Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare 4/2018

11.06.2018 | Original Paper

On single-peaked domains and min–max rules

verfasst von: Gopakumar Achuthankutty, Souvik Roy

Erschienen in: Social Choice and Welfare | Ausgabe 4/2018

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

We consider social choice problems where the admissible set of preferences of each agent is single-peaked. First, we show that if all the agents have the same admissible set of preferences, then every unanimous and strategy-proof social choice function (SCF) is tops-only. Next, we consider situations where different agents have different admissible sets of single-peaked preferences. We show by means of an example that unanimous and strategy-proof SCFs need not be tops-only in this situation, and consequently provide a sufficient condition on the admissible sets of preferences of the agents so that unanimity and strategy-proofness guarantee tops-onlyness. Finally, we characterize all domains on which (i) every unanimous and strategy-proof SCF is a min–max rule, and (ii) every min–max rule is strategy-proof. As an application of our result, we obtain a characterization of the unanimous and strategy-proof social choice functions on maximal single-peaked domains (Moulin in Public Choice 35(4):437–455. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1007/​BF00128122, 1980; Weymark in SERIEs 2(4):529–550. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1007/​s13209-011-0064-5, 2011), minimally rich single-peaked domains (Peters et al. in J Math Econ 52:123–127. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1016/​j.​jmateco.​2014.​03.​008. http://​www.​sciencedirect.​com/​science/​article/​pii/​S030440681400047​0, 2014), maximal regular single-crossing domains (Saporiti in Theor Econ 4(2):127–163, 2009, J Econ Theory 154:216–228. https://​doi.​org/​10.​1016/​j.​jet.​2014.​09.​006. http://​www.​sciencedirect.​com/​science/​article/​pii/​S002205311400127​6, 2009), and distance based single-peaked domains.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
Barberà et al. (1993) and Ching (1997) provide equivalent presentations of this class of SCFs.
 
2
A rich literature has developed around the single-peaked restriction by considering various generalizations and extensions (see Barberà et al. 1993; Demange 1982; Schummer and Vohra 2002; Nehring and Puppe 2007a, and Nehring and Puppe 2007b).
 
3
See, for instance, the domain restriction considered in models of voting (Tullock 1967; Arrow 1969), taxation and redistribution (Epple and Romer 1991), determining the levels of income redistribution (Hamada 1973; Slesnick 1988), and measuring tax reforms in the presence of horizontal inequity (Hettich 1979). Recently, Puppe (2018) shows that under mild conditions these domains form subsets of the maximal single-peaked domain.
 
4
Chatterji and Sen (2011) provide a sufficient condition on a domain so that every unanimous and strategy-proof SCF on it is tops-only. However, an arbitrary single-peaked domain does not satisfy their condition.
 
5
The top-connectedness property is well studied in the literature (see Barberà and Peleg 1990; Aswal et al. 2003; Chatterji and Sen 2011; Chatterji et al. 2014; Chatterji and Zeng 2018; Puppe 2018 and Roy and Storcken 2016).
 
6
A domain is regular if every alternative appears as the top-ranked alternative of some preference in the domain.
 
7
Single-crossing domains appear in models of taxation and redistribution (Roberts 1977; Meltzer and Richard 1981), local public goods and stratification (Westhoff 1977; Epple and Platt 1998; Epple et al. 2001), coalition formation (Demange 1994; Kung 2006), selecting constitutional and voting rules (Barberà and Jackson 2004), and designing policies in the market for higher education (Epple et al. 2006).
 
8
Saporiti (2014) provides a different but equivalent functional form of these SCFs which he calls augmented representative voter schemes.
 
9
A single-peaked preference is called left (or right) single-peaked if every alternative to the left (or right) of the peak is preferred to every alternative to its right (or left).
 
10
Such preferences appear in directional theories of issue voting (Stokes 1963; Rabinowitz 1978; Rabinowitz et al. 1982; Rabinowitz and Macdonald 1989).
 
11
For details, see Weymark (2011).
 
12
A median rule is a min–max rule that is anonymous. More formally, a min–max rule with respect to parameters \((\beta _S)_{S \subseteq N}\) is a median rule if \(\beta _S=\beta _{\bar{S}}\) for all \(S,\bar{S} \subseteq N\) with \(|S|=|\bar{S}|\). For details see Moulin (1980).
 
13
Since \(f(P'_{i},P_{N {\setminus } i}) = y'\), if \(r_{1}(P'_i) \ne y'\), then by strategy-proofness, \(f(P''_{i},P_{N {\setminus } i}) = y'\) for some \(P''_{i} \in \mathcal {S}_{i}\) with \(r_{1}(P''_{i}) = y'\). Similarly, if \(r_{1}(P_{j}) < y'\) for some \(j \in N {\setminus } i\), then by strategy-proofness, \(f(P'_{i},P'_{j},P_{N {\setminus } \{i,j\}}) = y'\) for some \(P'_{j} \in \mathcal {S}_{j}\) with \(r_{1}(P'_{j}) = y'\).
 
14
Here \(\mathcal {D}_{i}\) satisfies the unique seconds property defined in Aswal et al. (2003) and the SCF f considered here is similar to the one used in the proof of Theorem 5.1 in Aswal et al. (2003).
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Elkind E, Faliszewski P, Skowron P (2014) A characterization of the single-peaked single-crossing domain. In: AAAI, vol 14, pp 654–660 Elkind E, Faliszewski P, Skowron P (2014) A characterization of the single-peaked single-crossing domain. In: AAAI, vol 14, pp 654–660
Zurück zum Zitat Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57 Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57
Zurück zum Zitat Roy S, Storcken T (2016) Unanimity, pareto optimality and strategy-proofness on connected domains. Working Paper Roy S, Storcken T (2016) Unanimity, pareto optimality and strategy-proofness on connected domains. Working Paper
Zurück zum Zitat Saporiti A (2009) Strategy-proofness and single-crossing. Theor Econ 4(2):127–163 Saporiti A (2009) Strategy-proofness and single-crossing. Theor Econ 4(2):127–163
Zurück zum Zitat Slesnick D (1988) The political economy of redistribution policy. Unpublished University of Texas Working Paper Slesnick D (1988) The political economy of redistribution policy. Unpublished University of Texas Working Paper
Metadaten
Titel
On single-peaked domains and min–max rules
verfasst von
Gopakumar Achuthankutty
Souvik Roy
Publikationsdatum
11.06.2018
Verlag
Springer Berlin Heidelberg
Erschienen in
Social Choice and Welfare / Ausgabe 4/2018
Print ISSN: 0176-1714
Elektronische ISSN: 1432-217X
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-018-1137-1

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 4/2018

Social Choice and Welfare 4/2018 Zur Ausgabe