Skip to main content
Erschienen in: Theory and Decision 1/2019

10.09.2018

Experience in public goods experiments

verfasst von: Anna Conte, M. Vittoria Levati, Natalia Montinari

Erschienen in: Theory and Decision | Ausgabe 1/2019

Einloggen

Aktivieren Sie unsere intelligente Suche, um passende Fachinhalte oder Patente zu finden.

search-config
loading …

Abstract

Using information on students’ past participation in economic experiments, we analyze whether behavior in public goods games is affected by experience (participation in social dilemma-type experiments) and history (participation in experiments different from social dilemmas). We find that: (1) on average, the amount subjects contribute and expect others to contribute decreases with experience; (2) at the individual level, the proportion of unconditional cooperators decreases with experience, while the proportion of selfish people increases. Finally, history influences behavior less than experience. Researchers are urged to control for subjects’ experience and history to improve the external validity and replicability of results.

Sie haben noch keine Lizenz? Dann Informieren Sie sich jetzt über unsere Produkte:

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft+Technik" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 102.000 Bücher
  • über 537 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Automobil + Motoren
  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Elektrotechnik + Elektronik
  • Energie + Nachhaltigkeit
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Maschinenbau + Werkstoffe
  • Versicherung + Risiko

Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Springer Professional "Wirtschaft"

Online-Abonnement

Mit Springer Professional "Wirtschaft" erhalten Sie Zugriff auf:

  • über 67.000 Bücher
  • über 340 Zeitschriften

aus folgenden Fachgebieten:

  • Bauwesen + Immobilien
  • Business IT + Informatik
  • Finance + Banking
  • Management + Führung
  • Marketing + Vertrieb
  • Versicherung + Risiko




Jetzt Wissensvorsprung sichern!

Anhänge
Nur mit Berechtigung zugänglich
Fußnoten
1
We acknowledge that we use the term “history” with a meaning different from the one common in the public goods literature. History is generally used to signify the decisions that a player observes during the game (e.g., Gunnthorsdottir et al. 2007).
 
2
A different fundamental methodological issue, which focuses on the misrepresentation of social preferences in laboratory experiments with student samples, is addressed by Falk et al. (2013).
 
3
We chose this protocol to minimize strategic effects of repeated play and to allow for revisions to beliefs only at the population level.
 
4
To simplify notation, we always refer to player i’s partner as j, although this is a different person in each period.
 
5
In our experiment, we elicited beliefs about the others’ contribution. The previous research in experimental economics has shown that the mere act of eliciting beliefs can affect behavior in finitely repeated public goods games (see, e.g., Croson 2000 or Gächter and Renner 2010), although the evidence regarding the undesirable effects of belief elicitation procedures is far from being conclusive (e.g., Wilcox and Feltovich 2000) and does not concern stranger matching protocols.
 
6
See Selten (1998) for an axiomatic characterization of the rule, and Offerman et al. (2009) for an experiment investigating its behavioral properties.
 
7
A similar rule has been used, e.g., by Offerman et al. 1996, Costa-Gomes and Weizsäcker 2008, and Rey-Biel 2009, although there exists no consensus among experimentalists about the optimal incentive mechanism for eliciting beliefs. Huck and Weizsäcker (2002) compare beliefs elicited via a quadratic scoring rule with beliefs elicited via a Becker–DeGroot–Marshak pricing rule, and find that the former yields more accurate beliefs.
 
8
In the instructions, we use a verbal description of the rule and give numerical examples. Recognized problems of the quadratic scoring rule are that incentives are flat at the maximum and that this may be difficult to understand. To avoid the latter problem, our instructions emphasize that the more accurate the beliefs, the higher the payment.
 
9
From the experimental instructions, it can be noted that the explanation of the public good in our experiment is different from that used in other studies (e.g., Fischbacher et al. 2001). Yet, we are confident that participants understood correctly the social dilemma feature of the framework which they were confronted with. We base our statement on the following facts: (1) instructions were read aloud in each session to establish public knowledge of the fact that all participants in the session were facing the same experimental instructions and nothing was concealed; (2) participants had to solve some control questions (reported in the Online Appendix F) before starting the experiment; (3) contribution data and belief data from our experiment do not present any anomaly that might induce an analyst acquainted with the literature on public goods experiments to believe that something went out of control.
 
10
The first six sessions of treatment I have already been analyzed in Conte and Levati (2014).
 
11
We acknowledge that a stricter baseline would have had completely inexperienced subjects. However, since other researchers were using the laboratory at the time of our data collection, the recruitment of completely inexperienced subjects would have implied stopping all the ongoing experiments. In our econometric analysis, we control for the time passed from the first and/or last participation in an experiment, and therefore, we are able to distinguish between subjects who were participating for the first time and subjects who had already participated in experiments. These factors are found not to improve the econometric specifications.
 
12
Note that, on the basis of the information provided by the ORSEE system, we are only able to observe whether a subject has taken part in an experiment or not. We cannot observe other characteristics of the experiment, as, for example, matching protocol, money earned, length and repetitiveness of the interactions, etc.
 
13
By “expected contribution”, we mean the amount that subject i expects his partner j to contribute in each period t. These amounts are calculated by averaging all possible contributions, weighted for the corresponding beliefs. More exactly, expected contributions in period \(t=1,\ldots ,15\) are computed as
$$\begin{aligned} \text {E}_{i,t}(c_{j,t}) = \frac{\sum _{a=0}^{10} \left( a\times 10\right) \times b_{i,t}\left( a\right) }{100}. \end{aligned}$$
 
14
Given our rematching protocol, the number of statistically independent observations is 7 in both treatments.
 
15
To assess the accuracy of beliefs, along the lines of Eq. 2, for each individual i in the two samples, we derive the following index:
$$\begin{aligned} \delta _{i,t}=\sqrt{\sum _{a=0}^{10}\left[ \frac{b_{i,t}(a)}{100}-\sum _{j=1}^{S}\frac{\mathbb {1}({\hat{c}}_{j,t}=a\times 10)}{S}\right] ^{2}\bigg /11}. \end{aligned}$$
It represents the square root of a quadratic deviation of subject i’s beliefs from the empirical distribution of contributions: the lower \(\delta _{i,t}\) is, the closer the subject’s beliefs are to such a distribution.
 
16
We thank an anonymous referee who noted how it may seem surprising that, in the first periods of play, beliefs are less accurate (or better, similarly accurate) for the experienced than for the inexperienced. This may be due to the fact that the experienced do not know that they are interacting with other experienced subjects, so they may reasonably assume that their opponents are drawn from the general population composed of participants with different degrees of experience. As the experiment proceeds, however, the experienced subjects adjust their beliefs faster compared to the inexperienced ones.
 
17
This interpretation is consistent with the fact that, in the E treatment, subjects were not aware of the fact that their partners had had the previous experience of public goods experiments or other experiments.
 
18
To estimate the model, we divided contributions by 10.
 
19
Details can be found in Train (2003).
 
20
Identification fails in the following cases: when, given i’s distribution of beliefs and Eq. (9), i’s optimal contribution is always \(c_{i,t}=0\) (in that case, a conditional cooperator is indistinguishable from a selfish agent); when, given i’s distribution of beliefs and Eq. (9), i’s optimal contribution always corresponds to the median of i’s observed contributions, \(c_{i,t}=m_{i}\), (in that case, a conditional cooperator is indistinguishable from an unconditional cooperator); when subjects’ preferences are not stable throughout the game. In those cases, individual’s type identification is achievable (or refined) via repeated observations.
 
21
All the tests reported here are bootstrapped (200 replications) with asymptotic refinement (see Cameron and Trivedi 2005, among others).
 
22
The estimated relative proportion of selfish subjects with respect to conditional cooperators is 0.195 (s.e. 0.041) and 0.328 (s.e. 0.062) from sample I and E, respectively, the latter being significantly different from the former (\(z=2.12\), p-value \(=0.03\), two-sided test). However, this result does not exclude a different redistribution of types due to experience (for example, with conditional cooperators learning how to play the dominant strategy and unconditional cooperators conditioning their choices on beliefs).
 
23
The numbers in Table 4 have to be interpreted as follows. Specification 1 attests, for example, that, if we draw two samples which are equal in everything but in subjects’ experience, then we have to expect to find in the experienced sample, with respect to the inexperienced sample, that the proportion of selfish (conditional cooperator) is 6.37 (6.81) percentage points larger and the proportion of unconditional cooperators is 13.18 percentage points smaller.
 
24
Table 4 only reports the relevant results. We used several different controls such as the number of participations in a particular type of experiment, the time passed from the first and/or last participation in an experiment both for social dilemma and other experiments, course of study, and so on. None of them seem to improve upon the specifications displayed in the table, but are available from the authors on request.
 
Literatur
Zurück zum Zitat Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70(2), 297–323.CrossRef Anderson, S. P., Goeree, J. K., & Holt, C. A. (1998). A theoretical analysis of altruism and decision error in public goods games. Journal of Public Economics, 70(2), 297–323.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1988). Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37(3), 291–304.CrossRef Andreoni, J. (1988). Why free ride? Strategies and learning in public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 37(3), 291–304.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1993). An experimental test of the public-goods crowding-out hypothesis. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1317–1327. Andreoni, J. (1993). An experimental test of the public-goods crowding-out hypothesis. American Economic Review, 83(5), 1317–1327.
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public-goods experiments: kindness or confusion. American Economic Review, 85(4), 891–904. Andreoni, J. (1995). Cooperation in public-goods experiments: kindness or confusion. American Economic Review, 85(4), 891–904.
Zurück zum Zitat Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: an experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.CrossRef Andreoni, J., & Miller, J. (2002). Giving according to GARP: an experimental test of the consistency of preferences for altruism. Econometrica, 70(2), 737–753.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Arifovic, J., & Ledyard, J. (2012). Individual evolutionary learning, other-regarding preferences, and the voluntary contributions mechanism. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 808–823.CrossRef Arifovic, J., & Ledyard, J. (2012). Individual evolutionary learning, other-regarding preferences, and the voluntary contributions mechanism. Journal of Public Economics, 96, 808–823.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bardsley, N., & Moffatt, P. G. (2007). The experimetrics of public goods: inferring motivations from contributions. Theory and Decision, 62(2), 161–193.CrossRef Bardsley, N., & Moffatt, P. G. (2007). The experimetrics of public goods: inferring motivations from contributions. Theory and Decision, 62(2), 161–193.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bayer, R.-C., Renner, E., & Sausgruber, R. (2013). Confusion and learning in the voluntary contributions game. Experimental Economics, 16, 478–496.CrossRef Bayer, R.-C., Renner, E., & Sausgruber, R. (2013). Confusion and learning in the voluntary contributions game. Experimental Economics, 16, 478–496.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Benson, B. L., & Faminow, M. D. (1988). The impact of experience on prices and profits in experimental duopoly markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 9(4), 345–365.CrossRef Benson, B. L., & Faminow, M. D. (1988). The impact of experience on prices and profits in experimental duopoly markets. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 9(4), 345–365.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., & Normann, H.-T. (2011). A within-subject analysis of other-regarding preferences. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(2), 321–338.CrossRef Blanco, M., Engelmann, D., & Normann, H.-T. (2011). A within-subject analysis of other-regarding preferences. Games and Economic Behavior, 72(2), 321–338.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Bolton, (1991). A comparative model of bargaining: theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 81(5), 1096–1136. Bolton, (1991). A comparative model of bargaining: theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 81(5), 1096–1136.
Zurück zum Zitat Breitmoser, Y., Tan, J. H., & Zizzo, D. J. (2014). On the beliefs off the path: Equilibrium refinement due to quantal response and level-k. Games and Economic Behavior, 86, 102–125.CrossRef Breitmoser, Y., Tan, J. H., & Zizzo, D. J. (2014). On the beliefs off the path: Equilibrium refinement due to quantal response and level-k. Games and Economic Behavior, 86, 102–125.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Brosig, J., Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2007). Selfish in the end? An investigation of consistency and stability of individual behavior, MPRA Paper No. 2035, University Library of Munich. Brosig, J., Riechmann, T., & Weimann, J. (2007). Selfish in the end? An investigation of consistency and stability of individual behavior, MPRA Paper No. 2035, University Library of Munich.
Zurück zum Zitat Burlando, R. M., & Guala, F. (2005). Heterogeneous agents in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 8(1), 35–54.CrossRef Burlando, R. M., & Guala, F. (2005). Heterogeneous agents in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 8(1), 35–54.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics: methods and applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Cameron, A. C., & Trivedi, P. K. (2005). Microeconometrics: methods and applications. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Chi, M., Feltovich, P., & Glaser, R. (1981). Categorization and representation of physics problems by experts and novices. Cognitive Science, 5, 121–152.CrossRef Chi, M., Feltovich, P., & Glaser, R. (1981). Categorization and representation of physics problems by experts and novices. Cognitive Science, 5, 121–152.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Conte, A., & Levati, M. V. (2014). Use of data on planned contributions and stated beliefs in the measurement of social preferences. Theory and Decision, 76(2), 201–223.CrossRef Conte, A., & Levati, M. V. (2014). Use of data on planned contributions and stated beliefs in the measurement of social preferences. Theory and Decision, 76(2), 201–223.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 729–762.CrossRef Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Weizsäcker, G. (2008). Stated beliefs and play in normal-form games. Review of Economic Studies, 75(3), 729–762.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Croson, R. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: factors affecting the frequency of equilibrium play. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 41(3), 299–314.CrossRef Croson, R. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: factors affecting the frequency of equilibrium play. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 41(3), 299–314.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Erev, I., & Roth, A. E. (2014). Maximization, learning, and economic behavior. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 111(3), 10818–10825.CrossRef Erev, I., & Roth, A. E. (2014). Maximization, learning, and economic behavior. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 111(3), 10818–10825.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Falk, A., Meier, S., & Zehnder, C. (2013). Do lab experiments misrepresent social preferences? The case of self-selected student samples. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(4), 839–852.CrossRef Falk, A., Meier, S., & Zehnder, C. (2013). Do lab experiments misrepresent social preferences? The case of self-selected student samples. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(4), 839–852.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.CrossRef Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (1999). A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ferraro, P. J., & Vossler, C. A. (2010). The source and significance of confusion in public goods experiments. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 10(1), 1–42.CrossRef Ferraro, P. J., & Vossler, C. A. (2010). The source and significance of confusion in public goods experiments. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 10(1), 1–42.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U. (2007). Zurich toolbox for readymade economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef Fischbacher, U. (2007). Zurich toolbox for readymade economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.CrossRef Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 100(1), 541–556.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment, Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404. Fischbacher, U., Gächter, S., & Fehr, E. (2001). Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a Public Goods Experiment, Economics Letters, 71(3), 397–404.
Zurück zum Zitat Gächter, S., & Renner, E. (2010). The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 364–377.CrossRef Gächter, S., & Renner, E. (2010). The effects of (incentivized) belief elicitation in public goods experiments. Experimental Economics, 13(3), 364–377.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Goeree, J., Holt, C., & Laury, S. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83(2), 257–278.CrossRef Goeree, J., Holt, C., & Laury, S. (2002). Private costs and public benefits: unraveling the effects of altruism and noisy behavior. Journal of Public Economics, 83(2), 257–278.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114–125.CrossRef Greiner, B. (2015). Subject pool recruitment procedures: organizing experiments with ORSEE. Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114–125.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Grimm, V., & Mengel, F. (2012). An experiment on learning in a multiple games environment. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(6), 2220–2259.CrossRef Grimm, V., & Mengel, F. (2012). An experiment on learning in a multiple games environment. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(6), 2220–2259.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guala, F. (1999). The problem of external validity (or ‘parallelism’) in experimental economics. Social Science Information, 38, 555–573.CrossRef Guala, F. (1999). The problem of external validity (or ‘parallelism’) in experimental economics. Social Science Information, 38, 555–573.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guala, F. (2002). On the scope of experiments in economics: comments on Siakantaris. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 26(2), 261–267.CrossRef Guala, F. (2002). On the scope of experiments in economics: comments on Siakantaris. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 26(2), 261–267.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Guimarães, P., & Lindrooth, R. C. (2007). Controlling for overdispersion in grouped conditional logit models: a computationally simple application of Dirichlet-multinomial regression. Econometrics Journal, 10(2), 439–452.CrossRef Guimarães, P., & Lindrooth, R. C. (2007). Controlling for overdispersion in grouped conditional logit models: a computationally simple application of Dirichlet-multinomial regression. Econometrics Journal, 10(2), 439–452.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Gunnthorsdottir, A., Houser, D., & McCabe, K. (2007). Disposition, history and contributions in public goods experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 62, 304–315.CrossRef Gunnthorsdottir, A., Houser, D., & McCabe, K. (2007). Disposition, history and contributions in public goods experiments. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 62, 304–315.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Harrison, G. W., McKee, M., & Rutström, E. E. (1987). Experimental evaluations of institutions of monopoly restraints. In L. Green & J. H. Kagel (Eds.), Advances in Behavioral Economics (pp. 54–94). Norwood, N.J.: Ablex Press. Harrison, G. W., McKee, M., & Rutström, E. E. (1987). Experimental evaluations of institutions of monopoly restraints. In L. Green & J. H. Kagel (Eds.), Advances in Behavioral Economics (pp. 54–94). Norwood, N.J.: Ablex Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Haruvy, E., & Stahl, D. O. (2012). Between-game rule learning in dissimilar symmetric normal-form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 74(1), 208–221.CrossRef Haruvy, E., & Stahl, D. O. (2012). Between-game rule learning in dissimilar symmetric normal-form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 74(1), 208–221.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Houser, D., & Kurzban, R. (2002). Revisiting kindness and confusion in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1062–1069.CrossRef Houser, D., & Kurzban, R. (2002). Revisiting kindness and confusion in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 92(4), 1062–1069.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Huck, S., & Weizsäcker, G. (2002). Do players correctly estimate what others do? Evidence of conservatism in beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 47(1), 71–85.CrossRef Huck, S., & Weizsäcker, G. (2002). Do players correctly estimate what others do? Evidence of conservatism in beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 47(1), 71–85.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Isaac, M., Schmidtz, D., & Walker, J. (1989). The assurance problem in a laboratory market. Public Choice, 62, 217–236.CrossRef Isaac, M., Schmidtz, D., & Walker, J. (1989). The assurance problem in a laboratory market. Public Choice, 62, 217–236.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M., & Thomas, S. H. (1984). Divergent evidence on free riding: an experimental examination of possible explanations. Public Choice, 43, 113–149.CrossRef Isaac, R. M., Walker, J. M., & Thomas, S. H. (1984). Divergent evidence on free riding: an experimental examination of possible explanations. Public Choice, 43, 113–149.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Kurzban, R., & Houser, D. (2005). Experiments investigating cooperative types in humans: A complement to evolutionary theory and simulations. PNAS, 102(5), 1803–1807.CrossRef Kurzban, R., & Houser, D. (2005). Experiments investigating cooperative types in humans: A complement to evolutionary theory and simulations. PNAS, 102(5), 1803–1807.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In J. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics (pp. 111–194). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Ledyard, J. O. (1995). Public goods: a survey of experimental research. In J. Kagel & A. E. Roth (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics (pp. 111–194). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Zurück zum Zitat Loomes, G., Moffatt, P. G., & Sugden, R. (2002). A microeconometric test of alternative stochastic theories of risky choice. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 24, 103–130.CrossRef Loomes, G., Moffatt, P. G., & Sugden, R. (2002). A microeconometric test of alternative stochastic theories of risky choice. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 24, 103–130.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marchiori, D., Di Guida, S., & Erev, I. (2015). Noisy retrieval models of over-and undersensitivity to rare events. Decision, 2(2), 82–106.CrossRef Marchiori, D., Di Guida, S., & Erev, I. (2015). Noisy retrieval models of over-and undersensitivity to rare events. Decision, 2(2), 82–106.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Marwell, G., & Ames, R. E. (1980). Experiments on the provision of public goods. II. Provision points, stakes, experience and the free rider problem. American Journal of Sociology, 85(4), 926–937.CrossRef Marwell, G., & Ames, R. E. (1980). Experiments on the provision of public goods. II. Provision points, stakes, experience and the free rider problem. American Journal of Sociology, 85(4), 926–937.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Matthey, A., & Regner, T. (2013). On the independence of history: experience spill-overs between experiments. Theory and Decision, 75(3), 403–419.CrossRef Matthey, A., & Regner, T. (2013). On the independence of history: experience spill-overs between experiments. Theory and Decision, 75(3), 403–419.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Moffatt, P. G., & Peters, S. A. (2001). Testing for the presence of a tremble in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 4(3), 221–228.CrossRef Moffatt, P. G., & Peters, S. A. (2001). Testing for the presence of a tremble in economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 4(3), 221–228.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Mosimann, J. (1962). On the compound multinomial distribution, the multivariate beta-distribution and correlations among proportions. Biometrika, 49, 65–82. Mosimann, J. (1962). On the compound multinomial distribution, the multivariate beta-distribution and correlations among proportions. Biometrika, 49, 65–82.
Zurück zum Zitat Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., & Schram, A. (1996). Value orientations, expectations, and voluntary contributions in public goods. The Economic Journal, 106(437), 817–845.CrossRef Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., & Schram, A. (1996). Value orientations, expectations, and voluntary contributions in public goods. The Economic Journal, 106(437), 817–845.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., Van de Kuilen, G., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). A truth serum for non-Bayesians: correcting proper scoring rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1461–1489.CrossRef Offerman, T., Sonnemans, J., Van de Kuilen, G., & Wakker, P. P. (2009). A truth serum for non-Bayesians: correcting proper scoring rules for risk attitudes. Review of Economic Studies, 76(4), 1461–1489.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palacios-Huerta, I., & Volij, O. (2008). Experientia docet: professionals play minimax in laboratory experiments. Econometrica, 76(1), 71–115.CrossRef Palacios-Huerta, I., & Volij, O. (2008). Experientia docet: professionals play minimax in laboratory experiments. Econometrica, 76(1), 71–115.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1996). Altruism, reputation and noise in linear public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61(3), 409–427.CrossRef Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1996). Altruism, reputation and noise in linear public goods experiments. Journal of Public Economics, 61(3), 409–427.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1997). Anomalous behavior in public goods experiments: how much and why? American Economic Review, 87(5), 829–846. Palfrey, T. R., & Prisbrey, J. E. (1997). Anomalous behavior in public goods experiments: how much and why? American Economic Review, 87(5), 829–846.
Zurück zum Zitat Rand, D. G., Peysakhovich, A., Kraft-Todd, G. T., Newman, G. E., Wurzbacher, O., Nowak, M. A., et al. (2014). Social heuristics shape intuitive cooperation. Nature communications, 5, 1–12.CrossRef Rand, D. G., Peysakhovich, A., Kraft-Todd, G. T., Newman, G. E., Wurzbacher, O., Nowak, M. A., et al. (2014). Social heuristics shape intuitive cooperation. Nature communications, 5, 1–12.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Rey-Biel, P. (2009). Equilibrium play and best response to (stated) beliefs in normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 65(2), 572–585.CrossRef Rey-Biel, P. (2009). Equilibrium play and best response to (stated) beliefs in normal form games. Games and Economic Behavior, 65(2), 572–585.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Sass, M., & Weimann, J. (2012). The dynamics of individual preferences in repeated public good experiments, FEMM working papers 120002, Otto-von-Guericke University Magdeburg, Faculty of Economics and Management. Sass, M., & Weimann, J. (2012). The dynamics of individual preferences in repeated public good experiments, FEMM working papers 120002, Otto-von-Guericke University Magdeburg, Faculty of Economics and Management.
Zurück zum Zitat Selten, R. (1998). Axiomatic characterization of the quadratic scoring rule. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 43–62.CrossRef Selten, R. (1998). Axiomatic characterization of the quadratic scoring rule. Experimental Economics, 1(1), 43–62.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Skinner, B. F. (1953). Science and human behavior. New York: Simon and Schuster. Skinner, B. F. (1953). Science and human behavior. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Zurück zum Zitat Smith, V. L. (2010). Theory and experiment: what are the questions? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 73, 3–15.CrossRef Smith, V. L. (2010). Theory and experiment: what are the questions? Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 73, 3–15.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Train, K. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef Train, K. (2003). Discrete choice methods with simulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Verkoeijen, P. P., & Bouwmeester, S. (2014). Does intuition cause cooperation? PloS one, 9(5), e96654.CrossRef Verkoeijen, P. P., & Bouwmeester, S. (2014). Does intuition cause cooperation? PloS one, 9(5), e96654.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Volk, S., Thöni, C., & Ruigrok, W. (2012). Temporal stability and psychological foundations of cooperation preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81, 664–676.CrossRef Volk, S., Thöni, C., & Ruigrok, W. (2012). Temporal stability and psychological foundations of cooperation preferences. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 81, 664–676.CrossRef
Zurück zum Zitat Wilcox, N.T., & Feltovich, N. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: comment, University of Houston, Department of Economics Working Paper. Wilcox, N.T., & Feltovich, N. (2000). Thinking like a game theorist: comment, University of Houston, Department of Economics Working Paper.
Zurück zum Zitat Zelmer, J. (2003). Linear public goods experiments: a meta-analysis. Experimental Economics, 6(3), 299–310.CrossRef Zelmer, J. (2003). Linear public goods experiments: a meta-analysis. Experimental Economics, 6(3), 299–310.CrossRef
Metadaten
Titel
Experience in public goods experiments
verfasst von
Anna Conte
M. Vittoria Levati
Natalia Montinari
Publikationsdatum
10.09.2018
Verlag
Springer US
Erschienen in
Theory and Decision / Ausgabe 1/2019
Print ISSN: 0040-5833
Elektronische ISSN: 1573-7187
DOI
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11238-018-9670-z

Weitere Artikel der Ausgabe 1/2019

Theory and Decision 1/2019 Zur Ausgabe