of relevant worldwide initiatives are the Yozma program in Israel, the Small Business Investment Companies program (SBIC) in the USA, the Canadian labor-sponsored venture capital corporation, and the Australian Innovation Investment Fund. In Europe, the examples include the Fund for the Promotion of Venture Capital in France, the High Tech Fund of Funds in the UK, the German ERP-EIF Dachfonds fund, the Dutch TechnoPartner Seed facility fund, and the Danish Vækstfonden fund.
 
8
A VC’s reputation is generally associated with its skills to select the best ventures or to enhance their performance (Bertoni et al. 2016; Bertoni et al. 2015; Gompers 1996; Nahata 2008). However, a VC’s reputation may by itself attract high quality ventures, either as a means for the latter to signal their potential, or because of the easier access to resources that the association with a highly reputable VC would engender (Dimov et al. 2007; Lee et al. 2011). We simply focus here on the probability that a reputable VC matches with high-quality ventures, regardless of its source.
 
9
The extraction refers to April 2012.
 
10
As a robustness check, we followed the method of Cumming and Dai (2013) and employed a different definition of lead VC, that is, the one that invested the largest cumulative amount of capital. The obtained results were robust to the adoption of this different definition.
 
11
Thomson One defines an IVC as “an Independent Private Partnership,” namely “an independent private firm that makes private equity investments and which raises a portion or all of its capital from outside investors.” We included the following typologies of funds in the GVC category: “Government”, defined as “A program funded by a government agency used to make private equity investments,” SBIC funds and “Business/Community Development Program,” defined as “a private equity fund formed by a local community to help fund community interests, such as housing developments, workforce programs, childcare centers, schools, businesses, and community centers.” Out of 1551 total rounds (i.e., first rounds and follow-on rounds, for both switchers and non-switchers) led by GVCs, 64.21% refers to the Small Business Investment Company (SBIC) Program, 30.11% refers to Government VC funds and 5.61% refers to the Business/Community Development Program.
 
12
It should be noted that a venture may switch more than once in the observed period.
 
13
The remaining 40 switching rounds refer to a switching from a GVC to another GVC. We did not include these rounds in our analysis, because the limited number of observations did not allow us to perform a significant analysis of the phenomenon.
 
14
We also compared switcher and non-switcher ventures according to the “size of government” component of the EFW index (Economic Freedom of the World, Frazer Institute). The results indicate that ventures switching to or from a GVC show a significantly higher value than non-switchers, with respect to several variables that measure the role and the incidence of Government (e.g., General Government Consumption Spending and Transfers and Subsidies as a percentage of GDP, both measured considering the average value from 1998 to 2010). The results of these tests are not reported in the manuscript, for the sake of brevity, but are available from the authors upon request.
 
15
This number was estimated by year, considering those IPOs for which the focal VC was the lead investor at the time of the last funding round.
 
16
Lee et al.’s (2011) VC reputation index is available for public use at www.​timothypollock.​com. The VC investors in our sample were not all included in Lee et al.’s (2011) index. The presence of these missing values explains why we replicated Lee et al.’s (2011) procedure instead of directly using their index.
 
17
We adopted the industry classification provided in the Thomson One database.
 
18
We have provided a number of robustness checks in the Appendix: a multinomial logit that discards first rounds (Table 9 in Appendix 1) and two probit models that run separately on IVC investments (which are the only ones that can switch to a GVC) in the first column in Table 10 in Appendix 2 and on GVC investments (which are the only ones that can switch to an IVC) in the second column in Table 10 in Appendix 2, respectively.
 
19
The results of this regression have been omitted for the sake of brevity, but are available to the readers upon request to the authors.
 
20
We estimated the probability of a successful exit for each venture at the start of each round; therefore, we employed a non-static measure of perceived quality.
 
21
As a robustness check, we also applied another similar estimation procedure with sample selection. We ran the first stage probit model of the Heckman procedure and we obtained the inverse Mills’ ratio (IMR), which is the estimated value of the generalized residual. To correct for any selection bias, the inverse Mills’ ratio control factor was then included in a second probit model, according to the specifications of the second stage of the Heckman procedure. The results of these estimates are not reported in the text, for the sake of brevity, but are available upon request to the authors.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Alperovych, Y., Hübner, G., & Lobet, F. (2015). How does governmental versus private venture capital backing affect a firm’s efficiency? Evidence from Belgium. Journal of Business Venturing, 30, 508–525.CrossRef Alperovych, Y., Hübner, G., & Lobet, F. (2015). How does governmental versus private venture capital backing affect a firm’s efficiency? Evidence from Belgium. Journal of Business Venturing, 30, 508–525.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Armour, J., & Cumming, D. J. (2006). The legislative road to Silicon Valley. Oxford Economic Papers, 58(4), 596–635.CrossRef Armour, J., & Cumming, D. J. (2006). The legislative road to Silicon Valley. Oxford Economic Papers, 58(4), 596–635.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Avnimelech, A., & Teubal, M. (2006). Creating venture capital industries that co-evolve with high tech: Insights from an extended industry life cycle perspective of the Israeli experience. Research Policy, 35, 1477–1498.CrossRef Avnimelech, A., & Teubal, M. (2006). Creating venture capital industries that co-evolve with high tech: Insights from an extended industry life cycle perspective of the Israeli experience. Research Policy, 35, 1477–1498.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertoni, F., D’Adda, D., & Grilli, L. (2016). Cherry-picking or frog-kissing? A theoretical analysis of how investors select entrepreneurial ventures in thin venture capital markets. Small Business Economics, 46, 391–405.CrossRef Bertoni, F., D’Adda, D., & Grilli, L. (2016). Cherry-picking or frog-kissing? A theoretical analysis of how investors select entrepreneurial ventures in thin venture capital markets. Small Business Economics, 46, 391–405.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertoni, F., Colombo, M., & Quas, A. (2015). The patterns of venture capital investment in Europe. Small Business Economics, 45, 543–560.CrossRef Bertoni, F., Colombo, M., & Quas, A. (2015). The patterns of venture capital investment in Europe. Small Business Economics, 45, 543–560.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bertoni, F., Colombo, M., & Quas, A. (2017). The role of governmental venture capital in the venture capital ecosystem: an organizational ecology perspective. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice forthcoming. Bertoni, F., Colombo, M., & Quas, A. (2017). The role of governmental venture capital in the venture capital ecosystem: an organizational ecology perspective. Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice forthcoming.
Zurück zum Zitat Brander, J. A., Du, Q., & Hellmann, T. F. (2015). The effects of government-sponsored venture capital: International evidence. Review of Finance, 19, 571–618.CrossRef Brander, J. A., Du, Q., & Hellmann, T. F. (2015). The effects of government-sponsored venture capital: International evidence. Review of Finance, 19, 571–618.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Buzzacchi, L., Scellato, G., & Ughetto, E. (2013). The investment strategies of publicly sponsored venture capital funds. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(3), 707–716.CrossRef Buzzacchi, L., Scellato, G., & Ughetto, E. (2013). The investment strategies of publicly sponsored venture capital funds. Journal of Banking & Finance, 37(3), 707–716.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chan, Y. S. (1983). On the positive role of financial intermediation in allocation of venture capital in market with imperfect information. Journal of Finance, 35, 1543–1568.CrossRef Chan, Y. S. (1983). On the positive role of financial intermediation in allocation of venture capital in market with imperfect information. Journal of Finance, 35, 1543–1568.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cressy, R. (2002). Funding gaps: a symposium. Economic Journal, 112(477), F1–F16.CrossRef Cressy, R. (2002). Funding gaps: a symposium. Economic Journal, 112(477), F1–F16.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Croce, A., Ughetto, E. (2016). Venture quality, investor reputation and geography. The dynamics of changing the type of lead venture capitalist. Unpublished manuscript. Croce, A., Ughetto, E. (2016). Venture quality, investor reputation and geography. The dynamics of changing the type of lead venture capitalist. Unpublished manuscript.
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D. J. (2007). Government policy towards entrepreneurial finance: Innovation investment funds. Journal of Business Venturing, 22(2), 193–235.CrossRef Cumming, D. J. (2007). Government policy towards entrepreneurial finance: Innovation investment funds. Journal of Business Venturing, 22(2), 193–235.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D. J., & Dai, N. (2013). Why do entrepreneurs switch lead venture capitalists? Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 37(5), 999–1017. Cumming, D. J., & Dai, N. (2013). Why do entrepreneurs switch lead venture capitalists? Entrepreneurship: Theory and Practice, 37(5), 999–1017.
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D. J., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2001). Venture capital investment duration in Canada and the United States. Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 11, 445–463.CrossRef Cumming, D. J., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2001). Venture capital investment duration in Canada and the United States. Journal of Multinational Financial Management, 11, 445–463.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D. J., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2006). Crowding out private equity: Canadian evidence. Journal of Business Venturing, 21(5), 569–609.CrossRef Cumming, D. J., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2006). Crowding out private equity: Canadian evidence. Journal of Business Venturing, 21(5), 569–609.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D. J., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2007). Mutual funds that invest in private equity? An analysis of labour-sponsored investment funds. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31, 445–487.CrossRef Cumming, D. J., & MacIntosh, J. G. (2007). Mutual funds that invest in private equity? An analysis of labour-sponsored investment funds. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 31, 445–487.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cumming, D., & Li, D. (2013). Public policy, entrepreneurship, and venture capital in the United States. Journal of Corporate Finance, 23, 345–367.CrossRef Cumming, D., & Li, D. (2013). Public policy, entrepreneurship, and venture capital in the United States. Journal of Corporate Finance, 23, 345–367.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Da Rin, M., Nicodano, G., & Sembenelli, A. (2006). Public policy and the creation of active venture capital markets. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1699–1723.CrossRef Da Rin, M., Nicodano, G., & Sembenelli, A. (2006). Public policy and the creation of active venture capital markets. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 1699–1723.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Da Rin, M. D., Hellmann, T., & Puri, M. (2013). A survey of venture capital research. In G. Constantinides, M. Harris, & R. Stulz (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of finance. Part A (Vol. 2, pp. 573–648). New York: Elsevier.CrossRef Da Rin, M. D., Hellmann, T., & Puri, M. (2013). A survey of venture capital research. In G. Constantinides, M. Harris, & R. Stulz (Eds.), Handbook of the economics of finance. Part A (Vol. 2, pp. 573–648). New York: Elsevier.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Devenow, A., & Welch, I. (1996). Rational herding in financial economics. European Economic Review, 40(3–5), 603–615.CrossRef Devenow, A., & Welch, I. (1996). Rational herding in financial economics. European Economic Review, 40(3–5), 603–615.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Dimov, D., Shepherd, D. A., & Sutcliffe, K. M. (2007). Requisite expertise, firm reputation, and status in venture capital investment allocation decisions. Journal of Business Venturing, 22, 481–502.CrossRef Dimov, D., Shepherd, D. A., & Sutcliffe, K. M. (2007). Requisite expertise, firm reputation, and status in venture capital investment allocation decisions. Journal of Business Venturing, 22, 481–502.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fitza, M., Matusik, S. F., & Mosakowski, E. (2009). Do VCs matter? The importance of owners on performance variance in start-up firms. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 387–404.CrossRef Fitza, M., Matusik, S. F., & Mosakowski, E. (2009). Do VCs matter? The importance of owners on performance variance in start-up firms. Strategic Management Journal, 30, 387–404.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fried, V. H., & Hisrich, R. D. (1994). Toward a model of venture capital investment decision making. Financial Management, 23(3), 28–37.CrossRef Fried, V. H., & Hisrich, R. D. (1994). Toward a model of venture capital investment decision making. Financial Management, 23(3), 28–37.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gompers, P. A. (1996). Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial Economics, 43, 133–156.CrossRef Gompers, P. A. (1996). Grandstanding in the venture capital industry. Journal of Financial Economics, 43, 133–156.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. (2000). The venture capital cycle. Cambridge: MIT Press. Gompers, P. A., & Lerner, J. (2000). The venture capital cycle. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Grilli, L., & Murtinu, S. (2014). Government, venture capital and the growth of European high-tech entrepreneurial firms. Research Policy, 43, 1523–1543.CrossRef Grilli, L., & Murtinu, S. (2014). Government, venture capital and the growth of European high-tech entrepreneurial firms. Research Policy, 43, 1523–1543.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guler, I. (2007). Throwing good money after bad? Political and institutional influences on sequential decision making in the venture capital industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, 248–285.CrossRef Guler, I. (2007). Throwing good money after bad? Political and institutional influences on sequential decision making in the venture capital industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, 248–285.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guerini, M., & Quas, A. (2016). Governmental venture capital in Europe: screening and certification. Journal of Business Venturing, 31, 175–195.CrossRef Guerini, M., & Quas, A. (2016). Governmental venture capital in Europe: screening and certification. Journal of Business Venturing, 31, 175–195.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Hsu, D. H. (2004). What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation? Journal of Finance, 59, 1805–1844.CrossRef Hsu, D. H. (2004). What do entrepreneurs pay for venture capital affiliation? Journal of Finance, 59, 1805–1844.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Johan, S., Schweizer, D., & Zhan, F. (2014). The changing latitude: labor-sponsored venture capital corporations in Canada. Corporate Governance, 22(2), 145–161.CrossRef Johan, S., Schweizer, D., & Zhan, F. (2014). The changing latitude: labor-sponsored venture capital corporations in Canada. Corporate Governance, 22(2), 145–161.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lee, P. M., Pollock, T. G., & Jin, K. (2011). The contingent value of venture capitalist reputation. Strategic Organization, 9(1), 33–69.CrossRef Lee, P. M., Pollock, T. G., & Jin, K. (2011). The contingent value of venture capitalist reputation. Strategic Organization, 9(1), 33–69.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Leleux, B., & Surlemont, B. (2003). Public versus private venture capital: Seeding or crowding out? A pan-European analysis. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(1), 81–104.CrossRef Leleux, B., & Surlemont, B. (2003). Public versus private venture capital: Seeding or crowding out? A pan-European analysis. Journal of Business Venturing, 18(1), 81–104.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lerner, J. (1999). The government as venture capitalist: the long-run impact of the SBIR program. Journal of Business, 72(3), 285–318.CrossRef Lerner, J. (1999). The government as venture capitalist: the long-run impact of the SBIR program. Journal of Business, 72(3), 285–318.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lerner, J. (2002). When bureaucrats meet entrepreneurs: the design of effective ‘public venture capital’ programmes. Economic Journal, 112(477), F73–F84.CrossRef Lerner, J. (2002). When bureaucrats meet entrepreneurs: the design of effective ‘public venture capital’ programmes. Economic Journal, 112(477), F73–F84.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Lerner, J. (2010). The future of public efforts to boost entrepreneurship and venture capital. Small Business Economics, 35, 255–264.CrossRef Lerner, J. (2010). The future of public efforts to boost entrepreneurship and venture capital. Small Business Economics, 35, 255–264.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Luukkonen, T., Deschryvere, M., & Bertoni, F. (2013). The value added by government venture capital funds compared with independent venture capital funds. Technovation, 33, 154–162.CrossRef Luukkonen, T., Deschryvere, M., & Bertoni, F. (2013). The value added by government venture capital funds compared with independent venture capital funds. Technovation, 33, 154–162.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mason, C. M., & Harrison, R. T. (1995). Closing the regional equity capital gap: the role of informal venture capital. Small Business Economics, 7, 153–172.CrossRef Mason, C. M., & Harrison, R. T. (1995). Closing the regional equity capital gap: the role of informal venture capital. Small Business Economics, 7, 153–172.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Muzyka, D., Birley, S., & Leleux, B. (1996). Trade-offs in the investment decisions of European venture capitalists. Journal of Business Venturing, 11, 273–287.CrossRef Muzyka, D., Birley, S., & Leleux, B. (1996). Trade-offs in the investment decisions of European venture capitalists. Journal of Business Venturing, 11, 273–287.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Nahata, R. (2008). Venture capital reputation and investment performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 90, 127–151.CrossRef Nahata, R. (2008). Venture capital reputation and investment performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 90, 127–151.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Petty, S. J., & Gruber, M. (2011). “In pursuit of the real deal”. A longitudinal study of VC decision making. Journal of Business Venturing, 26, 172–188.CrossRef Petty, S. J., & Gruber, M. (2011). “In pursuit of the real deal”. A longitudinal study of VC decision making. Journal of Business Venturing, 26, 172–188.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sahlman, W. A. (1990). The structure and governance of venture-capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(2), 473–521.CrossRef Sahlman, W. A. (1990). The structure and governance of venture-capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics, 27(2), 473–521.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Shepherd, D. A. (1999). Venture capitalists’ assessment of new venture survival. Management Science, 45(5), 624–632.CrossRef Shepherd, D. A. (1999). Venture capitalists’ assessment of new venture survival. Management Science, 45(5), 624–632.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sørensen, M. (2007). How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital. Journal of Finance, 62, 2725–2762.CrossRef Sørensen, M. (2007). How smart is smart money? A two-sided matching model of venture capital. Journal of Finance, 62, 2725–2762.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
The dynamics of switching between governmental and independent venture capitalists: theory and evidence
verfasst von
Laura Abrardi
Annalisa Croce
Elisa Ughetto
Publikationsdatum
11.04.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Small Business Economics / Ausgabe 1/2019
Print ISSN: 0921-898X
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-0913
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-018-0047-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2019

Small Business Economics 1/2019 Zur Ausgabe